Skip to main content

A Complete One-Sector Neoclassical Growth Model

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economic Growth and Development

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 1058 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter we put all the elements discussed in previous chapters together. The model includes private capital from Chap. 2, government capital and taxation from Chap. 3, and fertility and schooling from Chap. 4. The features are combined to study large income differences across rich and poor countries, what is known as development economics. At the dawn of the Industrial Revolution, the differences in per capita income across countries were relatively modest. Per capita income in the richest countries was only 2–4 times greater than per capita income in the poorest countries. Over the course of the last two centuries, per capita income of the rich countries has diverged from that of the poor countries. By the end of the twentieth century, rich countries were 20–40 times richer than poor countries. What could explain stylized growth fact G4, dramatically large gaps in living standards?

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Galor and Moav (2002) generalize this specification by allowing for a separate utility weight on the quantity and quality of children. They then go on to develop an evolutionary theory in which households raise the weight they placed on the quality of their children over the course of economic development. Using this more flexible specification would increase the ability of our model to fit the stylized growth facts.

  2. 2.

    For notational simplicity only, we assume the government’s time discount factor is the same as that used by private households. One could allow the discount factor to differ from private households to study how the government’s time preference affects policy.

  3. 3.

    We assume that the government can commit to its policy choices in advance. For a discussion of commitment issues in regard to the setting of fiscal policy see Lundquist and Sargent (2004, Chapter 22).

  4. 4.

    In 1997 Mexico began Progresa , a program designed to increase human capital in poor families by paying families to send their children to school and to visit health care providers. Grants are provided directly by the government to the mothers of children. The school grants cover about 2/3 of what the child would receive in full time work (Krueger 2002).

  5. 5.

    Our model abstracts from tuition costs (see Problems 2 and 3 from Chap. 4). The government can raise schooling by increasing tuition subsidies. Doepke (2004) and Lord and Rangazas (2006) study the historical impact of government tuition subsidies in England . They find that lower tuition has modest effects on schooling and growth. Lower tuition reduces the cost of all children and, in particular, young children who would have attended school in any case. This raises fertility for several periods and slows the demographic transition. Thus, something like a Progresa program or compulsory schooling is needed to generate a quick demographic transition and rapid economic growth.

References

  • Acemoglu D (2009) Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2012) Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown Publishers, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aschauer D (1989) Is public expenditure productive? Journal of monetary economics 23(2):177–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis C, Drazen A (1990) Threshold externalities in economic development. Quarterly journal of economics 105(2):501–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis C, Stachurski J (2004) Poverty traps. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Amsterdam, North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G, Murphy K, Tamura R (1990) Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of political economy 98(5):S12–S37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bongaarts J (2002) The end of the fertility transition in the developing world. Population and development review 28(3):419–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F. and Fyrer, J., 2007, The Marginal Product of Capital, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 535–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida RH (1993) International capital mobility, public investment, and economic growth. NBER working paper 4506. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Córdoba J, Ripoll M (2013) What explains schooling differences across countries? Journal of monetary economics 60(2):184–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix D (2013) Fertility, education, growth, and sustainability. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doepke M (2004) Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. Journal of economic growth 9(3):347–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A (1978) Government debt, human capital, and bequests in a life-cycle model. Journal of political economy 86(6):505–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A (2000) Political economy in macroeconomics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A, Isard P (2004) Can public discussion enhance program ownership? NBER working paper 10927. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W (2001) The elusive quest for growth. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W (2007) The white man’s burden. Penguin Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W, Levine R, Roodman D (2004) Aid, policies, and growth. American economic review 94(3):774–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2011) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2002) Natural selection and the origins of economic growth. Quarterly journal of economics 117(4):1133–1192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Ziera J (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of economic studies 60(1):35–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glomm G, Ravikumar B (1997) Productive government expenditures and long-run growth. Journal of economic dynamics and control 21(1):183–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (2001) Special interest politics. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall R, Jones C (1999) Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly journal of economics 114(1):83–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isard P, Lipschitz L, Mourmouras A, Yontcheva B (2006) High-level seminar on foreign aid and macroeconomic management: Overview and synopsis of key lessons. In: Isard P, Lipschitz L, Mourmouras A, Yontcheva B (eds) The macroeconomic management of foreign aid. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ivanyna, M, Mourmouras, A and Rangazas, P (2018) The macroeconomics of corruption: governance and growth, Springer, New York.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger A (2002) A model for evaluating the use of development dollars, south of the border. New York Times, May 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lord W (2002) Household dynamics, policy, and economics growth. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lord W, Rangazas P (2006) Fertility and development: The roles of schooling and family production. Journal of economic growth 11(3):229–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mallaby S (2004) The world’s banker. Penguin Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marchesi S, Sabani L (2007) IMF concerns for reputation and conditional lending failure: Theory and empirics. Journal of development economics 84(2):640–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mourmouras A, Mayer W (2005) The political economy of IMF conditionality: A common agency model. Review of development economics 9(4):449–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mourmouras A, Rangazas P (2007) Foreign aid policies and sources of poverty: a quantitative framework. IMF staff papers 54: 59–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunn N, Qian N (2014) US food aid and civil conflict. American economic review 104(6):1630–1666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G (1990) Macroeconomic policy, credibility, and politics. Harwood, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba J (1997) Rate of return to corporate capital and factor shares. NBER working paper 6263. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett L (2000) The tyranny of concepts: CUDIE (cumulated depreciated investment effort) is not capital. Journal of economic growth 5(4):361–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radelet S, Clemens M Bhavnani R (2006) Aid and growth: The current debate and some new evidence. CGD working paper 133. Center for Global Development, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raghuram R, Subramanian A (2008). Aid and growth: What does the cross-country evidence really show? Review of economics and statistics 90(4):643–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan R, Subramanian A (2011) Aid, Dutch disease, and manufacturing. Journal of development economics 94(1):106–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rangazas P (2000) Schooling and economic growth: A King-Rebelo experiment with human capital. Journal of monetary economics 46(2):397–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scholl A (2009) Aid effectiveness and limited enforcement conditionality. Review of economic dynamics 12(2):377–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson J (2000) When is foreign aid policy credible? Aid dependence and conditionality. Journal of development economics 61(1):61–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil D (2009) Economic growth. Addison Wesley, New York.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Alternative Interpretations of the Cost of Children

In the household model of fertility the cost of children can be thought of as lost adult consumption needed to feed children or forgone work time needed to raise children. In reality, both costs are important but it is simpler in the model to assume just one type of cost. In this chapter we think of the cost of children as representing lost adult consumption that is proportional to parent’s wages because, especially in developing countries, we think of this as the most important cost quantitatively. We use the cost of time rearing in the second half of the book because it gives rise to simpler expressions in the theory and we are not as concerned about quantitative accuracy as we are here.

The key difference between the two cost interpretation surfaces when you calculate the economy’s supply of labor. If the cost of children is lost adult consumption then the family supply of effective labor is

$$ {\widehat{h}}_t\equiv {h}_t+{n}_{t+1}\gamma \overline{h}\left(T-{e}_t\right).\kern3em \left(\mathrm{lost}\ \mathrm{consumption}\ \mathrm{interpretation}\right) $$

Alternatively, under the forgone work time interpretation we have

$$ {\widehat{h}}_t\equiv {h}_t\left(1-\eta {n}_{t+1}\right)+{n}_{t+1}\gamma \overline{h}\left(T-{e}_t\right).\kern3em \left(\mathrm{forgone}\ \mathrm{work}\ \mathrm{time}\right) $$

Note that the labor supply of the adult worker is reduced by the time spent raising children. Using (5.1a), we can simplify the expression for human capital per family as.

$$ {\widehat{h}}_t={h}_t\frac{1+\beta }{1+\beta +\psi }.\kern3.25em \left(\mathrm{forgone}\ \mathrm{work}\ \mathrm{time}\right) $$

1.2 Optimal Fiscal Policy in a Closed Economy

Domestic fiscal policy is determined by maximizing (5.7) subject to the government budget constraint and the accumulation equations for private and public capital . The private household’s indirect utility function may be written as.

$$ {U}_t={U}_0+{\overline{U}}_t+\left(1+\beta \right)\ln \left(\left(1-{\tau}_t\right){w}_t{D}_t\right)+\beta \ln {R}_t+\psi \ln \left(\left(1-{\tau}_{t+1}\right){w}_{t+1}{D}_{t+1}\right), $$

where is a constant and is independent of fiscal policy. For the purpose of setting optimal fiscal policy, the government can then be modeled as choosing tax rates and public capital to maximize,

$$ \sum \limits_{t=0}^{\infty }{\beta}^t\left(\ln {c}_t^g+\phi \left\{\left(1+\beta \right)\ln \left(\left(1-{\tau}_t\right){w}_t{D}_t\right)+\beta \ln {R}_t+\psi \ln \left(\left(1-{\tau}_{t+1}\right){w}_{t+1}{D}_{t+1}\right)\right\}\right) $$
(5.7′)

subject to (5.4), (5.6), (5.8), and (5.9).

Substituting the constraints into the objective function and collecting common terms yields the following equivalent problem

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\underset{{\left\{{\tau}_{t+1},{g}_{t+1},{k}_{t+1}\right\}}_{t=0}^{\infty }}{\max}\sum \limits_{t=0}^{\infty }{\beta}^t\ln \left[{\tau}_t{k}_t^{\alpha }{g}_t^{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)}{\widehat{h}}_t-{g}_{t+1}\left(1+q\right){n}_{t+1}\right]\\ {}+\phi \sum \limits_{t=0}^{\infty }{\beta}^t\Big\{\left[\beta \left(\alpha -1\right)+\psi \alpha +\beta \alpha \left(1+\beta \right)\right]\ln {k}_{t+1}\\ {}+\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)\left[\left(\beta +\psi \right)+\beta \left(1+\beta \right)\right]\ln {g}_{t+1}+\left[\beta +\psi +\beta \left(1+\beta \right)\right]\ln \left(1-{\tau}_{t+1}\right)\Big\}\\ {}+\sum \limits_{t=1}^{\infty }{\lambda}_t\left\{\left[\frac{\beta }{1+\beta +\psi}\right]\frac{\left(1-{\tau}_{t-1}\right)\left(1-\alpha \right){k}_{t-1}^{\alpha }{g}_{t-1}^{\mu \left(1-\alpha \right)}{h}_{t-1}}{\left(1+q\right){n}_t{\widehat{h}}_t}-{k}_t\right\},\end{array}} $$

where λ is the multiplier associated with the private capital accumulation constraint.

To solve this sequence problem, begin by differentiating to get the first-order conditions for , for t ≥ 1. Be careful to differentiate wherever the choice variable appears in the objective function. Next, substitute into the first order conditions the “guess” , where B is an undetermined coefficient. Finally, solve the first order conditions for B, , , and to get (5.10).

A tricky part of the solution given by (5.10) involves the first order condition for . This equation, along with the first order condition for and the guess for the , can be used to solve for the expression by solving the following difference equation, \( {\lambda}_t{k}_t={\beta}^{t-1}\left\{\frac{\alpha \beta}{1-B}+\phi \left[\beta \left(\alpha -1\right)+\alpha \psi +\alpha \beta \left(1+\beta \right)\right]\right\}+{\alpha \lambda}_{t+1}{k}_{t+1} \), to get \( {\lambda}_t{k}_t=\frac{\beta^{t-1}}{1-\alpha \beta}\left\{\frac{\alpha \beta}{1-B}+\phi \left[\beta \left(\alpha -1\right)+\alpha \psi +\alpha \beta \left(1+\beta \right)\right]\right\} \). Use this solution to eliminate in the first order conditions for and . Using the guess for , these two first order conditions can be used to solve for and B to get \( {\tau}_t=\tau =\frac{1-\alpha \beta}{1+\left(1-\alpha \beta \right)\left(1-B\right)\phi \Gamma} \) and \( \mathrm{B}=\frac{\frac{\mu \beta \left(1-\alpha \right)}{1-\alpha \beta}+\mu \beta \left(1-\alpha \right)\phi \Gamma}{1+\mu \beta \left(1-\alpha \right)\phi \Gamma} \). Combining these two expressions, completes the solution.

1.3 Optimal Fiscal Policy in an Open Economy

In an open economy , the government’s problem can be written so that it solves

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\underset{{\left\{{\tau}_{t+1},{g}_{t+1}\right\}}_{t=0}^{\infty }}{\max}\sum \limits_{t=0}^{\infty }{\beta}^t\ln \left[{\tau}_t{\left(\frac{\left(1-{\tau}_t\right)\alpha }{r\ast}\right)}^{\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }}{g}_t^{\mu }{\widehat{h}}_t-{g}_{t+1}\left(1+q\right){n}_{t+1}\right]\\ {}+\phi \left[\psi +\beta \left(1+\beta \right)\right]\sum \limits_{t=0}^{\infty }{\beta}^t\left\{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}\ln \left(1-{\tau}_{t+1}\right)+\mu \ln {g}_{t+1}\right\}.\end{array}} $$

This problem differs from the closed economy problem because private capital intensity is now determined by international capital flows rather than domestic saving. In a closed economy, government policy affected private capital formation by affecting the after-tax wage of savers that fund the subsequent period’s private capital intensity. Now government policy affects private capital intensity by affecting the marginal product of private investments in the poor country—reduced by higher tax rates and raised by higher public capital intensity. In an open economy , government policy has a more immediate effect on private capital formation—this period’s policy affects this period’s capital intensity rather than this period’s saving flow and next period’s capital intensity.

Differentiating with respect to and generates first order conditions. As before guess a solution for g of the form.

$$ \left(1+q\right){n}_{t+1}{g}_{t+1}=B{\tau}_t{\left(\frac{\alpha \left(1-{\tau}_t\right)}{r\ast}\right)}^{\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }}{g}_t^{\mu }{\widehat{h}}_t. $$

Substitute into the first order conditions and solve for and B to get the solution in the text.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Das, S., Mourmouras, A., Rangazas, P. (2018). A Complete One-Sector Neoclassical Growth Model. In: Economic Growth and Development. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-89755-4_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics