Advertisement

From Robbins to Friedman and Beyond

Chapter
  • 363 Downloads

Abstract

In the early 1950s, Milton Friedman canonized neoclassical economics for his era of economists by accepting Robbins’ concept of scarcity as a core disciplinary concern and insisting that economists’ main concern was with “positive economics,” solely concerned with “what is,” not with what “ought to be” (the domain of “normative economics). He argued that economists’ empirical research must be guided by simplified models that need not, and could not, pass the test of descriptive reality. Indeed, he argued that no theory could be fully descriptive. Accordingly, “perfect rationality” and “perfect competition,” while lacking egregiously, in descriptiveness, were acceptable devices for analyses, especially if they eased analyses and if the predictions drawn from the models past repeated empirical tests. Neither Robbins nor Friedman made the economy within the human brain a central issue.

References

  1. Ariely, Dan. 2008. Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions. York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
  2. Becker, Gary S. 1971. The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press (originally published in 1957).Google Scholar
  3. Becker, Gary S. 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  4. Becker, Gary S. 1993. A Treatise on the Family (expanded edition). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Becker, Gary S. 1994. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Approach. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  6. Becker, Gary S. 1997. The Economics of Life. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  7. Brown, Charles, Curtis Gilroy, and Andrew Kohen. 1982. The effect of the minimum wage on employment and unemployment. Journal of Economic Literature 20: 487–528.Google Scholar
  8. Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. 1995. Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Editors. 1987. The right minimum wage: “$0.00.” New York Times, January 14.Google Scholar
  10. Friedman, Milton. 1953. The Methodology of Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  11. Friedman, Milton. 1976. Inflation and unemployment. Nobel Memorial Lecture, December 13.Google Scholar
  12. Hayek, F.A. 1943. Scientism and the study of society: Part II. Economica 10 (37): 34–63 (reprinted in Hayek, 2010).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Hayek, F.A. 1944. Scientism and the study of society: Part III. Economica 11 (41): 27–39 (reprinted in Hayek, 2010).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Kahneman, Daniel. 2011. Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
  15. Kosters, Marvin, and Finis Welch. 1972. The effects of minimum wages on the distribution of changes in aggregate employment. American Economic Review 62: 323–31.Google Scholar
  16. McKenzie, Richard B. 1994. Times Change: The Minimum Wage and the New York Times. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute.Google Scholar
  17. McKenzie, Richard B. 2014. Why are there so few job losses from minimum-wage hikes? Dallas: National Center for Policy Analysis, Study 354, April 9.Google Scholar
  18. Mises, Ludwig von. 1962. The Ultimate Foundation of Economics. New York: Martino Fine Books (republished in 2012).Google Scholar
  19. Neumark, David, and William L. Wascher. 2008. Minimum Wages. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Peterson, John M., and Charles T. Stewart. 1969. Employment Effects of Minimum Wage Rates. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.Google Scholar
  21. Ragan, James F. 1977. Minimum wages and the youth labor market. Review of Economics and Statistics 59: 129–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Robbins, Lionel. 1935. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Misses Institute (first published in 1932 and revised and reissued in 2007).Google Scholar
  23. Schabas, Margaret. 2014. A World Ruled by Number William Stanley Jevons and the Rise of Mathematical Economics Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Shepard R.N. 1981. Psychological complementarity. In Perceptual Organization, ed. M. Kubovy and J.R. Pomerantz, 279–342. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.Google Scholar
  25. Shepard, R.N. 1990. Mind Sights: Original Visual Illusions, Ambiguities, and Other Anomalies. New York: W.H. Freeman and Company.Google Scholar
  26. Stigler, George J. 1962. The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy 69 (June): 213–225.Google Scholar
  27. Stigler, George J., and Gary S. Becker. 1977. De gustibus non est disputandum. American Economic Review 67 (2, March): 76–90.Google Scholar
  28. Thaler, Richard H., and Cass R. Sunstein. 2008. Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Paul Merage School of BusinessUniversity of California, IrvineIrvineUSA

Personalised recommendations