Skip to main content
  • 834 Accesses

Abstract

The history of studies on bubbles and crashes is mired in misleading and flawed theory elegantly packaged in mathematical economics approaches that plainly don’t work: That’s because trading is always conducted in an open nonlinear system that noticeably destabilize as extreme market events unfold. Moreover, the underlying and still predominant efficient-market and capital asset pricing models were never designed nor intended to be used as platforms for the study of such events. Flaws in the rationality approach thus run so deep as to render the entire framework—as here surveyed for reference and historical perspective purposes—bereft of any ongoing analytical benefits.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 24.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Assumptions are that agents are risk -neutral, have rational expectations, and require a constant (real) rate of return on the asset, EtRt+i = k. The Euler equation is then Pt = δ(EtPt + 1 + EtDt + 1), where P is the price, D is the dividends, E is the mathematical expectations operator, and δ = 1/(1 + k) is the discounting factor. Cuthbertson and Nitzsche (2004, p. 398) explain: “The price you are prepared to pay today for a stock depends on the price you think you can obtain at some point in the future. But the latter depends on the expected price even further in the future…[T]he Euler equation does not rule out the possibility that the price may contain an explosive bubble.” An Euler equation is a general theorem of the calculus that appears as x1f1 +x2f2 = kf(x1,x2).

    After repeated forward substitutions and the assumption that what is known as a transversality condition holds (i.e., lim(δnEtDt + n = 0 as n → ∞), the formulation of a “rational bubble” that satisfies the Euler equation is expressed as:

    \( {P}_t=\sum \limits_{i=1}^{\infty }{\delta}^i{E}_t{D}_{t+1}+{B}_t={P}_t^f+{B}_t \), where Bt is the “rational bubble,” and “the actual market price Pt deviates from its fundamental value, \( {P}_t^f \) by the amount of the rational bubble Bt” (p. 399). As Bailey (2005, p. 241) writes, this suggests that “asset prices need not equal the NPV of future payoffs but can become any one of an infinite number of values according to the size of the bubble. The ‘bubble’ term captures all the speculative and self-fulfilling aspects of potentially wild asset price changes.”

    According to Cuthbertson and Nitzsche (2004, p. 401), individuals will pay prices above the fundamental price “as long as the bubble element yields them the required rate of return next period and is expected to persist…[I]n the real world, rational bubbles can really only exist if each individual’s horizon is shorter than the time period when the bubble is expected to burst…[O]ne would pay a price above the fundamental value because one believes that someone else will pay an even greater price in the future…investors are myopic.”

    From this point onward, however, assumptions and complications with the various rational bubble models begin to compound in terms of both model-specification complexities and problematic econometric testing assumptions. Cuthbertson and Nitzsche (2004, p. 408), for example, include in their list of econometric challenges:

    • Potentially nonstationary series using finite data sets

    • Behavior of asymptotic test statistics in the presence of explosive regressors

    • Obtaining precise estimates of nonlinear parameters

    • Corrections for heteroscedasticity and moving average errors

    • Difficulties in specification of correct equilibrium modes of expected returns

    Poundstone (2010, p. 9) questions entirely the notion that prices of anything can be firmly established over time. “Relative valuations are stable and coherent, while actual dollar amounts can be wildly arbitrary.” And Prechter writes in the April 2011 Elliott Wave Theorist that “the stock market never attaches to any benchmark of value, be it dividends, earnings, book values or the bond/stock yield spread. It is ceaselessly dynamic.” By illustration, over the past century, the price of $1 worth of S&P annual earnings based on trailing 12-month P/E ratios has ranged from around six times to more than 50 times (excluding rare years of losses when the ratio is infinite). Similarly, the price of $1 worth of annual DJIA dividends has had a range of 14 times and for book value around 19 times. In the 1940s and the early 1980s, $1 worth of S&P 400 book value was priced around $1.50 and, in the early 2000s, around $9.00. Poundstone (2010, p. 263) makes the same point.

  2. 2.

    To take account of the cost of money and uncertainty of payoff, the general mathematical representation of the LOOP is simply stated as pt+1 = f (mt, pt), where mt are discount factors and parameters and pt are prices (with pt+1 being the price one period ahead).

  3. 3.

    Interest in the rational expectations school of thought continued to grow and peaked in the 1980s, although it was not until 1995 that Robert Lucas, Jr., a leader in the field, was awarded the Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. But another Nobel Laureate, Gary Becker, says in O’Grady (2009), “There is a lot of debate in economics about whether we can understand bubbles within a rational framework.” And Garrison (2001) provides a detailed review of why RE doesn’t work from the Austrian school’s perspective. As Stiglitz (1990) explains with regard to the large body of work on rational expectations, the underlying issue is the movement of asset prices over time :

    If the asset price increased more slowly than the discount factor, eventually the terminal price became of negligible importance as viewed from today. Under such circumstances, the value of the asset had to be just equal to the discounted value of the stream of returns it generated, and no bubbles could exist. But as long as no one in the economy has an infinite planning horizon, there was nothing to ensure that this condition on prices (called the transversality condition) would be satisfied…If, for some asset, the rate of price increase equals (or exceeds) the rate of interest, then the share of the value of all assets accounted for by this asset would grow without bound, a condition inconsistent with long run equilibrium.

  4. 4.

    Evans (2003, p. 15) mentions this, and in Chap. 2, drawing on the comprehensive Raines and Leathers (2000), he surveys and compares competing theories. Keynes , for instance, is shown to be unsurprised by volatile departures from “intrinsic” values, and Toporowski (1999) views the market in nonequilibrium terms antithetical to the EMH approaches.

  5. 5.

    The Turnovsky (1996, pp. 59-60) representation of the rational expectations hypothesis is not much different from those used by others. Predictions generated by this model are conditional on information available at the time of prediction, with purely random price fluctuations around the forecast shown by the error term, et, which has zero mean. Turnovsky 1996, p. 137) writes that “most rational expectations models have been associated with saddlepoint behavior. That is, the dynamic system in which they are embedded involves both unstable and stable roots.”

  6. 6.

    The quotation is from Azariadis (1981). Theoretical embellishments include overlapping generation (OLG) models that take account of presumed intertemporal optimizing changes of consumer utility functions, but that also include what are known as “sunspot ” equilibria, the meaning of which, according to Azariadis and Guesnerie (1986),

    is still open to interpretation. One may view “ sunspots ” as a convenient label for a host of psychological factors (“animal spirits,” fears, Bayesian learning theories, etc.) that are unrelated to the preferences, endowment or production set of any individual, and yet come to influence the forecasts and actions of economic decision-makers…these factors have some pertinence for the explanation of…the Dutch tulip mania…and the Great Depression….Whatever it may denote, the concept of sunspot equilibrium seems to be of central importance for a thorough understanding of rational expectations as an equilibrium construct.

    This says that in some circumstances economic fundamentals alone will not be sufficient to determine equilibrium allocations and that psychological factors (i.e., extraneous variables or “sunspots”) eventually do matter. How investors interpret, feel about, and react to fundamentals may thus be important. Thus, following Tirole (1982), Blanchard and Fischer (1989, pp. 218–223) explain that “bubbles cannot arise when there is a finite number of individuals who have infinite horizons…if bubbles can exist in a general equilibrium, it must be because new players come into the game over time.” Duffy and Fisher (2005) advise that the “difficulty lies in identifying sunspot variables and isolating their effects from those of the fundamentals.” Their lab experiment found direct evidence of sunspot equilibria in a closed-book call market in which price determination is centralized. Such equilibria are sensitive to the flow of information. As an aside, the phrase “self -fulfilling prophecy” was coined by sociologist Robert K. Merton (and father of financial economist Robert C. Merton) in the Antioch Review, 1948. See Dunbar (2000, p. 19). In the article by Cass and Shell (1983), a sunspot is something that is intrinsically irrelevant but nonetheless influences prices. Benhabib et al. (2015) formalize a Keynesian rational expectations model showing that aggregate demand driven by sentiments (i.e., “animal spirits”) can generate output fluctuations and boom-bust cycles.

  7. 7.

    Kurz (1994) proposes that “the theory of expectations be reformulated under the assumption that agents do not know the structural relations (such as equilibrium prices) of the economy.”

  8. 8.

    Different implications of rationality assumptions appear in Kindleberger and Aliber (2011, p. 40). Maddala (2001, p. 420) shows that Muth required the prediction error, \( {(e)}_t={y}_t-{y}_t^{\ast } \), to be unbiased, with E(ε)t = 0. He also required that the prediction error be uncorrelated with the entire information set that is available to the forecaster at the time the prediction is made. It would seem at the outset that the use of such rational expectations models for the purpose of studying bubbles is already doomed to failure by this very assumption, which requires that at the inception of every new trade, automaton-like investors immediately erase from their memories any and all past information and emotions relating to previous trades. Evans (1991) explains the econometric weaknesses of REH studies.

    Several additional objections to the REH approach are raised because, for this approach to work, rather severe restrictive assumptions are required. For example, commonly shared information ought to be held unanimously and all relationships are assumed to be linear. But in a world in which information appears to be far from being perfectly distributed and relationships are probably far from linear, these model restrictions alone appear ab initio to limit practical applications. Lovell (1986) is also a skeptic, finding in a study of business firms that “the variance of anticipations is larger than the variance of the realizations, which is inconsistent with the rational expectations hypothesis…if the cumulative evidence is to be believed, we are compelled to conclude that expectations are a rich and varied phenomenon that is not adequately captured by the concept of rational expectations.”

    The Cagan (1956) model of hyperinflation is an early example suggesting that adaptive inflation expectations can be “rational,” but only under special assumptions. The Cagan REH approach allows, for example, according to Blanchard and Fischer (1989, pp. 218–23), “that the announcement of a future increase in the money stock itself increases the price level today. Real money balances decrease, and the price level slowly increases to its new higher level over time. Inflation therefore takes place in advance of the increase in the money stock.”

  9. 9.

    Tuckett (2011, p. x). Meltzer (1982) also wrote: “The models used to illustrate rational expectations typically endow people with more information than they usually have.”

  10. 10.

    The question and the arguments harken back to Friedman’s Essays in Positive Economics (1953) in which Keynes is quoted as saying that positive economics deals with what is not what ought to be. See also Brock (1991).

    Again, Shiller (2002b) places rational expectations in historical perspective:

    The efficient markets theory reached its height of dominance in academic circles around the 1970s. At that time, the rational expectations revolution in economic theory was in its first blush of enthusiasm…Prominent finance models of the 1970s related speculative asset prices to economic fundamentals , using rational expectations to tie together finance and the entire economy in one elegant theory…

    …efficient markets theory may lead to drastically incorrect interpretations of events such as major stock market bubbles. (p. 31)

  11. 11.

    Surveys in this area include Camerer (1989), Flood and Hodrick (1990), and Campbell (2000).

  12. 12.

    According to Greenwald et al. (2001, pp. 148–9), a further implication with respect to the EMH/CAPM is that “value investors reject both parts of the theory. They think stock selection does matter, and they do not accept the definition of risk as simply relative volatility…volatility is not the only and perhaps not even the best measure of risk.” Ederington and Guan (2005), in fact, indicate that adjusted mean absolute deviation might be a better measure. Also, in a BusinessWeek interview (April 9, 2007) with Peter Bernstein , Professor Elroy Dimson is quoted as saying “Risk means more things can happen than will happen.” This quotation also appears in Bernstein (2005b, p. 47) and is from Dimson’s earlier work. See also Zhang et al. (2016). The DCF methodology is also deceptive because both the cash flow estimates and discount-rate assumptions are highly uncertain (i.e., stochastic).

    Taleb (2007, p. 161) emphasizes that when making forecasts, “variability matters.” Bogle (2008) highlights the work of economist Frank H. Knight, who made the first distinction between the terms “risk”—a measureable quantity in which probabilities and distributions are known—and “uncertainty ,” which is immeasurable and thus not subject to probabilities. And commodity trader, Richard Dennis , is quoted in Covel (2007, p. 23) as saying, “One man’s volatility is another man’s profit.”

  13. 13.

    Hansen and Renault (2009) describe pricing kernels or stochastic discount factors as being used to represent valuation operators. Such operators are built as “mappings that assign prices that trade in competitive markets to payoffs on portfolios of assets.” This is all related to the law of one price.

  14. 14.

    See also Miao (2014).

  15. 15.

    See Henriques (2008).

  16. 16.

    Among the many studies of short-selling bans and regulations, see Saffi and Sigurdsson (2011), Beber and Pagano (2013), and Jain et al. (2013). Napoleon labeled short-sellers “enemies of the state,” England banned the practice from 1733 until the middle of the nineteenth century, and short-selling was illegal in New York State in the early 1800s. See Surowiecki (2004, p. 225).

  17. 17.

    Tirole (1982) adds, “the price has to grow faster during the duration of the bubble…for the asset holders to be compensated for the probability of a crash.” McQueen and Thorley (1994) similarly say, “The probability of a high return exactly compensates investors for the probability of a crash; the model shows the rationality of staying in the market despite the overvaluation.”

  18. 18.

    Using traditional methods—in which the number of positive abnormal returns within a period suspected of containing bubbles is counted—Hardouvelis (1988) further notes that “[I]nstead of testing directly the null hypothesis of speculative bubbles, they test the null hypothesis that stock prices are priced rationally, and then interpret a possible rejection of this null hypothesis as evidence that speculative bubbles may be present. Since these methods are indirect, they have very little power to detect speculative bubbles.” See also Scheinkman and Xiong (2003).

  19. 19.

    This appears in Gay et al. (1994).

  20. 20.

    Hillier (1997, pp. 3–5) explains that asymmetric information problems fall into three categories: selection of projects, hidden actions, and costly state verification.

  21. 21.

    They go on to show that “[T]he simplest is that of a deterministic bubble, ct = c0θt.” In this case the higher price is justified by the higher capital gain and the deviations grow exponentially.

  22. 22.

    In comparing the Blanchard and Watson (1982) to the Abreu and Brunnermeier (2003) approach, Chamley (2004, p. 383) explains that in “Blanchard , the growth rate of the bubble price must be higher than the market rate to compensate for the probability of the crash, as all agents are informed.” But in Abreu and Brunnermeier , “the growth rate of the price bubble does not need to be as high, because only a fraction of the agents are informed.”

  23. 23.

    As Jeremy Grantham said in GMO’s January 2005 Quarterly Letter (p. 5), “one of the paradoxes…is that reducing or avoiding real risk in portfolios can seriously increase career and business risk, which rises with any deviation from standard behavior.” Hong et al. (2000) cited in Cassidy (2009a, p. 178) found that “being bold and good does not significantly improve an analyst’s future career prospects.” A similar finding for fund managers appears in Chevalier and Ellison (1999). See also Guerrieri and Kondor (2012) and Sato (2016).

    Grantham , in the GMO October 2006 Quarterly Letter (p. 4) and in Barron’s of November 6, 2006, later observes that “Great Lakes Dock & Dredge, Hartford Steam Boiler and Twin Disc Clutch made clients feel much worse, apparently, than losing the same money in Avon, IBM and Johnson & Johnson.” The implication is that investment in the most popular stocks carries a lower career risk even though the losses may be the same with less popular names. In the GMO April 2007 Quarterly Letter, he observes that the necessary conditions for bubbles to form are that “the fundamental economic conditions must appear to be excellent…and liquidity must be generous in quantity and price: it must be easy and cheap to leverage.” He calls the early 2007 experience the “first truly global bubble” in which the risk premiums for the three major asset classes—stocks, bonds, and real estate—reached historic lows everywhere.

  24. 24.

    In using equal-weighted and value-weighted monthly data of major exchange indices, Harman (2000, p. 266) questions whether duration dependence tests have the power adequate to detect speculative bubbles in stock prices. “[T]he type of hazard function used and the frequency at which returns were measured had an effect on the results.” Serial dependence is covered by Kritzman (1994). Another study relevant to duration dependence by Harman and Zuehlke (2004) points to “some troublesome issues” and “calls into question the efficacy of using hazard models to test for speculative bubbles.”

  25. 25.

    Pierdzioch (2010) found that periodically collapsing bubbles in the pre-WWI German stock market cannot be ruled out.

  26. 26.

    Other papers that touch on the topic of runs tests include Blanchard and Watson (1982), Meese (1986), West (1987), and Woo (1987).

  27. 27.

    See Gerlis (2014a, b) about art as an investable asset. See also Ekelund (2017).

  28. 28.

    Nobel Laureate Vernon Smith began experimental economics in Smith (1962). An example of its application is in Henker and Owen (2008). Laboratory asset market experiments by Lei et al. (2001) suggest (counterintuitively and unrealistically, in my opinion) that even when speculation is not possible, bubbles and crashes still emerge. Gjerstad and Smith (2009) write, “Bubbles can arise when some agents buy not on fundamental value, but on price trend or momentum. If momentum traders have more liquidity, they can sustain a bubble longer.” Smith’s laboratory approach also suggests that people who experience bubbles more than once tend to learn from their first-round experience, with later bubbles not as pronounced. This is discussed in Hussam et al. (2008) and in Caginalp et al. (2000). Greenwood and Nagel (2008), also showed that more experienced fund managers in the TMT bubble were better at recognizing the bubble and avoiding it than were the younger ones. Experiments in Haruvy et al. (2007) indicate that individuals hold beliefs conditioned on past trends and that traders don’t initially anticipate market downturns. Palan (2009) surveys experimental economics literature and suggests that the efficiency of markets might be improved through the use of derivative forward-looking options. Poundstone (2010, p. 263) cites similar experiments by Colin Camerer. See also Ackert et al. (2009) and Andrade et al. (2016) on types of recently seen films affecting subsequent trading activity.

  29. 29.

    Several Ph.D. dissertations have focused on bubbles include Harman (2000), who analyzes “characteristics of securities to determine whether bubbles form more readily in the prices of some securities than in the prices of others.” Harman examines bubbles from the standpoint of institutional investors and finds “evidence of skewness , kurtosis, and serial dependence in returns that is consistent with asset price bubbles.” She also finds that “investor herding is present during periods identified as having characteristics consistent with speculative bubbles,” that “investors herd on both positive and negative returns,” and that there is evidence “of a positive relationship between changes in institutional ownership and measures of abnormal volume.” Other dissertations of interest include those of Golden (1995), Aksoy (1997), Porras-Gonzalez (2000), Ali (2003), and Smith (2003).

  30. 30.

    The definitional approach that comes mathematically closest to the current work was provided by Watanabe et al. (2007), in which divergent and convergent expressions of recent prices are exponentially fitted for the purpose of defining bubbles and crashes emanating from the TMT mania of the late 1990s. The Watanabe approach, however, is entirely mechanistic and, like vector autoregression models, atheoretical.

  31. 31.

    West (1987) tests for bubbles using the specification test of Hausman by comparing two sets of estimated parameters that calculate the expected present discounted value (PDV ) of a stock’s dividend stream. The null hypothesis is that prices are in accord with a standard EMH model. “Speculative bubbles are tested for, then, by seeing whether the two sets of estimates are the same…The data reject the null hypothesis of no bubbles.” Another approach is shown in Engsted and Tanggaard (2004), who constructed a test for speculative bubbles based on the price/dividend ratio, with the idea that if there are no bubbles, the P/D ratio can be decomposed into different covariances. The results suggest that “up to the late 1980s, there are not strong indications of bubbles in U.S. stock prices. However, by including data from the 1990s, there is some evidence of the presence of speculative bubbles.”

  32. 32.

    Dezhbakhsh and Demirguc-Kunt (1990) applied what is known as a regression equation specification error test (RESET) even though the test, because of its behavioral symmetry, admittedly does not discriminate between bubbles and fads. Additional tests for self-fulfilling speculative price bubbles, discussed in Hamilton (1986), may also be applicable here. Fukuta (2002) examines via cointegration techniques two necessary conditions for the absence of rational bubbles while assuming that the discount rate is stationary.

  33. 33.

    With the Sola and Driffill approach, the explanatory importance of a bubble in accounting for the divergence of stock price trends from expected dividend trends is relatively low. A Markov-switching unit root test approach for detecting periodically collapsing bubbles is further explored by Hall et al. (1999), who propose use of a generalized Dickey -Fuller procedure to identify collapsing periods from expanding ones. On regime switching see also Driffill and Sola (2001). Evans (1991) examines pitfalls in testing for explosive bubbles. Charemza and Deadman (1995) highlight the failure of unit root testing, and Psaradakis et al. (2001) note that “tests for unit roots and cointegration may fail to detect the presence of explosive rational bubbles that collapse periodically.” On using unit root tests (augmented Dickey -Fuller), see also Hamilton and Whiteman (1985), Campbell and Perron (1991), Craine (1993), and Taipalus (2012).

  34. 34.

    Cointegration, for example, is a method for analyzing long-run relationships between nonstationary variables and has often been used to test the rational expectations and market efficiency hypotheses. The methodology is covered by Dickey et al. (1991) and by Maddala and Kim (1999). Cointegration aspects of bubbles are noted in Campbell and Shiller (1987), Froot and Obstfeld (1991), Barsky and DeLong (1993), and Gujarati (1995, p. 726). From Sarno and Taylor (1999):

    If stock prices and dividends are realizations of I(1)(difference-stationary) processes, then in the absence of bubbles the standard present value model of stock prices implies cointegration between the stock price and dividend series…If the stock price series contains an explosive bubble term, however, which is not by definition in the dividend price series, then this will drive a wedge between prices and dividends so that they will not be cointegrated.

    The vector autoregression (VAR) approach, as described by Maddala (2001, p. 544), “is a multiple time-series generalization…easy to estimate because we can use the OLS [ordinary least squares] method.”

  35. 35.

    Such direct tests, focused on the presence of deterministic bubbles, include those found in Flood and Garber (1980), McQueen and Thorley (1994), Van Norden (1996), and Schaller and van Norden (1997).

  36. 36.

    A test that does not require a detailed specification of the underlying equilibrium model was designed by Diba and Grossman (1988). In this study, the explosive price action of a rational bubble is such that prices and fundamentals follow a different path, that is, prices and fundamentals will not be cointegrated. The advantage of this approach is that the researcher does not have to specify all the details of the equilibrium model. Still, the main drawback of the Diba and Grossman method is that it will generally have difficulty in discovering bubbles that successively grow over time and partially burst.

    West (1987) provides a specification test for rational speculative bubbles based on estimates of the underlying equilibrium model using two different techniques. From Engsted and Tanggaard (2002):

    …one technique gives consistent estimates of the model parameters both with and without bubbles. The other technique gives consistent estimates if there are no bubbles, but inconsistent estimates if there is a bubble (provided the bubble is correlated with fundamentals ). Thus, under the null hypothesis of no bubbles, the two sets of estimates should be equal. If the null is rejected, it indicates the presence of bubbles. A drawback of this test is that it requires detailed specification of the underlying equilibrium model, so rejection of the no bubble hypothesis may not be due to bubbles but may instead be due to imposition of the wrong model.

  37. 37.

    As implied in Greene (2003, p. 631) and also Mills (1990, p. 69), stationarity guarantees that all moments such as the mean and variance exist, are independent of time, and are finite. See also Gujarati (1995, p. 719), Hendry (1995, p. 44), and Favero (2001, p. 39).

  38. 38.

    Econometricians have thus devised tests for stationarity, among which the unit root test is perhaps the most popular. In West’s tests, for instance, a model using discounted stock dividends requires a specific assumption about whether the discount rate is stationary or time-varying (and also a model of what generates such variation), whereas in the Diba and Grossman (1988) approach it doesn’t matter whether the discount factor applied to future dividends varies as long as the series itself is stationary.

  39. 39.

    In media-related stocks, Time Warner had responded to the 2006 breakup threat by corporate activist Carl Icahn by repurchasing $20 billion worth of shares at prices around $18. By 2008, the remaining shares had traded down to $9. Percentage declines of Viacom and CBS shares in the face of sizable repurchase programs were even steeper. And from 2006 onward GE had been repurchasing nearly $25 billion of shares at as high as $40 in 2007/2008, but this didn’t prevent shares from falling to $13 in late 2008. At the urging of activist Trian Fund, GE then from 2014-17 wasted $29 billion on share repurchases at prices averaging $30, more than double the early 2018 price. GE was then unable to comfortably support pension liabilities and an already reduced dividend. See also Grullon and Michaely (2002).

  40. 40.

    Higher regulatory and other related costs, meanwhile diminished the number of IPOs even as mergers and private equity takeovers reduced the number of domestic companies listed on U. S. exchanges from a peak of 8,025 in 1996 to 4,333 in 2016.

  41. 41.

    See Laherrère and Sornette (1998) and Chang and Feigenbaum (2006).

  42. 42.

    Malliaris (2012) breaks this literature into four categories:a) Papers that assume all investors to be rational and have identical information. In these, finite bubbles cannot exist;b) Investors have rational expectations but asymmetric information. Bubbles might develop more easily under such conditions;c) Investors might be either rational or behavioral in reactions and bubbles can last a long time;d) Traders have heterogeneous beliefs and bubbles can emerge.

  43. 43.

    Sornette (2003a, p. 153) suggests, “The market return from today to tomorrow is proportional to the crash hazard rate…the higher the risk of a crash, the larger is the price return. In essence, investors must be compensated by a higher return in order to be induced to hold an asset that might crash.”

  44. 44.

    About Elliott’s work, see the February and June 1999 Scientific American and also Elliott (1938), who apparently was first to describe stock market price patterns as being “fractal .” Prechter (2004) says that such self-similarity at different scales was foreshadowed by Goethe in 1790 and then by the mathematician Georg Cantor a hundred years later. The basic Elliott idea can be described as follows: A line of length c is partitioned into segment lengths a and b. The ratio of the first segment, a, to the second, b, is made equal to the ratio of the second segment, b, to the total, c. The equation is then a/b = b/(a+b) = b/c. Setting b = 1 as the scale of measurement, the equation becomes a = 1/(a + 1), or a2 + a – 1 = 0. The two solutions for a are then 0.618 (the “golden mean”) and −1.618. See also Chap. 10, note 15 and Sornette (2003b) and Gresnigt et al. (2015) in which crashes are modeled as being akin to earthquakes.

  45. 45.

    Bourke (1998) describes 1/f noise.

  46. 46.

    Pareto (Zipf’s) law has also been used to compare the number of cities in the world and the number of inhabitants. The income or revenue of a company as a function of the rank is another example of the law, which as Li (1999) has noted should be called Pareto’s law because Pareto observed this at the end of the 1800s.

  47. 47.

    See Pierce (1980, p. 87), Farmer and Lillo (2004), and Gabaix (2009).

  48. 48.

    There may be instances in which a function seems to follow a power law (i.e., be exponential) but in actuality does not. But a study by Ijiri and Simon (1974) showed that rejecting the Pareto law (i.e., a power law) in favor of a downwardly concave relationship between log-size and log-rank is consistent with positively autocorrelated growth rates. This would then suggest that a power law might still be used as an approximation and that autocorrelation might be more broadly applied. Among the papers in this area are those by Laherrère and Sornette (1998), Li (1999), Rousseau (1999), Urzua (2000), and Limpert et al. (2001).

    Skepticism as to the full applicability of power laws to a wide variety of physical and economic data is also the theme of Laherrère and Sornette (1998), who instead propose use of a complementary alternative known as a stretched exponential family of probability density functions (pdfs). The problem is that such log-log plots “often display linearity over a limited range of scales and/or exhibit noticeable curvature.” In their comparisons of fit, they found that stretched exponential pdfs “account remarkably well for the center of most analyzed distributions…and have a tail that is ‘fatter’ than the exponential but much less so than a pure power law distribution…being economical in their number of adjustable parameters.” See also Geraskin and Fantazzini (2013).

  49. 49.

    From West (2017, p. 142): “…it turns out that the patterns of fluctuations in financial markets…are simply nonlinearly scaled versions of one another...the behavior of the stock market is a self-similar fractal pattern that repeats itself across all timescales following a power law that can be quantified by its exponent.

  50. 50.

    Bikhchandani and Sharma (2001) provide an overview of herding. However, the best contextually developed sources are Prechter (2001, 2016). Mass psychology leading toward herding and synchronicity is covered by Strogatz (2003, pp. 1–3).

  51. 51.

    An attractor, as Hilborn (2000, p. 22) explains, “is that set of points to which trajectories approach as the number of iterations goes to infinity.” The trajectory or orbit is the sequence of position values as measured over time and is analogous to, say, the path of a planet orbiting the sun . Williams (1997, p. 14) has additionally advised that “chaos analysis can reveal the time-limits of reliable predictions and can identify conditions where long-term forecasting is largely meaningless.” There is indeed a value to knowing ahead of time when something cannot be predicted, but chaos theory is weak in revealing details of a particular underlying physical law or governing equation.

  52. 52.

    Serletis (1996) adds that “chaotic processes have first and second moment properties that are the same as for white noise processes.”

  53. 53.

    Chaos theory methods, according to Hsieh (1991), make possible the description of a rich variety of nonlinear situations that are commonly found in financial market economics. Says Serletis (1996, p. 211), “[T]he existence of chaos creates the possibility that profitable nonlinearity-based trading rules may exist, raising questions about the efficient markets hypothesis.”

  54. 54.

    Serletis: “The most important tool for diagnosing the presence of sensitive dependence on initial conditions (and thereby chaoticity) is provided by the dominant Lyapunov exponent. The exponent measures the average exponential divergence or convergence between (state-space) trajectories that have ‘infinitesimally’ small differences in their initial conditions. A positive Lyapunov exponent is an operational definition of chaotic behavior.”

    Lyapunov-exponent methods are widely used in searching for such attractors. These exponents are based on the idea that in time-series regions governed by chaos, the most significant feature is sensitive dependence on initial conditions (SDIC). This means that even a small change at the beginning of the data series results in enormous changes down the line. But it also means that long-term forecasts cannot be made.

    Bulow and Klemperer (1994) explain frenzies by focusing on the idea that “in the real world, buyers and sellers can choose when to trade…A further result is that the price path is highly sensitive to small changes in the underlying demand structure.” See also Williams (1997, pp. 355–70) and Theiler et al. (1992).

  55. 55.

    Liu et al. (1992) found that the correlation exponent test of chaos theory could distinguish white noise from chaos (but could not distinguish white noise from chaos mixed with a small amount of white noise). Their paper advises instead that the well-known BDS test (Brock et al. 1996) is perhaps more effective in distinguishing between linear and nonlinear stochastic processes. The classic papers of Grassberger and Procaccia (1983a, b) showed how the correlation dimension could be used to detect attractors in both standard and lagged phase space. See also Takens (1981), Wolf et al. (1985), Rasband (1990, p. 75), and Hilborn (2000, p. 376). Gleick (1987) provides a popular overview.

    As for the BDS test, Serletis and Dormaar (1996, p. 116) nevertheless say, “The BDS test does not currently provide a direct test for nonlinearity or for chaos, because the sampling distribution of the test statistic is not known (either in finite samples or asymptotically) under the null hypothesis of nonlinearity, linearity, or chaos. It is, however, possible to use the BDS test to produce indirect evidence about nonlinear dependence…which is necessary but not sufficient for chaos.” See also Brock (1986).

  56. 56.

    See Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973).

  57. 57.

    Falconer (2013, p. 87). Very small such random steps taken rapidly at small intervals t with length \( \sqrt{t} \) lead to a fractal Brownian motion form. See also Hassler (2016), Cox and Hobson (2005), Heston et al. (2007), Jarrow et al. (2010, 2011), Cieplinski et al. (2012), and Herzog (2015). Brownian noise is, of course, the random walk under a different name. It is an example of a martingale process, in which the best forecast of xt+1 that could be determined on the basis of current information, Ωt, equals xt.

  58. 58.

    The EMH construct crumbles when the correlations among the returns of individual securities and different asset classes rise toward unity, as they alway do in extreme events (e.g., Fig. 2.8).

  59. 59.

    Dardik (2017, p. 130) writes in relation to science in general that “[M]athematics does not work where there is high variability, or a high degree of complexity, within or across scales.” That is, for instance, bubbles and crashes.

  60. 60.

    Wilmott and Orrell (2017, pp. 140–7) write: “…it is no longer correct to say that the volatility is a single parameter– it is a whole series of separate parameters, which apply to different prices and dates.” Bookstaber (2017, pp. 17–8) adds that markets are not ergodic, a term that describes a process that doesn’t vary with time or experience and continues to follow the same probabilities as in the past. “This works for physics. And for the game of roulette…Our world is not ergodic – yet economists treat it as though it is.”

  61. 61.

    Brunnermeier (2001, p. 59) adds: “…almost all bubbles can be ruled out in a symmetric information setting.”

  62. 62.

    Buchanan (2013, pp. 29–49) provides a concise history of equilibrium-thinking economics and of the different meanings ascribed to the word “efficiency.”

  63. 63.

    See also McCauley (2004, p. 6) and Farmer and Geanakoplos (2009, p. 17). Wilmott and Orrell (2017) also question the notion of equilibrium.

  64. 64.

    Spotton and Rowley (1998) write that the simple premise that “fundamental ” present value of discounted stream of dividends and earnings governs asset and prices is a corresponding

    implicitly compromised by the severity of its main requirements for constituents and a corresponding reliance on supplemental assumptions (representative individuals, atomistic markets, very rapid and sensitive adjustments…and an effective and immediate…dynamic process of arbitrage )…Trading risk against anticipated return, the rational investors choose current portfolios, seemingly free from the activities of others…the commitment to EMH often stems from a prior conviction that efficiency is clearly desirable…rather than from a clear evidential basis.

    The random -walk/EMH approach and the presumed rationality of investors in the REH are actually separate issues that are not necessarily linked, even though the two notions often confusingly appear together in the literature.

  65. 65.

    Taylor (2005, p. 69) agrees, writing, “It is very clear that the returns -generating process is not even approximately Gaussian.” And in Baker-Said (2008), Taleb explains that quant models typically make at least four errors: (a) narrativity , in which people hedge for what makes sense even though things that can happen don’t make sense at the time; (b) low volatility, in which the mistake is that low volatility does not mean low risk; (c) blindfoldedness, in which most people take risks even when they don’t know what risks they are incurring; and (d) stress testing, in which the most dangerous unforeseen events are not tested.

    Patterson (2010b, p. 57) writes that Lévy studied distributions in which a single sample made an important change to the curve. Fox (2009, p. 7) writes that Henri Poincaré, the great French mathematician and thesis supervisor of Bachelier, thought with regard to the Gaussian distribution that “caution needed to be exercised in applying it to human behavior.” Jovanovic and Schinckus (2017, p. 2) recall that a French banker’s assistant, Jules Regnault, in 1863 first began to represent market variations using a random-walk approach.

  66. 66.

    The belief remains that there is an equilibrium “fundamental” value that might somehow be found if only the right models were to be specified . Gilles and LeRoy (1992) indicate that the difficulties already begin with coming to an understanding of what is meant by the terms “fundamental” and “speculative bubble.” A source of the confusion, they say, is that “fundamental” is used to describe “sunspot as well as bubble equilibria.” See also Allen et al. (1993) and Brunnermeier (2001, p. 50), who say that sunspots “serve as a coordination device for the agents in the economy to select a particular static price equilibrium.”

    Bailey (2005, Chapter 1) describes markets that can be “efficient” in several different ways: allocative, operational, informational, and portfolio structure. And Bray (1985) says that “Employing the rational expectations hypothesis imposes two logical requirements, that objective probability distributions exist, and that rational expectations equilibrium exists.”

  67. 67.

    Robert Lucas, Jr., a pioneer proponent of the REH, in fact later found the theory to be flawed because it is not reasonable to believe that humans are perfectly rational or perfectly informed. Much of this theory “worked” only after making such idealistic assumptions. In the strict Lucas REH approach, there are no bubbles and banking crises.

  68. 68.

    Kindleberger (1996, [1989], p. 21).

  69. 69.

    Kahneman (2013, pp. 49, 411). “ The only test of rationality is not whether a person’s beliefs and preferences are reasonable, but whether they are internally consistent.”

  70. 70.

    Lim (2015, p. 139 and 155).

  71. 71.

    In an overview of modern financial economics, Cochrane (2005, p. 4) states that if the marginal utility of consumption, c, in period t+1 versus that in period t is taken into account, it can be shown that “bubbles”—“in which the prices grow so fast that people will buy now just to resell at higher prices later, even if there are no dividends”—are ruled out (p. 25). By contrast, the portfolio approach to asset pricing as in the CAPM and ICAPM relies heavily on the assumption that the investor has no non-asset income (p. 36)…the CAPM and ICAPM are not alternatives to the consumption -based model: “they are special cases of that model” (p. 169). Even Fama and French (2004) conclude that the early versions of the CAPM have “never been an empirical success…[T]he problems are serious enough to invalidate most applications of the CAPM.”

  72. 72.

    From Cochrane (2005, p. 23). Barberis et al. (2001) develop a model in which investors derive direct utility not only from consumption but also from fluctuations in wealth. Their model allows for changes in risk aversion, incorporates aspects of prospect theory from behavioral finance, and also helps to explain excess volatility, predictability of returns, and a low correlation with consumption growth.

  73. 73.

    Bailey (2005, p. 65) adds: “Without a criterion for separating what is fundamental from what is not, the distinctiveness of the EMH evaporates.”

  74. 74.

    As per Prechter (2016, pp. 506–10).

  75. 75.

    The emotional tail is explored in a somewhat different context by Haidt (2001).

  76. 76.

    See Forbes (2009). Bookstaber (2017, p. 183) writes that with a deductive approach “[Y]ou could be only somewhat right, and you can find many ways to be completely and precisely wrong.”

  77. 77.

    The quotation also appears in Mehrling (2005, p. 13) and in Triana (2009, p. 53). Bernstein (2007, p. 214) adds that when Black moved from MIT near Boston to Goldman Sachs in New York in 1984, he said, “The market appears a lot more efficient on the banks of the Charles River than it does on the banks of the Hudson .” The quote is also in Mehrling , p. 246. Sharpe would also obviously agree with the sentiment. In a discussion with Bernstein (2007, p. 94), Sharpe says, “…how in the world can you measure expectations, which are a look forward, not backward? You cannot just look at history and deduce much about what expectations have been – or would be. The whole matter revolves around the future. Therefore, the historical data on which we all depend so heavily may be useless for asset pricing.”

    Lowenstein (2008a) similarly writes, “Modern finance is an antiseptic discipline; it eschews anecdotes and examples, which are messy and possibly misleading — but nonetheless real. It favors abstraction, which is perfect but theoretical. Rather than evaluate financial assets case by case, financial models rely on the notion of randomness, which has huge implications for diversification. It means two investments are safer than one, three safer than two.”

  78. 78.

    In commenting on the EMH, Buchan (1997, p. 240) says, “The efficient -markets doctrine is merely another attempt to apply rational laws to an arena that is self-evidently irrational. A market cannot operate by laws, for the laws would be discovered, and it would cease to be a market.”

References

  • Abreu, D., & Brunnermeier, M. K. (2003). Bubbles and Crashes. Econometrica, 71, 173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ackert, L. F., Charupat, N., Deaves, R., & Kluger, B. D. (2009). Probability Judgment Error and Speculation in Laboratory Asset Market Bubbles. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44(3), 719–744.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adam, M. C., & Szafarz, A. (1992). Speculative Bubbles and Financial Markets. Oxford Economic Papers, 44, 626.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahamed, L. (2009). Lords of Finance: The Bankers Who Broke the World. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aksoy, L. (1997). A Nash Equilibrium Solution for Stock Market Crashes. Unpublished PhD Dissertation, City University of New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ali, M. F. (2003). Stock Market Bubbles, Time-Varying Risk Premia, and Monetary Policy. Unpublished PhD Dissertation, George Mason University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., & Gorton, G. (1993). Churning Bubbles. Review of Economic Studies, 60(4), 813–836.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., Morris, S., & Postlewaite, A. (1993). Finite Bubbles with Short Sale Constraints and Asymmetric Information. Journal of Economic Theory, 61, 206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrade, E. B., Odean, T., & Lin, S. (2016). “Bubbling with Excitement: An Experiment, “ Review of Finance, 20(2)(March)

    Google Scholar 

  • Angeletos, G.-M., & La’O, J. (2013). Sentiments. Econometrica, 81(2), 739–779.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asako, K. (1991). The Land Price Bubble in Japan. Ricerche Economiche, XLV(2–3).

    Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C. (1981). Self-Fulfilling Prophecies. Journal of Economic Theory, 25(3), 380–396.

    Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C., & Guesnerie, R. (1986). Sunspots and Cycles. Review of Economic Studies, 53(5), 725–737.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, R. E. (2005). The Economics of Financial Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker-Said, S. (2008, May). Flight of the Black Swan. Bloomberg Markets.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barberis, N., Huang, M., & Santos, T. (2001). Prospect Theory and Asset Prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXVI(1), 1–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barsky, R. B., & DeLong, J. B. (1993). Why Does the Stock Market Fluctuate? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(2), 291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beber, A., & Pagano, M. (2013). Short-Selling Bans Around the World: Evidence from the 2007–09 Crisis. Journal of Finance, 68(1), 343–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Wang, P., & Wen, Y. (2015). Sentiments and Aggregate Demand Fluctuations. Econometrica, 83(2), 549–585.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, P. L. (2005b). Capital Ideas: The Improbable Origins of Modern Wall Street. Hoboken: Wiley (Paperback ed.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, P. L. (2007). Capital Ideas Evolving. Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhar, R., & Malliaris, A. G. (2005). Are There Rational Bubbles in the U.S. Stock Market? Overview and a New Test. In Malliaris (2005).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bikhchandani, S., & Sharma, S. (2001). Herd Behavior in Financial Markets. IMF Staff Papers, 47(3), 279–310. Washington, DC: IMF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger, M. (1999). Stock Markets, Speculative Bubbles and Economic Growth. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, F., & Scholes, M. (1973). The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81(3), 637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. J. (1979). Speculative Bubbles, Crashes and Rational Expectations. Economics Letters, 3(4).

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. J., & Fischer, S. (1989). Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. J., & Watson, M. W. (1982). Bubbles, Rational Expectations, and Financial Markets. In P. Wachtel (Ed.), Crises in the Economic and Financial Structure. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bogle, J. C. (2008). Black Monday and Black Swans. Financial Analysts Journal, 64(2), 30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohl, M. T. (2001). Periodically Collapsing Bubbles in the U.S. Stock Market. Working Paper Series, No. 6. Frankfurt: European University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bookstaber, R. (2017). The End of Theory: Financial Crises, the Failure of Economics, and the Sweep of Human Interaction. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourke, P. (1998). Generating Noise with Different Power Spectra Laws. Available at http://astronomy.swin.edu.au/~pbourke/fractals/noise/

  • Brav, A., & Heaton, J. B. (2002). Competing Theories of Financial Anomalies. Review of Financial Studies, 15(2), 575.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bray, M. (1985). Rational Expectations, Information and Asset Markets: An Introduction. Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 37(2)161–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A. (1986). Distinguishing Random and Deterministic Systems. Journal of Economic Theory, 40, 168–195. (Abridged version).

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A. (1991). Causality, Chaos, Explanation, and Prediction in Economics and Finance. In J. Casti & A. Karlqvist (Eds.), Beyond Belief: Randomness, Predition, and Explanation in Science. Boca Raton: FL. CRC Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A. (2000). Chaos Theory. In Smelser and Baltsis (2001) (Eds.), International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Sciences. London: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., Decehert, J. A., Scheinkman, J. A., & LeBaron, B. (1996). A Test for Independence Based on the Correlation Dimension. Econometric Reviews, 15(3), 197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, C., & Katsaris, A. (2003). Regime Switching Models of Speculative Bubbles with Volume: An Empirical Investigation of the S&P 500 Composite Index. Reading: IMSA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M. K. (2001). Asset Pricing Under Asymmetric Information: Bubbles, Crashes, Technical Analysis, and Herding. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., & Nagel, S. (2004, October). Hedge Funds and the Technology Bubble. Journal of Finance, LIX(6) and AFA 2004 San Diego Meetings; EFA 2003 Annual Conference Paper No. 446. Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=423940

  • Buchan, J. (1997). Frozen Desire: The Meaning of Money. New York: Farrar Straus Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, M. (2013). Forecast: What Physics, Meteorology, and the Natural Sciences Can Teach Us About Economics. New York: Bloomsbury.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulow, J., & Klemperer, P. (1994). Rational Frenzies and Crashes. Journal of Political Economy, 102(1), 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cagan, P. (1956). The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation. In M. Friedman (Ed.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caginalp, G., Porter, D., & Smith, V. L. (2000). Overreactions, Momentum, Liquidity, and Price Bubbles in Laboratory and Field Asset Markets. Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets, 1(1), 24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F. (1989). An Experimental Test of Several Generalized Utility Theories. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 2, 61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y. (2000). Asset Pricing at the Millennium. Journal of Finance, 55, 1515.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y., & Perron, P. (1991). Pitfalls and Opportunities: What Macroeconomists Should Know About Unit Roots. NBER Technical Working Paper No. 100 in Macroeconomics Annual 1991, National Bureau of Economic Research. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. J. (1987). Cointegration and Tests of Present Value Models. Journal of Political Economy, 95(5), 1062–1088.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y., Lo, A. W., & MacKinlay, A. C. (1997). The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Case, K., & Shiller, R. J. (1989). The Efficiency of the Market for Single-Family Homes. American Economic Review, 79(1), 125–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cass, D., & Shell, K. (1983). Do Sunspots Matter? Journal of Political Economy, 91(2), 193–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassidy, J. (2009). How Markets Fail: The Logic of Economic Calamities. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casti, J., & Karlqvist, A. (Eds.). (1991). Beyond Belief: Randomness, Prediction, and Explanation in Science. Boca Raton: CRC Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamley, C. P. (2004). Rational Herds: Economic Models of Social Learning. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K., McQueen, G., & Thorley, S. (1998). Are There Rational Speculative Bubbles in Asian Stock Markets? Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 6, 125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, G., & Feigenbaum, J. (2006). A Bayesian Analysis of Log-Periodic Precursors to Financial Crashes. Quantitative Finance, 6, 15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charemza, W. W., & Deadman, D. F. (1995). Speculative Bubbles with Stochastic Explosive Roots: The Failure of Unit Root Testing. Journal of Empirical Finance, 2, 153.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chevalier, J., & Ellison, G. (1999). Career Concerns of Mutual Fund Managers. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(2), 389–432.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cieplinski, T., Dominiczak, A., & Kutner, R. (2012). Short Comprehensive Report on the Non-Brownian Stochastic Dynamics at Financial and Commodity Markets. Acta Physica Polonica A, 121, B-24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J. H. (2005). Asset Pricing (Rev. ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cootner, P. H. (Ed.). (1964). The Random Character of Stock Market Prices. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Covel, M. W. (2007). The Complete Turtle Trader: The Legend, the Lessons, the Results. New York: HarperCollins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, A., & Hobson, D. (2005). Local Martingales, Bubbles and Option Prices. Finance and Stochastics, 9, 477.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craine, R. (1993). Rational Bubbles: A Test. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17, 829.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuthbertson, K., & Nitzsche, D. (2004). Quantitative Financial Economics (2nd ed.). Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dardik, I. (2017). The Nature of Nature: The Discovery of SuperWaves and How It Changes Everything. New York: Rodale.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, P., & Grimaldi, M. (2003). Bubbling and Crashing Exchange Rates. CESIfo Working Paper No. 1045. Leuven, Belgium: Catholic University of Leuven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Derman, E. (2004). My Life As a Quant: Reflections on Physics and Finance. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dezhbakhsh, H., & Demirguc-Kunt, A. (1990, March). On the Presence of Speculative Bubbles in Stock Prices. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 25, 101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diba, B. T. (1990). Bubbles and Stock-Price Volatility. In G. P. Dwyer Jr. & R. W. Hafer (Eds.), The Stock Market: Bubbles, Volatility, and Chaos. Norwell: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diba, B. T., & Grossman, H. I. (1987, August). On the Inception of Rational Bubbles. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(409).

    Google Scholar 

  • Diba, B. T., & Grossman, H. I. (1988, September). The Theory of Rational Bubbles in Stock Prices. Economic Journal, 98, 746.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickey, D. A., Jansen, D. W., & Thornton, D. L. (1991). A Primer on Cointegration with an Application to Money and Income. In Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review. St. Louis: Federal Reserve Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Driffill, J., & Sola, M. (2001). Irreversible Investment and Changes in Regime. Economic and Social Research Council Working Paper. Birkbeck College, University of London. Available at http://www.econ.bbk.ac.uk//research/macro/macro.htm

  • Duffy, J., & Fisher, E. O’N. (2005). Sunspots in the Laboratory. American Economic Review, 95(3), 510.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar, N. (2000). Inventing Money: The Story of Long-Term Capital Management and the Legends Behind It. Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dwyer, G. P., Jr., & Hafer, R. W. (Eds.). (1990). The Stock Market: Bubbles, Volatility, and Chaos. Norwell: Kluwer Academic Press. Also in Proceedings of the Thirteenth Annual Economic Policy Conference of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ederington, L. H., & Guan, W. (2005, Spring/Summer). Measuring Historical Volatility. Journal of Applied Finance.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R. B., Jr. (2017). The Economics of American Art: Issues, Artists and Market Institutions. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, R. N. (1938). The Wave Principle. Gainesville: New Classics Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engsted, T., & Tanggaard, C. (2002). A New Test for Speculative Bubbles Based on Return Variance Composition. Working Paper Series, No. 106. Aarhus, Denmark: University of Aarhus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engsted, T., & Tanggaard, C. (2004). Speculative Bubbles in Stock Prices? Tests Based on the price-dividend Ratio (Working Paper Series). Aarhus: University of Aarhus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Etienne, X. L., Irwin, S. H., & Garcia, P. (2014, April). Bubbles in Food Commodity Markets: Four Decades of Evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance, 42, 129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evanoff, D. D., Kaufman, G. G., & Malliaris, A. G. (Eds.). (2012). New Perspectives on Asset Price Bubbles: Theory, Evidence, and Policy. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G. W. (1991). Pitfalls in Testing for Explosive Bubbles in Asset Prices. American Economic Review, 81, 922–930.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, L. L., Jr. (2003). Why the Bubble Burst: US Stock Market Performance Since 1982. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evstigneev, I. V., Hens, T., & Schenk-Hoppé, K. R. (2006). Evolutionary Stable Stock Markets. Economic Theory, 27(2), 449–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Falconer, K. (2013). Fractals: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. (1988). Dividend Yields and Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. (2004, Summer). The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3).

    Google Scholar 

  • Farmer, J. D., & Geanakoplos, J (2009). The Virtues and Vices of Equilibrium and the Future of Financial Economics. Working paper. Cowles Foundation ad available at: https://arxiv.org/pdf/0803.2996.pdf/

    Google Scholar 

  • Farmer, J. D., & Lillo, F. (2004). On the Origin of Power Law Tails in Price Fluctuations. Quantitative Finance, 4(1), 7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favero, C. A. (2001). Applied Macroeconometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flood, R. P., & Garber, P. M. (1980). Market Fundamentals Versus Price-Level Bubbles: The First Tests. Journal of Political Economy, 88, 745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flood, R. P., & Garber, P. M. (Eds.). (1994). Speculative Bubbles, Speculative Attacks and Policy Switching. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flood, R. P., & Hodrick, R. J. (1990). On Testing for Speculative Bubbles. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2), 85–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forbes, W. (2009). Behavioural Finance. Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, J. (2009). The Myth of the Rational Market: A History of Risk, Reward, and Delusion on Wall Street. New York: HarperCollins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, D. M. (2008). Adaptive Expectations and Stock Market Crashes. International Economic Review, 49(2), 595–619.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (Ed.). (1956). Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, B. M. (1979). Optimal Expectations and the Extreme Information Assumption of Rational Expectations’ Macromodel. Journal of Monetary Economics, 5(1), 23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, D., & Abraham, R. (2009, April). Bubbles and Crashes: Gradient Dynamics in Financial Markets. Journal of Dynamics & Control, 33, 922.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froot, K. A., & Obstfeld, M. (1991). Intrinsic Bubbles: The Case of Stock Prices. American Economic Review, 81(5).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fukuta, Y. (2002). A Test for Rational Bubbles in Stock Prices. Empirical Economics, 27(4), 587–600.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X. (2009). Power Laws in Economics and Finance. Annual Review of Economics, 1, 255–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. K. (1988). The Great Crash, 1929 (2nd ed.). Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (2001). Time and Money: The Macroeconomics of Capital Structure. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gay, G., Kale, J., Kolb, R., & Noe, T. (1994). (Micro) Fads in Asset Prices: Evidence from the Futures Market. Journal of Futures Markets, 14, 637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gennotte, G., & Leland, H. (1990). “Market Liquidity, Hedging, and Crashes,” American Economic Review, 80(5)(December).

    Google Scholar 

  • Geraskin, P., & Fantazzini, D. (2013). Everything You Always Wanted to Know About Log-Periodic Power Laws for Bubble Modeling But Were Afraid to Ask. The European Journal of Finance, 19(5), 366–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlis, M. (2014a). Art as an Investment? A Survey of Comparative Assets. London: Lund Humphries.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlis, M. (2014b, January 14). Is Collecting Art As Profitable as It Is Painted? Financial Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilchrist, S., Himmelberg, C. P., and Huberman, G. (2004). Do Stock Price Bubbles Influence Corporate Investment? Staff Report No. 177. Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, C., & LeRoy, S. F. (1992). Bubbles and Charges. International Economic Review, 33(2), 323–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gjerstad, S. D., & Smith, V. L. (2009, April 6). From Bubble to Depression? Wall Street Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glassman, J. K., & Hassett, K. A. (1999). Dow 36,000: The New Strategy for Profiting from the Coming Rise in the Stock Market. New York: Times Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gleick, J. (1987). Chaos: Making a New Science. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golden, D. P. (1995). Three Essays on the Theory of Speculative Bubbles. Unpublished PhD dissertation, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grassberger, P., & Procaccia, I. (1983a). Characterization of Strange Attractors. Physical Review Letters, 50(5), 346.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grassberger, P., & Procaccia, I. (1983b). Measuring the Strangeness of Strange Attractors. Physica D, 9, 189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric Analysis (5th ed.). Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwald, B. C. N., Kahn, J., Sonkin, P. D., & van Biema, M. (2001). Value Investing: From Graham to Buffett and Beyond. New York: Wiley (Paperback ed.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, R., & Nagel, S, (2008). Inexperienced Investors and Bubbles. Available at http://faculty-gsb.stanford.edu/nagel/pdfs/Mfage.pdf

  • Gresnigt, F., Kole, E., & Franses, P. H. (2015, July). Interpreting Financial Market Crashes as Earthquakes: A New Early Warning System for Medium Term Crashes. Journal of Banking & Finance, 56, 123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grullon, G., & Michaely, R. (2002). Dividends, Share Repurchases, and the Substitution Hypothesis. Journal of Finance, 57(4), 1649.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrieri, V., & Kondor, P. (2012). Fund Managers, Career Concerns, and Asset Price Volatility. American Economic Review, 102(5), 1986.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gujarati, D. N. (1995). Basic Econometrics (3rd Int. ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurkaynak, R. S. (2005). Econometric Tests of Asset Price Bubbles: Taking Stock. Washington, DC: Federal Reserve.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutierrez, L. (2013). Speculative Bubbles in Agricultural Commodity Markets. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 40(2), 217–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haacke, C. (2004). Frenzy: Bubbles, Busts and How to Come Out Ahead. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haidt, J. (2001). “The Emotional Dog and its Rational Tail,” Psychological Review, 108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, S. G., Psaradakis, Z., & Sola, M. (1999). Detecting Periodically Collapsing Bubbles: A Markov-Switching Unit Root Test. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 14, 143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J. D. (1986, October). On Testing for Self-Fulfilling Speculative Price Bubbles. International Economic Review, 27, 545.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J. D., & Whiteman, C. H. (1985). The Observable Implications of Self-Fulfilling Expectations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 16, 353.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L. P., & Renault, E. (2009). Pricing Kernels and Stochastic Discount Factors. In Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance. Chicago: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardouvelis, G. (1988, Summer). Evidence on Stock Market Speculative Bubbles: Japan, the United States, and Great Britain. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harman, Y. S. (2000). Bubbles, Fads, and the Psychology of Investors. Unpublished PhD Dissertation, Florida State University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harman, Y. S., & Zuehlke, T. W. (2004). Duration Dependence Testing for Speculative Bubbles. Journal of Economics and Finance, 28(2), 147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haruvy, E., Lahav, Y., & Noussair, C. N. (2007). Traders’ Expectations in Asset Markets: Experimental Evidence. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1901–1920.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hassler, U. (2016). Stochastic Processes and Calculus: An Elementary Introduction with Applications. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. (1995). Dynamic Econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henker, J., & Owen, S. A. (2008). Bursting Bubbles: Linking Experimental Financial Market Results to Field Market Data. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 9(1), 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henriques, D. B. (2008, March 28). Odd Crop Prices Defy Economics. New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hens, T., & Schenk-Hoppé, K. R. (2001). Evolution of Portfolio Rules in Incomplete Markets. Working Paper Series ISSN 1424-0459, No. 74. Zurich: University of Zurich. Available at http://www.iew.unizh.ch/wp/iewwp074.pdf

  • Herrera, S., & Perry, G. E. (2003). Tropical Bubbles: Asset Prices in Latin America, 1980–2001. In Hunter et al. (2003 [2005]).

    Google Scholar 

  • Herzog, B. (2015). An Econophysics Model of Financial Bubbles. Natural Science, 7, 55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heston, S. I., Loewenstein, M., & Willard, G. A. (2007). Options and Bubbles. Review of Financial Studies, 20(2), 359.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilborn, R. C. (2000). Chaos and Nonlinear Dynamics: An Introduction for Scientists and Engineers (2nd ed.). Oxford/New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillier, B. (1997). The Economics of Asymmetric Information. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homm, U., & Breitung, J. (2012). Testing for Speculative Bubbles in Stock Markets: A Comparison of Alternative Methods. Journal of Financial Econometrics, 10(1), 198–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., Kubik, J. D., & Solomon, A. (2000). Security Analysts’ Career Concerns and Herding of Earnings Forecasts. RAND Journal of Economics, 31(1), 121–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hong, H., Scheinkman, J. A., & Xiong, W. (2006). Asset Float and Speculative Bubbles. Journal of Finance, LXI(3), 1073–1117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, D. (1991). Chaos and Nonlinear Dynamics: Application to Financial Markets. Journal of Finance, 46, 1839–1877.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunter, W. C., Kaufman, G. G., & Pomerleano, M. (Eds.). (2003). Asset Price Bubbles: The Implications for Monetary, Regulatory, and International Policies. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press (Paperback ed., 2005).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hussam, R. N., Porter, D., & Smith, V. L. (2008). Thar She Blows: Can Bubbles Be Rekindled with Experienced Subjects? American Economic Review, 98(3), 924–937.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ijiri, Y., & Simon, H. A. (1974). Interpretations of Departures from the Pareto Curve Firm-Size Distributions. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jain A., Jain, P. K., McInish, T. H., & McKenzie, M. (2013). Worldwide Reach of Short-Selling Regulations. Journal of Financial Economics, 109(1), 177–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jarrow, R. A., Protter, P., & Shimbo, K. (2010). Asset Price Bubbles in Incomplete Markets. Mathematical Finance, 20(2), 145–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jarrow, R. A., Kchia, Y., & Protter, P. (2011). How to Detect an Asset Bubble. SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, 2(1), 839.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, A., & Sornette, D. (1999a). Critical Crashes. Risk, 12(1), 91–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, A., & Sornette, D. (1999b). Log-Periodic Power Law Bubbles in Latin-American and Asian Markets and Correlated Anti-Bubbles in Western Stock Markets: An Empirical Study. Economics Working Paper, St. Louis: Washington University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, A., & Sornette, D. (1999c). Modeling the Stock Market Prior to Large Crashes. European Physics Journal B, 9, 167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, A., & Sornette, D. (1999d). Financial ‘Anti-Bubbles’: Log-Periodicity in Gold and Nikkei Collapses. International Journal of Modern Physics C, 10(4), 563–575.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, F., & Schinckus, C. (2017). Econophysics and Financial Economics: An Emerging Dialog. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2013). Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. (1996[1989]). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises (3rd ed.). New York: Wiley. (2nd ed., 1989).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C., & Aliber, R. Z. (2011). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises (6th ed.). Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kodres, L., & Pritsker, M. (2002). A Rational Expectations Model of Financial Contagion,” Journal of Finance, 57(2).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kräussl, R., Lehnert, T., & Martelin, N. (2016, January). Is There a Bubble in the Art Market? Journal of Empirical Finance, 35, 99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kritzman, M. (1994, March/April). About Serial Dependence. Financial Analysts Journal, 50(2).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, M. (1994). On the Structure and Diversity of Rational Beliefs. Journal of Economic Theory, 4(6), 877–900.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laherrère, J., & Sornette, D. (1998). Stretched Exponential Distributions in Nature and Economy: ‘Fat Tails’ with Characteristic Scales. European Physical Journal, B2, 525–539. Available at http://xxx.lanl.gov/abs/cond-mat/9801293

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, I. H. (1998). Market Crashes and Informational Avalanches. Review of Economic Studies, 65, 741.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, T. (2004). Why the Markets Went Crazy. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lei, V., Noussair, C. N., & Plott, C. R. (2001). Nonspeculative Bubbles in Experimental Asset Markets: Lack of Common Knowledge of Rationality vs. Actual Irrationality. Econometrica, 69(4), 831.

    Google Scholar 

  • LeRoy, S. F. (2004). Rational Exuberance. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(3), 783.

    Google Scholar 

  • LeRoy, S. F., & Porter, R. D. (1981). The Present Value Relation: Tests Based on Implied Variance Bonds. Econometrica, 64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, W. (1999). Zipf’s Law Web site. Available at http://linkage.rockefeller.edu/wli/zipf/

  • Lillo, F., & Mantegna, R. N. (2000). Symmetry Alterations of Ensemble Return Distribution in Crash and Rally Days of Financial Markets. European Physical Journal B, 15, 603.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim, K. G. (2015). Financial Valuation and Econometrics (2nd ed.). Singapore: World Scientific.

    Google Scholar 

  • Limpert, E., Stahel, W. A., & Abbt, M. (2001). Lognormal Distributions across the Sciences: Keys and Clues. Bioscience, 51(5), 341–352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, T., Granger, C. W. J., & Heller, P. (1992). Using the Correlation Exponent to Decide Whether an Economic Time Series Is Chaotic. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 7, S25–S39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loeys, J., & Panigirtzoglou, N. (2006, Winter). Are Alternatives the Next Bubble? Journal of Alternative Investments, 9(3).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lovell, M. C. (1986, March). Tests of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis. American Economic Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowenstein, R. (2008, September 6). Long-Term Capital: It’s a Short-Term Memory. New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lux, T. (1995). Herd Behavior, Bubbles and Crashes. Economic Journal: The Journal of the Royal Economic Society, 105, 881.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lux, T., & Sornette, D. (2002). On Rational Bubbles and Fat Tails. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 34(3), 589–610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddala, G. S. (2001). Introduction to Econometrics (3rd ed.). Chichester: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddala, G. S., & Kim, I. (1999). Unit Roots, Cointegration, and Structural Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malliaris, A. G. (2012). Asset Price Bubbles and Central Bank Policies. In Evanoff et al. (2012).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandelbrot, B. (1960). The Pareto-Lévy Law and the Distribution of Income. International Economic Review, 1, 79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandelbrot, B. (1964). The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices. In P. Cootner (Ed.), The Random Character of Stock Prices. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandelbrot, B., & Hudson, R. L. (2004). The (Mis)Behavior of Markets: A Fractal View of Risk, Ruin, and Reward. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, A., & Ventura, J. (2015). The International Transmission of Credit Bubbles: Theory and Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 76(Supplement), S37–S56.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCauley, J. L. (2004). Dynamics of Markets: Econophysics and Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McQueen, G., & Thorley, S. (1994). Bubbles, Stock Returns, and Duration Dependence. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 29, 379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meese, R. A. (1986). Testing for Bubbles in Exchange Markets: A Case of Sparkling Rates? Journal of Political Economy, 94, 345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling, P. (2005). Fischer Black and the Revolutionary Idea of Finance. Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H. (1982). Rational Expectations, Risk, Uncertainty, and Market Responses. Available at http://repository.cmu.edu/tepper

  • Merton, R. C. (1973). Theory of Rational Option Pricing. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science (The Rand Corporation), 4(1), 141–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miao, J. (2014). Introduction to Economic Theory of Bubbles. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 53, 130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, J. I., & Ratti, R. A. (2009). Crude Oil and Stock Markets: Stability, Instability, and Bubbles. Energy Economics, 31(4), 559–568.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, T. C. (1990). Time Series Techniques for Economists. Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, T. C. (1993). The Econometric Modelling of Financial Time Series. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montier, J. (2002). Behavioural Finance: Insights into Irrational Minds and Markets. Chichester/Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muth, J. A. (1961). Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements. Econometrica, 29(6), 315–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Napier, R. (2007). Anatomy of the Bear: Lessons from Wall Street’s Four Great Bottoms (2nd ed.). Petersfield: Harriman House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noguchi, Y. (1994). The ‘Bubble’ and Economic Policies in the 1980s. Journal of Japanese Studies, 20(2), 291–329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nychka, D. W., Ellner, S., Gallant, A. R., & McCaffrey, D. (1992). Finding Chaos in Noisy Systems. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B, 54, 399–426.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Grady, M. A. (2009, March 21). Now Is No Time to Give Up on Markets. Wall Street Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palan, S. (2009). Bubbles and Crashes in Experimental Asset Markets. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, J. Y., & Whang, Y. J. (1999). Random Walk or Chaos: A Formal Test on the Lyapunov Exponent. Working Paper No. 9, Institute of Economic Research, Seoul National University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patterson, S. (2010). The Quants: How a New Breed of Math Whizzes Conquered Wall Street and Nearly Destroyed It. New York: Crown (Random House).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierce, J. R. (1980). An Introduction to Information Theory: Symbols, Signals and Noise (2nd. Rev. ed.). New York: Dover.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierdzioch, C. (2010). Periodically Collapsing Bubbles in the German Stock Market, 1876–1913. Applied Economics Letters, 17(9), 907–908.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porras-Gonzalez, E. R. (2000). Speculative Bubbles and Tests of the Contagion Mechanism in Financial Markets. Unpublished PhD Dissertation, Florida Atlantic University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, D., & Smith, V. L. (1992). Price Expectations in Experimental Asset Markets with Futures Contracting. Social Science Working Paper 827. Pasadena: California Institute of Technology. Available at http://www.hss.caltech.edu/SSPapers/sswp827.pdf

  • Poundstone, W. (2010). Priceless: The Myth of Fair Value. New York: Hill and Wang. (Farrar, Straus and Giroux).

    Google Scholar 

  • Prechter, R. R., Jr. (2001). Unconscious Herding Behavior as the Psychological Basis of Financial Market Trends and Patterns. Journal of Psychology and Financial Markets, 2(3), 120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prechter, R. R., Jr. (2004). The Fractal Nature of the Stock Market. In The Colours of Infinity: The Beauty, and Power of Fractals. London: Clear Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prechter, R. R., Jr. (2016). The Socionomic Theory of Finance. Gainesville: Socionomics Institute Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Psaradakis, Z., Sola, M., & Spagnolo, F. (2001). A Simple Procedure for Detecting Periodically Collapsing Rational Bubbles. Economic Letters, 72, and Birkbeck College Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raines, J. P., & Leathers, C. G. (2000). Economists and the Stock Market: Speculative Theories of Stock Market Fluctuations. Aldershot: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, J. B., Sayers, C. L., & Rothman, P. (1990). The Statistical Properties of Dimension Calculations Using Small Data Sets: Some Economic Applications. International Economic Review, 31(4), 991–1020.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasband, S. N. (1990). Chaotic Dynamics of Nonlinear Systems. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rousseau, R. (1999). A Weak Goodness-of-Fit Test for Rank-Frequency Distributions. In C. Macias-Chapula (Ed.), Proceedings of the Seventh Conference of the International Society for Scientometrics and Informetrics, Universidad de Colima, Mexico.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saffi, P. A. C., & Sigurdsson, K. (2011). Price Efficiency and Short Selling. Review of Financial Studies, 24(3), 821–852.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santoni, G. J. (1987). The Great Bull Markets of 1924–1929 and 1982–1987: Speculative Bubbles or Economic Fundamentals? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santos, M. S., & Woodford, M. (1997). Rational Asset Pricing Bubbles. Econometrica, 65, 19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarno, L., & Taylor, M. P. (1999). Moral Hazard, Asset Price Bubbles, Capital Flows, and the East Asian Crisis: The First Tests. Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, Y. (2016). “Fund Tournaments and Asset Bubbles,” Review of Finance, 20(4)(July).

    Google Scholar 

  • Schaller, H., & van Norden, S. (1997). Fads or Bubbles? Working Paper 97-92, Bank of Canada. Available at http://www.bankofcanada.ca/en/res/wp/1997/wp97-2.html

  • Scheinkman, J. A., & Xiong, W. (2003). Overconfidence and Speculative Bubbles. Journal of Political Economy, 111(6), 1183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, L. O. (1985). The Present Value Model of Stock Prices: Regression Tests and Monte Carlo Results. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67, 599–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Serletis, A. (1996). Is There Chaos in Economic Time Series? Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(Special Issue – Part 1), S210–S212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Serletis, A., & Dormaar, P. (1996). Chaos and Nonlinear Dynamics in Futures Markets. In W. A. Barnett et al. (Eds.), Nonlinear Dynamics and Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. J. (1981). Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to Be Justified by Subsequent Movements in Dividends? American Economic Review, 71(3), 421–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. J. (1989). Comovements in Stock Prices and Comovements in Dividends. Journal of Finance, 44(3), 719–729.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. J. (1992). Market Volatility. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. J. (2002a). Bubbles, Human Judgment, and Expert Opinion. Financial Analysts Journal, 58(3), 18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. J. (2002b, October). From Efficient Market Theory to Behavioral Finance. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1385. New Haven: Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics, Yale University. Available at http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/

  • Shiller, R. J., Kon-Ya, F., & Tsutsui, Y. (1996). Why Did the Nikkei Crash? Expanding the Scope of Expectations Data Collection. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1), 156–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). The Limits of Arbitrage. Journal of Finance, 52(1), 35–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G., & Lehnert, D. (1996). Evolutionary Chaos: Growth Fluctuations in a Schumpeterian Model of Creative Destruction. In W. A. Barnett, A. P. Kirman, & M. Salmon (Eds.), Nonlinear Dynamics and Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smelser, N. J., & Baltsis, P. B. (Eds.). (2001). International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Sciences. London: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L. (1962). An Experimental Study of Competitive Market Behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 70(3), 322–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, C. W. (2003). Bubbles and Stock Market Behavior, Rational and Irrational. Unpublished PhD Dissertation, State University of New York at Binghamton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V. L., Suchanek, G. L., & Williams, A. W. (1988). Bubbles, Crashes, and Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets. Econometrica, 56(5), 1119–1151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sola, M., & Driffill, J. (1998). Intrinsic Bubbles and Regime Switching. Journal of Monetary Economics, 42(2), 357–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sornette, D. (2003a). Why Stock Markets Crash: Critical Events in Complex Financial Systems. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sornette, D. (2003b). Critical Market Crashes. Physics Reports, 378(1), 1–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spotton, B., & Rowley, R. (1998). Efficient Markets, Fundamentals, and Crashes: American Theories of Financial Crises and Market Volatility. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 57(4), 663–690.

    Google Scholar 

  • Srivastava, N., & Satchell, S. (2012). Are There Bubbles in the Art Market? The Detection of Bubbles When Fair Value Is Unobservable. Birkbeck Working Papers in Economics and Finance, 1209 (April).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1990). Symposium on Bubbles. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4(2), 13–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strogatz, S. (2003). Sync: The Emerging Science of Spontaneous Order. New York: Hyperion.

    Google Scholar 

  • Surowiecki, J. (2004). The Wisdom of Crowds. New York: Doubleday.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taipalus, K. (2012). Detecting Asset Price Bubbles with Time-Series Methods. Helsinki, Bank of Finland, Scientific Monograph E, 47-2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Takens, F. (1981). Dynamical Systems and Turbulence. In D. A. Rand & L. S. Young (Eds.), Lecture Notes in Mathematics. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taleb, N. N. (2007). The Black Swan. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, S. (2005). Asset Price Dynamics, Volatility, and Prediction. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. P., & Peel, D. A. (1998). Periodically Collapsing Stock Price Bubbles: A Robust Test. Economics Letters, 61, 221–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Temin, P., & Voth, H.-J. (2004). Riding the South Sea Bubble. American Economic Review, 94(5), 1654–1668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Theiler, J. B., Galdrikian, A., Longtin, S., Eubank, S., & Farmer, J. D. (1992). Using Surrogate Data to Detect Nonlinearity in Time Series. In M. Casdagli & S. Eubank (Eds.), Nonlinear Modeling and Forecasting. Redwood City: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1982). On the Possibility of Speculation Under Rational Expectations. Econometrica, 50(5), 1163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toporowski, J. (1999). The End of Finance: Capital Market Inflation, Financial Derivatives and Pension Fund Capitalism. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Townsend, R. M. (1983). Forecasting the Forecasts of Others. Journal of Political Economy, 91(4), 546.

    Google Scholar 

  • Triana, P. (2009). Lecturing Birds on Flying: Can Mathematical Theories Destroy the Financial Markets? Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tuckett, D. (2011). Minding the Markets: An Emotional Finance View of Financial Instability. London: Palgrave/Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnovsky, S. J. (1996). Methods of Macroeconomic Dynamics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Urzua, C. M. (2000). A Simple and Efficient Test for Zipf’s Law. Economic Letters, 66, 257.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Norden, S. (1996). Regime-Switching as a Test for Exchange Rate Bubbles. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11(3), 219–251.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voth, H.-J. (2003). With a Bang, Not a Whimper: Pricking Germany’s ‘Stock Market Bubble’ in 1927 and the Slide into Depression. Journal of Economic History, 63(1), 65–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wachtel, P. (Ed.). (1982). Crises in the Economic and Financial Structure. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe, K., Takayasu, H., & Takayasu, M. (2007). A Mathematical Definition of the Financial Bubbles and Crashes. Physica A, 383, 120–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Werner, R. A. (2005). New Paradigm in Macroeconomics: Solving the Riddle of Japanese Macroeconomic Performance. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • West, K. D. (1987). A Specification Test for Speculative Bubbles. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 553.

    Google Scholar 

  • West, K. D. (1988). Bubbles, Fads and Stock Volatility Tests: A Partial Evaluation. Journal of Finance, 43(3), 639.

    Google Scholar 

  • West, G. (2017). Scale: The Universal Laws of Growth, Innovation, and Sustainability. New York: Penguin/Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, E. N. (Ed.). (1990). Crashes and Panics: The Lessons from History. Homewood: Dow-Jones-Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, G. P. (1997). Chaos Theory Tamed. Washington, DC: Joseph Henry Press/National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilmott, P., & Orrell, D. (2017). The Money Formula: Dodgy Finance, Psuedo Science, and How Mathematicians Took Over the Markets. Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolf, A., Swift, J. B., Swinney, H. L., & Vastano, J. A. (1985). Determining Lyapunov Exponents from a Time Series. Physica D, 16(3), 285–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo, W. T. (1987). Some Evidence of Speculative Bubbles in the Foreign Exchange Markets. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 19(4), 499.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, Y. (1995). Are There Rational Bubbles in Foreign Exchange Markets? Evidence from An Alternative Test. Journal of International Money and Finance, 14(1), 27–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, Y. (1997). Rational Bubbles in the Stock Market: Accounting for the U.S. Stock-Price Volatility. Economic Inquiry, 35(2), 309–319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, F. X., Green, J., & Hand, J. (2016). Errors and Questionable Judgments in Analysts’ DCF Models. Review of Accounting Studies, 21(2), 596–632.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Vogel, H.L. (2018). Rationality Rules. In: Financial Market Bubbles and Crashes, Second Edition. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-71528-5_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-71528-5_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-71527-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-71528-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics