Skip to main content

Public Procurement of Public Goods as Innovation Policy: The Cloud of New Technologies Around Military Product Development

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Visible Costs and Invisible Benefits

Part of the book series: Economics of Science, Technology and Innovation ((ESTI))

  • 598 Accesses

Abstract

Advanced industrial production is always surrounded by a cloud of new technology, available to each and all in proportion to the ability of local entrepreneurs to pick up and commercialize its content – receiver competence. We talk about technological spillovers or positive externalities, a concept originally invented and used by the nineteenth-century British economists Henry Sidgwick, Arthur Pigou, and Alfred Marshall (1890). Marshall introduced the theoretical concept to overcome the shortcomings of the then dominant static economic model that I will have reason to return to in the theoretical Chap. 13. Most of this document is however devoted to measuring the economy-wide long-term consequences of technologies created during military product development.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    It may therefore require a separate explanation. See Sect. 5.4.1. The Gripen of Sect. 4 was not originally planned for exports. The exports of Gripens, for instance, to South Africa and Brazil net of modification work for those markets and costs for manufacturing the aircraft will therefore appear as “spillovers.” The A26 submarine (in Chap. 9) is a more complicated case, in that the original price charged to FMV was based on some submarines being exported. If not so, the contract was to be negotiated.

  2. 2.

    The internal profit targeting practice I met with in large US firms, where CHQ staff could not fully assess the capacity of divisions or profit centers to deliver, was to demand the “same as before” and a little more (see case on page 50f in Eliasson 1976a). If division management was unwilling or not capable of delivering an improvement, they had to credibly explain why, or management change was likely to be enacted. Maintain or improve profits, the MIP principle, was a commonly used targeting principle (Eliasson 1976a:159, 236ff, 1991a, 2005b). The MIP principle can be shown to approximate a short-term ex ante profit maximization ambition of the firm and is so implemented in the micro to macro model presented in Sect. 13.6.

  3. 3.

    The Swedish military procurement agency FMV could draw on previous (before Gripen) industrial experience from having itself coordinated development work on manufacturing and assembly of military aircraft over specialist subcontractors. Saab was then a subcontractor to FMV. With the Gripen this systems coordination and integration task became overwhelming for FMV, and it gradually migrated over to Saab.

  4. 4.

    We have a terminology problem of sorts here, since traditional econometric literature refers to estimated spillovers as externalities , without recognizing the intermediary and very resource demanding commercialization process (see Sect. 12.3 and Chap. 13).

  5. 5.

    In the industrial subsidy study referred to earlier (Carlsson 1983a,b; also see Sect. 14.6), the micro to macro model was used, and wages were endogenously determined and thus also opportunity costs .

  6. 6.

    Between 1950 and 1996, the share of Swedish manufacturing industry in GNP had decreased from 30 to 23 percent according to the national accounts but had not decreased at all but rather stayed constant, between 45 and 50 percent the entire period, when corrected for outsourced engineering-related service production to reach 56 percent in 1996 (Eliasson & Johansson, 1999).

  7. 7.

    Burenstam Linder (1961) made that last point but referred to it as a “comparative advantage ” of static international trade theory.

  8. 8.

    An externality (positive or negative) is a phenomenon that is observed, but that cannot be explained within the existing economic model. The term was first used by British economists in the nineteenth century, among them by Alfred Marshall (1890), in his attempts to deal with the deficiencies of the static Walrasian model. The so-called “new growth theory ” attempts to endogenize (“explain”) spillovers within the static neoclassical model.

  9. 9.

    Or more precisely, as they write, constant returns to scale “together with the necessary conditions for producer equilibrium.”

  10. 10.

    Positive spillovers “insert” a positive wedge between the private and the social rate of return on R&D. The spillover multiplier is the ratio between the estimated social values created net of opportunity costs and the R&D investment that has created them. The difference between social and private rates of return is roughly proportional to the spillover multiplier and, as well, to the estimated underinvestment in R&D (see Eliasson 2010a: Supplement II, Sect. 5.4 and Chap. 13). That underinvestment will go away as diminishing returns set in when private R&D is expanded. Whether or when diminishing returns set in is an empirical question in new growth theory .

  11. 11.

    Bentzel (1980), using a macro model, came to roughly the same conclusion for Sweden for the years 1870–1975.

  12. 12.

    While the Gunnarsson et al. (2004) conclusion draws on Griliches (1969) proposition of a technical complementarity between R&D and human capital, the commercialization is the downstream production activity of turning technically defined innovations into a business through entrepreneurship and industrially competent venture finance (Eliasson 2003, and Table 1.3).

Bibliography

  • Bentzel, R. (1980). Svensk ekonomisk tilväxt 1870–1975 (Swedish economic growth 1870–1975). In E. Dahmén & G. Eliasson (Eds.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Burenstam-Linder, S. (1961). An essay on trade and transformation. Uppsala: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, R. I., & Jaffe, A. B. (1993, May). How high are the giants’ shoulders? – An empirical assessment of knowledge spillovers and creative destruction in a model of economic growth NBER Working Paper No. 4370. Cambridge, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, B. (1983a). Industrial subsidies in Sweden: Macro-economic effects and an international comparison. Journal of Industrial Economics, XXXII(1), 9–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, B. (1983b). Industrial subsidies in Sweden: Simulations on a micro-to-macro model. In Microeconometrics, IUI yearbook 1982–1983. IUI: Stockholm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davies, A., Ergas, H., & Thomson, M. (2012). Should Australia build warships? An economic and strategic analysis. Paper presented at the RAN Seapower conference, Sydney 1 February 2012, Australian Strategic Policy Institute (ASPI).

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1976a). Business economic planning – Theory, practice and comparison. London, etc.: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1990b). Chapter I: The knowledge-based information economy. In G. Eliasson et al. (Eds.), The knowledge based information economy. Stockholm: IUI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1991a). Deregulation, innovative entry and structural diversity as a source of stable and rapid economic growth. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 1, 49–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1992a). Business competence, organizational learning and economic growth – Establishing the Smith-Schumpeter-Wicksell connection. In F. M. Scherer & M. Perlman (Eds.), Entrepreneurship, technological innovation, and economic growth: Studies in the Schumpeterian tradition. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1992b) Arbetet – dess betydelse, dess innehåll, dess kvalitet och dess ersättning (Work – Its significance, content, quality and compensation). Stockholm: IUI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1994c). Educational efficiency and the market for competence. European Journal of Vocational Training, 2(94), 5–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1995). En teknologigenerator eller ett nationellt prestigeprojekt? svensk flygindustri (A technology generator or a national prestige project? Swedish aircraft industry). Stockholm: City University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1996a). The firm, its objectives, its controls and its organization. Boston/Dordrecht/London: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1996b). Spillovers, integrated production and the theory of the firm. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 6, 125–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (1996c). The use of highly educated people in production. TRITA – IEO R 1996-10, Stockholm: KTH.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2000e). Chapter III: A platform theory of cumulative learning – The dropout or fall off problem. In G. Eliasson (Ed.), Industrial change, life long learning and labor market performance. Stockholm: KTH TRITA-IEO-R 2000:14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2003). The venture capitalist as a competent outsider. In K. Alho, J. Lassila, & P. Ylä-Anttila (Eds.), Economic research and decision making, ETLA-Taloustieto oy, Helsinki.; An earlier version was published under the same title by Stockholm: KTH, TRITA-IEO R 1997:06.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (Ed.). (2005a). The birth, the life and the death of firms – The role of entrepreneurship, creative destruction and conservative institutions in a growing and experimentally organized economy. Stockholm: The Ratio Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2005b). The nature of economic change and management in a new knowledge based information economy. Information Economics and Policy, 17, 428–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2010a). Advanced public procurement as industrial policy – Aircraft industry as a technical university. New York/Dordrecht/Heidelberg/London: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2010b). Synliga Kostnader, Osynliga Vinster – Offentlig upphandling som industripolitik (Visible costs, invisible benefits – Public procurment as industrial policy). Stockholm: SNS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G. (2013a). The internet as a global production reorganizer: The old industry in the new economy. In A. Pyka (Ed.), Long term economic development, economic complexity and evolution. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, U. (1997). Företagandets konst – om konstproduktionen i renässansens Florens (The art of enterprise – On the art production in renaissance Florence). Stockholm: City Universitetet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G., & Eliasson, Å. (2005). The theory of the firm and the markets for strategic acquisitions. In U. Cantner, E. Dinopoulos, & R. F. Lanzilotti (Eds.), Entrepreneurship, the new economy and public policy. Berlin/Heidelberg/New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson, G., & Johansson, D. (1999). Den C&C användande Industrin. In G. Eliasson & D. Johansson (Eds.),. Dynamik och flexibilitet i svensk IT-industry (Dynamics and Flexibility in Swedish IT-industry) (pp. 199–217). Stockholm: City University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1969). Capital – Skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics, LI, 465–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of R&D to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics (Spring), 10(1), 92–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gunnarsson, G., Mellander, E., & Savvidou, E. (2004). Human capital is the key to the IT productivity paradox. IFAU Working paper 2004:13, Uppsala.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heum, P., Yla-Antilla, P., Braunerhjelm, P., & Thomsen, S. (1992). Firm dynamics in a Nordic perspective – Large corporations and industrial transformation. Helsingfors: ETLA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C.,. I., & Williams, J. C. (1998). Measuring the Social Returns to R&D. The Quartery Journal of Economics, 113(4), 1119–1135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. & Williams, J. C. (1999, August). Too much of a good thing? The economics of investment in R&D (NBER Working Paper Nr 7283). Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D. W., & Griliches, Z. (1967). The explanation of productivity change. Review of Economic Studies, XXXIV(3), 249–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. H. (1944). Diminishing returns from investment. Journal of Political Economy, LII, 26–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, L. W. (1959). On the existence of general equilibrium for a competitive market. Econometrica, 27(1), 30–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nadiri, I. (1978). A dynamic model of research and development expenditure. In B. Carlsson, G. Eliasson, & I. Nadiri (Eds.), The importance of technology and the permanence of structure in industrial growth. IUI Conference Reports, 1978:2, Stockholm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nadiri, I. (1993). Innovations and technological spillovers. Working Paper No. 4423. Cambridge, MA; NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. L. (1987). We’d better watch out. New York Times Book Review, 12, 36.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Eliasson, G. (2017). Public Procurement of Public Goods as Innovation Policy: The Cloud of New Technologies Around Military Product Development. In: Visible Costs and Invisible Benefits. Economics of Science, Technology and Innovation. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-66993-9_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics