Skip to main content

Theoretical Insight on the Property Tax

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Property Tax in BRICS Megacities

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

  • 413 Accesses

Abstract

The large and vibrant literature on local public finance constitutes the basis for a normative framework on property tax, which is outlined in Sect. 2.1. Beyond that, the question of the property tax incidence, i.e. who pays the property tax, is illustrated in Sect. 2.2. Finally, based on the public finance literature, criteria for a rational local property tax are derived and reviewed in Sect. 2.1.3.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Depending on the spatial benefit incidence, the allocation function could also be assigned to the central government. However, decentralizing political, financial, and administrative authority is generally more efficient as the focused attention is on local preferences.

  2. 2.

    The decentralization theorem presumes that there is no perfect information given and, therefore, the central government provides a uniform provision of public services across all jurisdictions.

  3. 3.

    Dillinger (1991: 3) states that intergovernmental transfers (mainly revenue sharing) and local indirect taxes may play a role in stabilization and distributional policies but that they cannot be seen as prices (as is the case of benefit taxes).

  4. 4.

    All public services with ‘private good’ character user fees are appropriate because spillovers are unlikely to exist. In the case of collective or ‘public good’ benefit, where specific beneficiaries cannot be identified, a local benefit tax is best. The property tax, for instance, covers the cost of providing services that provide collective benefits to the local community (Mohanty et al. 2007: 33; Kitchen 2013: 3).

  5. 5.

    The revenue assignment is, however, not that easy. The vertical tax assignment structure is therefore described in literature as ‘tax-assignment problem’ (McLure 1983).

  6. 6.

    Musgrave first clearly articulated the free-riding problem in his 1939 article “The Voluntary Exchange Theory of Public Economy“. In his book, “The Theory of Public Finances” he emphasized that public and private goods provision differs in the free-riding problem.

  7. 7.

    Tiebout (1956: 422): “Just as the consumer may be visualized as walking to a private market place to buy his goods, the prices of which are set, we place him in the position of walking to a community where the prices (taxes) of community services are set. Both trips take the consumer to market”.

  8. 8.

    Fiscal equivalence does not necessarily imply that taxes paid reflect someone’s individual consumption of public goods. Fiscal equivalence fits best when thinking about (relatively) various municipalities consisting of homogenous Tiebout-like groups, where public goods generate (about) the same utility for each individual within one (out of many) respective Tiebout-like group. Services would be provided at the lowest point on the average cost curve, where the ones who pay for service provision are the ones who benefit. This is also called group-related local equivalence (Haller 1981: 40; Zimmermann 2009: 142).

  9. 9.

    The capitalization effect could be defined as the manifestation of local taxes and expenditures into property values. Oates (1969: 968) econometric evidence of the capitalization effect was based on a 1960-dataset of northern New Jersey municipalities. Oates concluded “if a community increases its tax rates and employs the receipts to improve its school system, the coefficients indicate that the increased benefits from the expenditure side of the budget will roughly offset (or perhaps even more than offset) the depressive effect of the higher tax rates on local property values.”

  10. 10.

    According to Fischel (2001: 56) “capitalization is everywhere”. Fischel (1992: 171) argues that there is a wide range of zoning tools (e.g. minimum lot sizes, height restrictions, requirements for off-street parking etc.) that could be used by local governments to control their capital stock (zoning is imposing strict limits on housing consumption).

  11. 11.

    In the context of private goods, the ultimate form of decentralization would be delivered by the market, with a consumer buying a tailored good from a choice of suppliers. As this in not the case with public goods, decentralization may approximate the market allocation.

  12. 12.

    The idea of the institutional symmetry goes back to Knut Wicksell’s (1896) “Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen”. His ideas were revived by Richard A. Musgrave’s (1939) publication “The Voluntary Exchange Theory of Public Economy” (Blankart 2003: 27f.).

  13. 13.

    There is a grey area with subnational governments having budgetary discretion and political leadership responding to local preferences, but they are not elected by local population as is the case in China.

  14. 14.

    Besides, land taxation roots can be found in earlier works of Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill (Gu and Trefzger 2000: 149).

  15. 15.

    The property tax on unimproved land (land value only) cannot be shifted, as the tax will not cause any change in the behaviour of the landowner. This holds if the market value is the assessment base. The particular use is then independent of the tax. “Whatever use would be most profitable in the absence of such a tax will remain so when the tax is levied” (Heilbrun 1983: 58).

  16. 16.

    Lowell C. Harris is speaking about “getting richer while sleeping” in the context of urban landownership (Harriss and Oates 2001: 15).

  17. 17.

    Therefore, the benefit tax could be seen as a non-distortionary user charge.

  18. 18.

    “The match between incidence of the property tax and the benefits of the service it finances is clearly far from perfect: the statutory burden of the property tax is distributed according to value of property; the benefits of the service it finances are not (Dillinger 1991: 3).”

  19. 19.

    “The tax on capital is seen as a combination of a basic (or average) tax rate applied to all capital (which capital owners cannot escape since it is levied on a fixed supply of capital) plus a local differential that varies across jurisdictions—thus working as an incentive for capital to reallocate among jurisdictions until net after-tax rates of return are equalized” (Norregaard 2013: 17).

  20. 20.

    The property tax differential is defined as the difference between the present value of the benefits of local public services received and property taxes paid.

  21. 21.

    In order to make the benefit principle work in general, property taxation has to be applied so that all real property benefits from local public services equal the property tax yields, which would be the Tiebout equilibrium (Musgrave and Musgrave 1976: 344); “A general tax on real property, therefore, is a poor instrument for charging for services rendered.” Musgrave and Musgrave conclude, that income and value added tax might be a better proxy for benefits for individuals and firms. Yet, in the case of different service levels among municipalities, the benefit principle fits. Given a community A with higher public service levels than community B, the difference will be capitalized in property values in A. Therefore, the argument for benefit taxation holds only for the differential. This establishes a tenuous link between ownership and service level.

  22. 22.

    For discussions on local tax criteria, see Oates (2001: 23–24); Mohanty (2003: 7); Bird and Slack (2004: 40–41); Smoke (2008: 40); Zimmermann (2009: 139–149); Brys et al. (2013: 13–18).

  23. 23.

    “The relative greater stability of market values is of little consequence, if market values are not accurately reflected in assessed property values (Bahl and Martinez-Vazques 2007: 6).”

  24. 24.

    The online seminar lecture “Designing and Implementing Property Tax Systems in Africa“, provided by the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, gives a well-structured overview on administrative and political aspects of the property tax design (attendance, April 2014).

  25. 25.

    While taxing land only leads to an unbiased development of residential properties, taxing buildings is not incentive-neutral (see Sect. 2.1.2). Nonetheless, there are countries taxing buildings only, this is usually the case where the land is nationalized or land is perceived as national asset belonging to the people collectively. Herewith, taxing buildings only is not considered as it is very costly to maintain the fiscal cadastre (see Sect. 2.2.5) and it would stifle land development. From an economic and administrative context, taxing buildings only is ‘nonsense’.

  26. 26.

    Exemption and exclusions constitute only one part of tax relief. Tax relief, however, can be granted on a number of stages besides exempting or excluding property from the tax base, such as differentiating the tax rates among the taxpayers or by not valuing/billing/collecting all properties, respectively, by not enforcing all property liabilities. Property tax relief programmes are outlined by Kitchen (2013: 29ff).

  27. 27.

    The revenue cost could be estimated if the average tax liability per property and the number of exempt properties is known. However, it has to be kept in mind that most exempt properties are well-located governmental properties; therefore, the revenue cost is a gross underestimation, see Mathur et al. (2009: 34):

    RCEX=(NEX) [\( \frac{TD\ }{AP} \)];

    RCEX=Estimated revenue cost of exemption

    NEX=Number of exempt property

    TD=Property tax demand for taxable properties

    AP=Number of taxable properties assessed.

  28. 28.

    Within the assessment, it is not required to determine an absolute value in market terms, but the relative value of properties at a common point in time (Dillinger 1991: 16).

  29. 29.

    A well-functioning property market implies that properties can be sold and bought on an open and competitive market. In this case, the property value reflects the highest and best use of the property and market price would equal the capital/market value (RICS 2012: 32f).

  30. 30.

    The distribution of the tax burden differs between rental value and capital value. The capital value will place a higher proportion of the tax burden on underdeveloped property such as, for instance, vacant land.

  31. 31.

    Some counties make use of hybrid approaches, capital value for residential properties (owner occupied) and rental value for commercial property (rental occupation).

  32. 32.

    The overview is based on Franzen and McCluskey (2013: 46–54); McCluskey (1999: 12–17); Norregaard (2013: 24); Bird and Slack (2003: 47–52); Bird and Slack (2004: 26–30); Bell et al. (2009: 1), Gosh and Kundu (2011: 97), and on proposals for a property tax reform in Germany.

  33. 33.

    Market value is determined by demand and supply factors and specific location factors that include the quantity and/or quality of public services. According to RICS (2014a, b: 9) “market value” is defined as: “... the estimated amount for which a asset or liability should exchange on the date of valuation date between a willing buyer and a willing seller in an arm’s length transaction after proper marketing and where the parties had each acted knowledgeably, prudently and without compulsion.”

  34. 34.

    Tax rate = (expenditures needs − non-property revenues)/(total assessed value).

  35. 35.

    Whereas a minimum tax rate may avoid distorting tax competition (property tax decisions play a role in intra-regional location decisions, hence there could be a race-to-the-button), a maximum tax rate avoids distorting tax-exporting (which happens especially when setting higher rates on commercial properties) (Kitchen 2013: 17).

  36. 36.

    The same benefit-rule applies as between municipalities where different levels of public service provision are reflected in different tax rates. They are an indicator for public service differences if Tiebout-like municipalities are given.

  37. 37.

    Proportional rate: As the value of property rises the tax liability rises by the same percentage;

    Progressive rate: As value/size increases, the tax takes an increasing percentage of value/m2;

    Regressive rate: As value/size increases, taxes take a smaller percentage of value/m2.

  38. 38.

    Dillinger (1991: 4) states that the poor performance of the property tax is partly technical. If the tax administration in developing countries would increase the coverage and collection efficiency, the revenue would increase substantially.

  39. 39.

    Properties and taxpayers are usually identified by making use of a geographic reference system such as parcel maps or (as in United Kingdom) street maps with a street address system.

  40. 40.

    Assessing and taxing wealth is quite complex from the administrative perspective, which would be based on the ability-to-pay principle. Therefore, it is more appropriate to tax income from property/wealth instead of wealth only.

  41. 41.

    The frequency of re-assessment recommended by the International Association of Assessing Officers (IAAO) is four to six years for physical reviews and property re-inspection (IAAO 2013: 12).

  42. 42.

    Assessors are still necessary within this approach as they have to test assessments according to their accuracy, equity, and uniformity by the application of standard statistical measures (e.g. ratio studies, coefficient of dispersion, and coefficient of variation) (McCluskey 1999: 29). Further, they have to identify property features that explain selling prices. Thereby, they further improve the mass-appraisal system.

  43. 43.

    Dillinger (1991: 30) got to the heart of deciding upon central or decentral tax administration by stating: “The choice between central and local administration can be characterized […] as trade-off between indifference and incompetence.”

  44. 44.

    Defining ownership is a difficult matter, as much of the urban periphery land in Africa has never been formally adjudicated. The same holds for Latin America, where some formally adjudicated land has been illegally occupied (Dillinger 1991: 25).

  45. 45.

    The penalties imposed have high political and administrative costs. In the case of the administration, they may not pay off directly but perhaps indirectly by increasing the overall tax compliance/collection performance.

  46. 46.

    The method used here is based on a simple model of ratios (see also Linn 1980; Bahl and Linn 1992; Lewis 2003). Bahl and Martinez-Vazquez (2007: 11) formulate a similar equation putting the property tax revenue to GDP, which makes the formula a benchmark for cross-referencing administrative performance among different countries.

  47. 47.

    A combination of administrative failure on coverage, valuation, and collection/enforcement even reinforces the negative impact in a multiplicative manner on the tax revenue.

References

  • Aaron HJ (1975) Who pays the property tax. Studies of government finance. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagchi A (1993) Financing urban local governments – issues and approaches. National Institute of Public Finance & Policy, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Bahl RW (2013) Decentralization of governance in metropolitan areas. In: Property taxation and local government. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 85–105

    Google Scholar 

  • Bahl RW, Linn JF (1992) Urban public finance in developing countries (1. print.). A World Bank book. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Bahl R, Martinez-Vazquez J (2007) The property tax in developing countries: current practice and prospects, Working Paper, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy

    Google Scholar 

  • Bahl RW, Martinez-Vazquez J, Youngman J (2008) The property tax in practice. In: Making the property tax work: experiences in developing and transitional countries. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 3–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandyopadhyay S (2013) Property tax reforms in India: a comparison of Delhi and Bangalore. Working Paper 13–21, Georgia State University, Andrew Young School, International Centre for Public Policy

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell ME, Bing Y, Katrina C (2009) A compendium of states with an area-based tax. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird RM, Slack E (2003) Land and property taxation around the world: a review. J Prop Tax Assess Adm 7(3):31–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird RM, Slack E (2004) Land and property taxation in 25 states: a comparative review. In: International handbook of land and property taxation. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, pp 19–56

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Blankart C (2003) Öffentliche Finanzen in der Demokratie. Verlag Vahlen, München, 5. Auflage

    Google Scholar 

  • Brys B, Matthews S, Herd R, Wang X (2013) Tax policy and tax reform in the People’s Republic of China. OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 18. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan JM (1965) An economic theory of clubs. Economica 32:1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan JM, Goetz CJ (1972) Efficiency limits of fiscal mobility: an assessment of the Tiebout model. J Public Econ 1:25–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dillinger W (1991) Urban property tax reform: guidelines and recommendations. Urban Management and Municipal Finance, World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischel WA (1992) Property taxation and the tiebout model: evidence for the benefit view from zoning and voting. J Econ Lit 30(1):171–177

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischel WA (1985) The economics of zoning laws: a property rights approach to American land use controls. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischel WA (2001) Municipal corporations, homeowners and the benefit view of the property tax. In: Property taxation and local government. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 33–78

    Google Scholar 

  • Franzen R, McCluskey WJ (2013) Value-based approaches to property taxation. In: A primer on property tax – administration and policy. Wiley-Blackwell, West Sussex, pp 41–68

    Google Scholar 

  • George H (1882) Progress and poverty. Appleton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gosh D, Kundu D (2011) Innovations in property taxation systems in India. In: Innovative and property taxation. UN HABITAT, Nairobi

    Google Scholar 

  • Gu AY, Trefzger JW (2000) Make it simple and light: some thoughts on real estate related taxation in China. Int Real Estate Rev 3:142–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Haller H (1981) S. 40 ff.: Die Steuern, 3. Aufl., Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton BW (1975) Zoning and property taxation in a system of local governments. Urban Stud 12:205–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harriss CL, Oates WE (2001) Property taxation and local government finance: essays in honor of C. Lowell Harriss. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Heilbrun J (1983) Who bears the burden of the property tax. In: Lowell Harriss C (ed) The property tax and local finance. The Academy of Political Science, New York, pp 57–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Hong Y-H, Ingram GK (2008) Fiscal decentralization and land policies. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 3–16

    Google Scholar 

  • IAAO (2013) Standard on ratio studies. International Association of Assessing Officers (IAAO), Kansas City

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly R (2003) Property taxation in Indonesia: challenges from decentralization. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly R (2013) Making the property tax work. Working Paper 13-1, International Centre for Public Policy, Andrew Young School, Georgia State University

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitchen H (2013) Property tax: a situation analysis and overview. In: A primer on property tax. Administration and policy. Wiley-Blackwell, West Sussex, pp 1-40

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis BD (2003) Property tax in Indonesia: measuring and explaining administrative (under-) performance. Public Adm Dev. doi:10.1002/pad.268, 227-239

    Google Scholar 

  • Linn JF (1980) Property taxation in Bogota, Colombia: an analysis of poor revenue performance. Public Finance Q 8(4):457–476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathur OP, Rajadhyaksha N, Thakur D (2009) Urban property tax potential in India. National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • McCluskey W (ed) (1999) Property tax: an international comparative review. Ashgate, England

    Google Scholar 

  • McLure CE Jr (ed) (1983) Tax assignment in federal states. Australian National University, Canberra

    Google Scholar 

  • McLure CE Jr (1995) Comment on “the dangers of decentralization” by R. Prud’homme. World Bank Res Obs 10:221–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mieszkowski P (1972) The property tax: an excise tax or a profits tax? J Public Econ 1:73–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mieszkowski P, Zodrow GR (1986) The new view of the property tax: a reformulation. Reg Sci Urban Econ 16(3):309–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohanty PK (2003) Reforming property tax: the approach of municipal corporation of Hyderabad. Working Paper, Centre for Good Governance, Hyderabad

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohanty PK, Misra BM, Goyal R, Jeromi PD (2007) Municipal finance in India: an assessment. Development Research Group Study No. 26, Department of Economic Analysis and Policy, Reserve Bank of India

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave RA (1939) The voluntary exchange theory of public economy. Q J Econ 53:213–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave RA (1959) The theory of public finance: a study in public economy. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave RA, Musgrave PB (1976) Public finance in theory and practice, Second edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Nechyba TJ (2001) The benefit view and the new view. Where do we stand, twenty-five years into the debate? In: Property taxation and local government finance. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 113–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Netzer D (2001) Local property taxation in theory and practice – some reflections. In: Property taxation and local government finance. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 321–338

    Google Scholar 

  • Norregaard J (2013) Taxing immovable property. Revenue potential and implementation challenges. IMF Working Paper, WP13/129

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (1969) The effects of property taxes and local public spending on property values: an empirical study of tax capitalization and the Tiebout hypothesis. J Polit Econ 77:957–971

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (1972) Fiscal federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (1999) An essay on fiscal federalism. J Econ Lit 37:1120–1149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1969) The principle of “fiscal equivalence”: the division of responsibilities among different levels of government. Am Econ Rev 59(2):479–487

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (2001) Property taxation and local government finance. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • RICS (2012) RICS valuation – Professional standards. Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors (RICS), Mar 2012

    Google Scholar 

  • RICS (2014a) The role of international and local valuation standards in influencing valuation practice in emerging and established markets. Royal Institute of Chartered Surveyors (RICS), London

    Google Scholar 

  • RICS (2014b) Global affordable housing report: BRICS plus mortar. Royal Institute of Chartered Surveyors (RICS), London

    Google Scholar 

  • Rondinelli D, Nellis JR, Cheema GS (1983) Decentralisation in developing countries: a review of recent experience, World Bank

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1954) The pure theory of public expenditures. Rev Econ Stat 36:387–389

    Google Scholar 

  • Sennoga EB, Sjoquist DL, Wallace S (2008) Incidence and economic impacts of property taxes in developing and transitional countries. In: Making the property tax work, experiences in developing and transitional countries. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 63–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Slack E (2004) Property taxation in South Africa. In: International handbook of land and property taxation. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, pp 199–204

    Google Scholar 

  • Smoke P (2008) Local revenues under fiscal decentralization in developing countries: linking policy reform, governance, and capacity. In: Fiscal decentralization and land politics. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 38–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout CM (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. Polit Econ 64:416–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu-Hung H, Brubaker D (2011) Integrating the proposed property tax with the public leasehold system. In: Chinas local public finance in transition. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, pp 168–187

    Google Scholar 

  • Yu-Hung H, Murakami J, Suzuki H, Tamayose B (2015) Financing transit-oriented development with land values, adapting land value capture in developing countries. The World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimmermann H (2009) Eine Einführung in die finanzwissenschaftliche Analyse der kommunalen Finanzwirtschaft, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Zorn K (2013) Establishing a tax rate. In: McCluskey WJ, Cornia GC, Walters LC (eds) A primer on property tax: administration and policy. Wiley-Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Salm, M. (2017). Theoretical Insight on the Property Tax. In: Property Tax in BRICS Megacities. Contributions to Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-62671-0_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics