Skip to main content

Approaches to Solving the Eurozone Sovereign Debt Default Problem

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Monetary Policy, Financial Crises, and the Macroeconomy
  • 1220 Accesses

Abstract

The Eurozone sovereign debt crisis stems from a failure in risk management design. In this paper we first present a formal model to clarify the nature of this failure, and then use it to analyse possible solutions. We argue that a long-term solution must involve institutional innovation based on the mutual insurance principle. We also critically discuss existing proposals in the light of our results.

Paper presented at the Conference in Celebration of Gerhard Illing’s 60th Birthday, Munich, 4–5 March 2016.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    From the insurance point of view, the less well-correlated such shocks are the better.

  2. 2.

    See for example Schuknecht et al. (2011).

  3. 3.

    As feared for example by De Grauwe (2011).

  4. 4.

    This is an essential feature which differentiates an insurance system proper from ex post pooling systems using funds contributed by countries in proportion to their GDP, not according to risk.

  5. 5.

    In this area of economic discussion the term “moral hazard” is often used rather loosely, when what is really being discussed is the free rider or common pool/externality problem. In the absence of asymmetric information these can always be solved if binding contracts are available, as is being assumed here.

  6. 6.

    Representative respectively of countries unlikely and countries more likely to run a significant risk of sovereign default.

  7. 7.

    This is simpler than having a labour market setting wages and the government then imposing a wage tax to determine the net wage. Here we can think of setting the wage as essentially choosing the level of taxation.

  8. 8.

    This is made more precise below.

  9. 9.

    For a recent survey and empirical analysis see Beirne and Fratzscher (2013).

  10. 10.

    We are grateful to Frank Heinemann for raising this point.

  11. 11.

    A formal analysis of the portfolio choice, which however is perfectly standard, is presented in the Appendix.

  12. 12.

    In the real situation, this would have been represented by the holdings of Greek debt by EZ banks other than Greek banks, which in the cases of France, Germany and Italy were substantial. Ultimately therefore the losses would have been incurred by the shareholders of these banks. This raises interesting distributional issues, since the bailout transfers are typically funded out of taxation. We do not however explore these in the present paper.

  13. 13.

    There is quite an extensive discussion in the welfare economics of risk of the issue of whether policy should maximise ex ante or ex post welfare. Issues such as the degree of rationality of decision takers and non-welfare maximisation by governments can also be raised here. For example governments often compensate people for flood damage who have bought houses in flood-prone areas and therefore have had that risk capitalised into house prices.

  14. 14.

    However, this assumption is not central and would be easy to change.

  15. 15.

    For this see Arnold (2016).

  16. 16.

    Recall the assumption that the capital market lends to country R at the riskless rate.

  17. 17.

    Bond purchases in country S depend on consumers’ wealth and the price q S on the world capital market, and neither of these changes when B R increases.

  18. 18.

    A more realistic model would have a set of countries with varying default probabilities entering into a mutual insurance arrangement whereby each pays a risk-based premium at date 0, and receives an indemnity at date 1 if and only if a default is necessary. In this context we could also take correlation in countries’ risks into account.

  19. 19.

    As mentioned in the Introduction, to cover the possibility that R would prefer to reject the insurance and run the risk of default, we make acceptance of the insurance scheme a necessary condition for membership of the monetary union.

  20. 20.

    European Council (2012).

  21. 21.

    Sinn (2012, pp. 347–349).

  22. 22.

    Dübel (2011, p. 2).

  23. 23.

    Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der Gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (2011, Chap. 3VI).

  24. 24.

    Sinn (2012, pp. 349f).

  25. 25.

    European Commission (2011, p. 12).

  26. 26.

    European Economic Advisory Group (2011, Chap. 2).

  27. 27.

    Asterisks indicate optimal values.

  28. 28.

    We assume that only P R and μ could be zero at the optimum.

  29. 29.

    Recall that b R S is fixed by the assumption that the price of an R-country bond is q S and consumers in country R have a fixed initial wealth. The world capital market is sufficiently large that variations in the supply of country R’s bonds have no effect on q S.

References

  • Arnold, N. K. (2016). The sovereign default problem in the Eurozone. Munich: ifo Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beirne, J., & Fratzscher, M. (2013). The pricing of sovereign risk and contagion during the European sovereign debt crisis. Journal of International Money and Finance, 34, 60–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borensztein, E., & Panizza, U. (2009). The costs of sovereign default. IMF Staff Papers, 56, 683–741.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cruces, J., & Trebesch, Ch. (2013). Sovereign defaults: The price of haircuts. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5, 85–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, P. (2011). Financial assistance in the Eurozone: Why and how. CESifo Dice Report, 3, 26–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dübel, H.-J. (2011). Partial sovereign bond insurance by the Eurozone: A more efficient alternative to blue (Euro-)bonds. CEPS Papers 5999. Centre for European Policy Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enderlein, H., Guttenberg, L., & Spiess, J. (2013). Blueprint for a cyclical shock insurance in the Euro area. Paris: Notre Europe/Jacques Delors Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2011). GREEN PAPER on the feasibility of introducing stability bonds. COM(2011) 818 final. Brussels. http://ec.europa.eu/commission_2010-2014/president/news/documents/pdf/green_en.pdf.

  • European Council. (2012). Treaty Establishing the European Stability Mechanism. http://www.european-council.europa.eu/media/582311/05-tesm2.en12.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Economic Advisory Group. (2011). The report on the European economy. Munich: CESifo. https://www.cesifo-group.de/DocDL/EEAG-2011.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuest, C., Heinemann, F., & Schröder, Ch. (2015). Accountability Bonds: Eine neue Art von Staatsanleihen. Ökonomenstimme. 9 November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furceri, D., & Zdzienicka, A. (2015). The Euro area crisis: Need for a supranational fiscal risk sharing mechanism. Open Economies Review, 26, 683–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mody, A. (2013). Sovereign debt and its restructuring framework in the Euro area. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 29, 715–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oksanen, H. (2016). Smoothing asymmetric shocks vs. redistribution in the Euro area. CESifo Working Papers 5817.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der Gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. (2011). Verantwortung für Europa wahrnehmen. Jahresgutachten 2011/12. Paderborn: Bonifatius GmbH Buch-Druck-Verlag. http://www.sachverstaendigenrat-wirtschaft.de/fileadmin/dateiablage/download/gutachten/ga11_ges.pdf.

  • Schuknecht, L., Moutot, P., Rother, P., & Stark, J. (2011). The stability and growth pact: Crisis and reform. Cesifo Dice Report, 3, 10–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn, H.-W. (2012). Die Target Falle: Gefahren für unser Geld und unsere Kinder. Munich: Carl Hanser Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • von Weizsäcker, J., & Delpla, J. (2010). The blue bond proposal. Policy Briefs 403. Bruegel.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Frank Heinemann, Michael Hoy and Conference participants, as well as to participants in the Hans Moeller Seminar, LMU on 19th April 2016, for helpful comments and discussion.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ray Rees .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Portfolio Problem

In country j ∈ {R, S} the consumer’s portfolio choice problem is:

$$\displaystyle{ \max _{b_{j}^{R},b_{j}^{S}}u(c_{0}^{\,j}) +\rho \{ (1-\pi )[u(c_{ H}^{\,j}) +\pi u(c_{ L}^{,j})]\} }$$
(35)

given:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} c_{0}^{\,j} = w_{ 0}^{\,j} + b_{ j}^{0} - q^{S}b_{ j}^{S} - q^{R}b_{ j}^{R}& &{}\end{array}$$
(36)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} c_{H}^{\,j} = w_{ H}^{\,j} + b_{ j}^{S} + b_{ j}^{R}& &{}\end{array}$$
(37)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} c_{L}^{\,j} = w_{ L}^{\,j} + b_{ j}^{S} + b_{ j}^{R}(1 - h)& &{}\end{array}$$
(38)

where h is the proportionate loss of income each investor expects as a result of the haircut imposed by country R in state L. As explained in the text, wage rates w are determined by the government at each date/state. We also impose the no-short sales constraints

$$\displaystyle{ b_{j}^{S},b_{ j}^{R} \geq 0 }$$
(39)

though assume that they do not bind. The Lagrange function for the problem is

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \mathcal{L} =\text{ }u(c_{0}^{\,j}) +\rho [(1-\pi )u(b_{j}^{S} + b_{j}^{R} + w_{H}^{\,j}) +\pi u(b_{j}^{S} + b_{j}^{R}(1 - h) + w_{L}^{\,j})]& \\ & +\lambda [b_{0}^{\,j} + w_{0}^{\,j} - q^{S}b_{j}^{S} - q^{R}b_{j}^{R} - c_{0}^{\,j}] &{}\end{array}$$
(40)

FOC areFootnote 27

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial c_{0}^{\,j}} = u^{{\prime}}(c_{ 0}^{\,j{\ast}}) -\lambda ^{{\ast}} = 0& &{}\end{array}$$
(41)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial b_{j}^{S}} =\rho [(1-\pi )u^{{\prime}}(c_{ H}^{\,j{\ast}}) +\pi u^{{\prime}}(c_{ L}^{\,j{\ast}})] -\lambda ^{{\ast}}q^{S} = 0& &{}\end{array}$$
(42)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial b_{j}^{R}} =\rho [(1-\pi )u^{{\prime}}(b_{j}^{S{\ast}} + b_{j}^{R{\ast}} + w_{H}^{\,j}) + (1 - h)\pi u^{{\prime}}(b_{j}^{S{\ast}} + b_{j}^{R{\ast}}(1 - h) + w_{L}^{\,j}]& \\ & -\lambda ^{{\ast}}q^{R} \leq 0; & \\ & \text{ }b_{j}^{R{\ast}}\geq 0;\text{ }b_{j}^{R{\ast}} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial b_{j}^{R}} = 0 &{}\end{array}$$
(43)

Given λ > 0, which follows from (36) with a non-satiation assumption, we have:

$$\displaystyle{ b_{0} + w_{0}^{\,j} - (c_{ 0}^{{\ast}} + q^{S}b_{ j}^{S{\ast}} + q^{R}b_{ j}^{R{\ast}}) = 0 }$$
(44)

Recall that h ∈ [0, 1]. Then by straightforward manipulation of the above conditions we have:

Result 1::

h > 0 and b j R > 0 ⇔ q R < q S

As we would expect, the possibility of a haircut means that if the R-country bonds are to be bought at all, they must be at a discount to the S-country bonds. Indeed:

Result 2::

b j R > 0 ⇔ q Sq R = γh, where γ ≡ [πρu (b j S + b j R(1 − h) + w L j)∕λ ] > 0

Thus the price discount increases with both the size of the haircut, if any, and the probability of the low return state π, as well as with the marginal utility of income in the low state, which also increases with the size of the haircut.

Could the R-country’s bonds ever actually be worthless? Here we have:

Result 3::

π < 1 and \(u^{{\prime}}(.) > 0 \Leftrightarrow q^{R} > 0\forall h \in [0,1]\).

Note that the worst the haircut can be is h = 1. Then if q R = 0 and b j R ≥ 0 we have from (43):

$$\displaystyle{ (1-\pi )u^{{\prime}}(b_{ j}^{S{\ast}} + b_{ j}^{R{\ast}} + w_{ H}^{\,j}) \leq 0 }$$
(45)

which is a contradiction if there is some chance that the better state will occur and consumers are non-satiated. Thus there is always some price at which the R-country bonds will be bought because it yields a positive return in at least one state.

1.2 First Order Conditions for Country R’s Problem

Here we simply present the first order conditions. Interpretation and discussion are given in the text of the paper.

Attaching multipliers λ 0, λ L , λ H to the respective budget constraints and μ to the haircut constraint, and denoting the Lagrange function of the problem by \(\mathcal{L}\), we have the first order conditionsFootnote 28:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial w_{0}^{R}} = n^{R}(u_{ 0}^{{\prime}}-\lambda _{ 0}) = 0& &{}\end{array}$$
(46)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial w_{L}^{R}} = n^{R}(\rho \pi u_{ L}^{{\prime}}-\lambda _{ L}) = 0& &{}\end{array}$$
(47)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial w_{H}^{R}} = n^{R}(\rho (1-\pi )u_{ H}^{{\prime}}-\lambda _{ H}) = 0& &{}\end{array}$$
(48)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial I^{R}} = -\lambda _{0} +\lambda _{L}F_{L}^{{\prime}}(I^{R}) +\lambda _{ H}F_{H}^{{\prime}}(I^{R}) = 0& &{}\end{array}$$
(49)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial B^{R}} = n^{R}\rho \pi u_{L}^{{\prime}} \frac{b_{R}^{R}} {(B^{R})^{2}} \{ \frac{\partial T} {\partial B^{R}}B^{R} - [P^{R} + T(B^{R},P^{R})]\}& \\ & +\lambda _{0}q^{S} -\lambda _{L}C_{R}^{{\prime}}-\lambda _{H} +\mu (1 - \frac{\partial T} {\partial B^{R}}) = 0 &{}\end{array}$$
(50)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial P^{R}} = n^{R}\rho \pi u_{L}^{{\prime}}\frac{b_{R}^{R}} {B^{R}} (1 + \frac{\partial T} {\partial P^{R}}) +\lambda _{L}(C_{R}^{{\prime}}- 1) -\mu (1 + \frac{\partial T} {\partial P^{R}}) \leq 0,& \\ & \text{ }P^{R} \geq 0,\text{ } \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial P^{R}}P^{R} = 0 &{}\end{array}$$
(51)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial \mu } = B^{R} - T(B^{R},P^{R}) - P^{R} \geq 0,\text{ }\mu \geq 0,\text{ }\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial \mu } \mu = 0\text{ }&{}\end{array}$$
(52)

Recall that ∂T∂P R = −1 when T > 0. Here we focus on the interpretation of conditions (50)–(52). There are a number of solution possibilities, depending inter al. on what kind of equilibrium country S will be in.

Case A: Assume T(B R, P R) ≡ 0 and B RP R > 0 so that μ = 0. There is no transfer and a haircut. The conditions then imply:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & q^{S} =\delta _{L}[C_{R}^{{\prime}} +\beta _{ R}^{R}\frac{P^{R}} {B^{R}}] +\delta _{H}&{}\end{array}$$
(53)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \delta _{L}[\beta _{R}^{R} + C_{R}^{{\prime}}(B^{R}) - 1] < 0 \Rightarrow \text{}P^{R} = 0;\text{ }& \\ & P^{R} > 0 \Rightarrow \beta _{R}^{R} + C_{R}^{{\prime}}(B^{R},P^{R}) = 1 &{}\end{array}$$
(54)

where δ H ρ(1 −π)u H u 0 and δ L ρπu L u 0 can be thought of as the planner’s discount factors for time and risk, and β R Rn R b R RB R. Note that we rule out the case in which T(B R, P R) ≡ 0 and μ > 0 since that implies no default even in state L, which is uninteresting.

Case B: Here there is a positive transfer and, from the earlier analysis, the equilibrium condition determining the relationships between T on the one hand and B R, P R on the other is

$$\displaystyle{ 1 -\frac{n^{S}b_{R}^{S}} {B^{R}} = C_{S}^{{\prime}}(B^{R} - P^{R} - T^{{\ast}}) }$$
(55)

As already shown, the comparative statics on this condition yield ∂T ∂P R = −1, but the sign of ∂T ∂B R is ambiguousFootnote 29:

$$\displaystyle{ \frac{\partial T^{{\ast}}} {\partial B^{R}} = -(\frac{n^{S}b_{R}^{S}} {(B^{R})^{2}} - C_{S}^{{\prime\prime}})/C_{ S}^{{\prime\prime}}\lesseqgtr 0 }$$
(56)

and so we have that ∂T ∂B R > 0 ⇔ (n S b R S∕(B R)2C S ′′) < 0. This has to be taken into account in interpreting the first order conditions in this case, in particular (50) above.

In (51), the assumption that B RT(B R, P R) − P R > 0, so there is still a positive haircut, implies the condition:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \delta _{L}(C_{R}^{{\prime}}(B^{R}) - 1) < 0 \Rightarrow \text{}P^{R} = 0;\text{ }& \\ & P^{R} > 0 \Rightarrow C_{R}^{{\prime}}(B^{R},P^{R}) = 1 &{}\end{array}$$
(57)

The difference to case A results from the fact that ∂T ∂P R = −1, the crowding out result.

Case C: Here, there is a complete bailout, and therefore no haircut in state L. The haircut constraint is binding with B RP R = T (B R, P R), and so we can substitute from the haircut constraint into the state L resource constraint to obtain

$$\displaystyle{ F_{L}(I^{R}) - n^{R}w_{ L}^{R} - [P^{R} + C_{ R}(T(B^{R},P^{R}))] \geq 0 }$$
(58)

while dropping the haircut term from the consumer’s state L utility function. As a result, we have the first order conditions:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial B^{R}} =\lambda _{0}q^{S} -\lambda _{L}C_{R}^{{\prime}} \frac{\partial T} {\partial B^{R}} -\lambda _{H} = 0&{}\end{array}$$
(59)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial P^{R}} = -\lambda _{L}(1 + C_{R}^{{\prime}} \frac{\partial T} {\partial P^{R}}) \leq 0,& \\ & \text{ }P^{R} \geq 0,\text{ } \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}} {\partial P^{R}}P^{R} = 0 &{}\end{array}$$
(60)

with the interpretation given in the text.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Rees, R., Arnold, N. (2017). Approaches to Solving the Eurozone Sovereign Debt Default Problem. In: Heinemann, F., Klüh, U., Watzka, S. (eds) Monetary Policy, Financial Crises, and the Macroeconomy. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-56261-2_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics