Advertisement

The Development of Organized Commodity Exchanges in Africa: An Economic Analysis

  • Heinz ZimmermannEmail author
  • Marco Haase
Chapter
  • 659 Downloads

Abstract

After the failure of international commodity price stabilization programs, the development of commodity futures exchanges has been popularized by economists and international agencies. Based on the experience and the history of commodity trading, the successful development of organized, standardized exchanges must be necessarily paired with steps towards improving the basic and financial infrastructure of countries. These improvements are all the more important as they help to improve food security, a major challenge in the upcoming demographic transition of sub-Saharan African societies. However, the outright launch of futures markets might be an excessive first step for most countries.

Keywords

Future Market Commodity Price Future Price Future Contract Cash Market 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

References

  1. AfDB. (2014). Guidebook on African commodity and derivatives exchanges. Abidjan: African Development Bank Group.Google Scholar
  2. Black, D. G. (1986). Success and failure of futures contracts: Theory and empirical evidence, Salomon Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, Graduate School of Business Administration. New York: New York University.Google Scholar
  3. Bremner, J. (2017). Population, food security, and climate change: Africa’s challenge. In H. Groth & J. F. May (Eds.), Africa’s population: In search of a demographic dividend. Dordrecht: Springer.Google Scholar
  4. Brorsen, B. W., & Fofana, N. F. (2001). Success and failure of agricultural futures contracts. Journal of Agribusiness, 19(2), 129–146.Google Scholar
  5. Brown, C. P. (1980). The political and social economy of commodity control. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Carlton, D. W. (1984). Futures markets: Their purpose, their history, their growth, their successes and failures. Journal of Futures Markets, 4(3), 237–271.Google Scholar
  7. CBOT. (1936). The development of the Chicago Board of Trade. Chicago: CBOT.Google Scholar
  8. Dana, J., & Gilbert, C. L. (2009). Managing agricultural price risk in developing countries. In H. Geman (Ed.), Risk management in commodity markets: From shipping to agriculturals and energy (cp. 13). Chichester: Wiley.Google Scholar
  9. Danthine, J.-P. (1978). Information, futures prices, and stabilizing speculation. Journal of Economic Theory, 17(1), 79–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Easterbrook, F. H. (1986). Monopoly, manipulation, and the regulation of futures markets. The Journal of Business, 59(2), 103–127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Everitt, L. (2012). How Africa’s first commodity exchange revolutionized Ethiopia’s economy. Guardian development network, 13 December 2012. https://www.theguardian.com/global-development/2012/dec/13/africa-commodity-exchange-ethiopia-economy. Accessed 26 Jul 2016.
  12. Gilbert, C. L. (1985). Futures trading and the welfare evaluation of commodity price stabilisation. The Economic Journal, 95(379), 637–661.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Gilbert, C. L. (1987). International commodity agreements: Design and performance. World Development, 5(15), 591–616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Gilbert, C. L. (2011). International commodity agreements and their current relevance for grains price stabilization. In A. Prakash (Ed.), Safeguarding food security in volatile global markets (pp. 211–239). Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.Google Scholar
  15. Gray, R. W. (1963). Onions revisited. Journal of Farm Economics, 45(2), 273–276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Gray, R. W. (1966). Fundamental price behavior characteristics in commodity futures. Futures Trading Seminar, Stanford University.Google Scholar
  17. Jacks, D. S. (2007). Populists versus theorists: Futures markets and the volatility of prices, in: Explorations. Economic History, 44, 342–362.Google Scholar
  18. Leuthold, R. M. (1974). The price performance on the futures market of a nonstorable com- modity: Live beef cattle. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 56(2), 271–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Leuthold, R. M. (1994). Evaluating futures exchanges in liberalising economies. Development Policy Review, 12(2), 149–164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. McKinnon, R. I. (1967). Futures markets, buffer stocks, and income stability for primary producers. The Journal of Political Economy, 75, 844–861.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Mohammed, I. N., & Issah, O. (2014). Developing an organized commodity exchange in Ghana: Challenges and economic prospects. International Journal of Finance and Banking, 1(5), 14–29.Google Scholar
  22. Morgan, C. W., Rayner, A. J., & Vaillant, C. (1999). Agricultural futures markets in LDCs: A policy response to price volatility? Journal of International Development, 11(6), 893–910.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Peck, A. E. (1985). The economic role of traditional commodity futures markets. In A. E. Peck (Ed.), Futures markets: Their economic role (pp. 1–81). Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.Google Scholar
  24. Pirrong, C. (1995a). The efficient scope of private transactions-cost-reducing institutions: The successes and failures of commodity exchanges. The Journal of Legal Studies, 24(1), 229–255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Pirrong, C. (1995b). The self-regulation of commodity exchanges: The case of market manipulation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 38(1), 141–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Pirrong, C. (2000). A theory of financial exchange organization. Journal of Law and Economics, 43(2), 437–471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Rashid, S., Winter-Nelson, A., & Garcia, P. (2010). Purpose and potential for commodity exchanges in African economies, IFPRI discussion paper, (01035), 1–21. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.Google Scholar
  28. Telser, L. G. (1981). Why there are organized futures markets. Journal of Law and Economics, 24(1), 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Telser, L. G., & Highbotham, H. N. (1977). Organized futures markets: Costs and benefits. The Journal of Political Economy, 85(5), 969–1000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Tomek, W. G., & Gray, R. W. (1970). Temporal relationships among prices on commodity futures markets: Their allocative and stabilizing roles. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 52(3), 372–380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. UNCTAD. (2003). Economic development in Africa, trade performance and commodity dependence. Geneva: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.Google Scholar
  32. Working, H. (1953). Futures trading and hedging. The American Economic Review, 43(3), 314–343.Google Scholar
  33. Working, H. (1970). Economic functions of futures markets. In futures trading. In H. H. Bakken (Ed.), Livestock: Origins and concepts (pp. 3–48). Chicago Mercantile Exchange: Madison.Google Scholar
  34. World Bank. (1994). Global economic prospects and the developing countries. Washington, DC: The World Bank Group.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer International Publishing AG 2017

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of BaselBaselSwitzerland

Personalised recommendations