Abstract
We provide a unified framework for modeling LIBOR rates using general semimartingales as driving processes and generic functional forms to describe the evolution of the dynamics. We derive sufficient conditions for the model to be arbitrage-free which are easily verifiable, and for the LIBOR rates to be true martingales under the respective forward measures. We discuss when the conditions are also necessary and comment on further desirable properties such as those leading to analytical tractability and positivity of rates. This framework allows to consider several popular models in the literature, such as LIBOR market models driven by Brownian motion or jump processes, the Lévy forward price model as well as the affine LIBOR model, under one umbrella. Moreover, we derive structural results about LIBOR models and show, in particular, that only models where the forward price is an exponentially affine function of the driving process preserve their structure under different forward measures.
Financial support from the PROCOPE project “Financial markets in transition: mathematical models and challenges” and the Europlace Institute of Finance project “Post-crisis models for interest rate markets” is gratefully acknowledged.
Access this chapter
Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout
Purchases are for personal use only
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
- 1.
We could, of course, use the following affine function \(g^k(t,x) = \log F(0,T_k,T_N) + \theta ^k(t) + \vartheta ^k(t)x\) and the model fits automatically the initial term structure. However, it becomes then difficult to provide models that produce non-negative LIBOR rates.
References
Andersen, L.B.G., Piterbarg, V.V.: Interest Rate Modeling, vols. 3. Atlantic Financial Press (2010)
Belomestny, D., Mathew, S., Schoenmakers, J.: Multiple stochastic volatility extension of the LIBOR market model and its implementation. Monte Carlo Methods Appl. 15, 285–310 (2009)
Bianchetti, M., Morini, M. (eds.): Interest Rate Modelling After the Financial Crisis. Risk Books (2013)
Brace, A., Ga̧tarek, D., Musiela, M.: The market model of interest rate dynamics. Math. Financ. 7, 127–155 (1997)
Brigo, D., Mercurio, F.: Interest Rate Models: Theory and Practice, 2nd edn. Springer (2006)
Criens, D., Glau, K., Grbac, Z.: Martingale property of exponential semimartingales: a note on explicit conditions and applications to financial models. Preprint (2015). arXiv:1506.08127
Duffie, D., Filipović, D., Schachermayer, W.: Affine processes and applications in finance. Ann. Appl. Probab. 13, 984–1053 (2003)
Eberlein, E., Kluge, W.: Exact pricing formulae for caps and swaptions in a Lévy term structure model. J. Comput. Financ. 9(2), 99–125 (2006)
Eberlein, E., Kluge, W.: Valuation of floating range notes in Lévy term structure models. Math. Financ. 16, 237–254 (2006)
Eberlein, E., Özkan, F.: The Lévy LIBOR model. Financ. Stoch. 9, 327–348 (2005)
Filipović, D., Trolle, A.: The term structure of interbank risk. J. Financ. Econom. 109, 707–733 (2013)
Glasserman, P.: Monte Carlo Methods in Financial Engineering. Springer (2003)
Goll, T., Kallsen, J.: Optimal portfolios for logarithmic utility. Stoch. Process. Appl. 89, 31–48 (2000)
Grbac, Z., Runggaldier, W.J.: Interest Rate Modeling: Post-Crisis Challenges and Approaches. SpringerBriefs in Quantitative Finance. Springer, Berlin (2015)
Jacod, J., Shiryaev, A.N.: Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes, 2nd edn. Springer (2003)
Jamshidian, F.: LIBOR and swap market models and measures. Financ. Stoch. 1, 293–330 (1997)
Jamshidian, F.: LIBOR Market Model with Semimartingales. Working Paper, NetAnalytic Ltd. (1999)
Kallsen, J.: A didactic note on affine stochastic volatility models. In: Kabanov, Y, Lipster, R., Stoyanov, J. (eds.) From Stochastic Calculus to Mathematical Finance: The Shiryaev Festschrift, pp. 343–368. Springer (2006)
Kallsen, J., Shiryaev, A.N.: The cumulant process and Esscher’s change of measure. Financ. Stoch. 6, 397–428 (2002)
Kallsen, J., Shiryaev, A.N.: Time change representation of stochastic integrals. Theory Probab. Appl. 46, 522–528 (2002)
Keller-Ressel, M., Papapantoleon, A., Teichmann, J.: The affine LIBOR models. Math. Financ. 23, 627–658 (2013)
Klein, I., Schmidt, T., Teichmann, J.: No-arbitrage theory for bond markets. In: Advanced modelling in mathematical finance, pp. 381–421. Springer, Switzerland (2016)
Kluge, W.: Time-inhomogeneous Lévy processes in interest rate and credit risk models. PhD thesis, Univ. Freiburg (2005)
Kluge, W., Papapantoleon, A.: On the valuation of compositions in Lévy term structure models. Quant. Financ. 9, 951–959 (2009)
Ladkau, M., Schoenmakers, J., Zhang, J.: Libor model with expiry-wise stochastic volatility and displacement. Int. J. Portfolio Anal. Manag. 1, 224–249 (2013)
Miltersen, K.R., Sandmann, K., Sondermann, D.: Closed form solutions for term structure derivatives with log-normal interest rates. J. Financ. 52, 409–430 (1997)
Musiela, M., Rutkowski, M.: Continuous-time term structure models: forward measure approach. Financ. Stoch. 1, 261–291 (1997)
Musiela, M., Rutkowski, M.: Martingale Methods in Financial Modelling 2nd edn. Springer (2005)
Papapantoleon, A.: Old and new approaches to LIBOR modeling. Stat. Neerl. 64, 257–275 (2010)
Papapantoleon, A., Schoenmakers, J., Skovmand, D.: Efficient and accurate log-Lévy approximations to Lévy-driven LIBOR models. J. Comput. Financ. 15(4), 3–44 (2012)
Schoenmakers, J.: Robust LIBOR Modelling and Pricing of Derivative Products. Chapman & Hall/CRC Press (2005)
Wheatley, M.: The Wheatley Review of LIBOR. Technical report, HM Treasury (2012)
Wu, L., Zhang, F.: LIBOR market model with stochastic volatility. J. Industr. Manag. Optim. 2, 199–227 (2006)
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Editor information
Editors and Affiliations
Appendix A: Semimartingale Characteristics and Martingales
Appendix A: Semimartingale Characteristics and Martingales
Let \((\Omega ,{\mathcal {F}},({\mathcal {F}}_{t})_{t\in [0,T_*]},{\mathbb {P}})\) denote a complete stochastic basis and \(T_*\) denote a finite time horizon. Let X be an \({\mathbb {R}^{d}}\)-valued semimartingale on this basis whose characteristics are absolutely continuous, i.e. its local characteristics are given by (b, c, F; A) with \(A_{t}=t\), for some truncation function h; cf. Jacod and Shiryaev [15, Proposition II.2.9]. Moreover, let \(f:{\mathbb {R}}_{+}\times {\mathbb {R}^{d}}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}\) be a function of class \(C^{1,2}({\mathbb {R}}_{+}\times {\mathbb {R}^{d}})\).
The process \(f(\cdot , X)\) is a real-valued semimartingale which has again absolutely continuous characteristics. Let us denote its local characteristics by \((b^{f}, c^{f}, F^{f})\) for a truncation function \(h^{f}\). Then, noting that Itô’s formula holds for the function \(f \in C^{1,2}({\mathbb {R}}_{+} \times {\mathbb {R}^{d}})\) and reasoning as in the proof of Corollary A.6 from Goll and Kallsen [13], we have that
Proposition A.1
Let X be an \({\mathbb {R}^{d}}\)-valued semimartingale with absolutely continuous characteristics (b, c, F) and let \(f: {\mathbb {R}}_{+} \times {\mathbb {R}^{d}}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}\) be a function of class \(C^{1, 2}\) such that the process Y defined by
is exponentially special. If the following condition holds
then Y is a local martingale.
Proof
The proof follows from Theorem 2.18 in Kallsen and Shiryaev [19]: set \(\theta =1\) and apply the theorem to the semimartingale \(f(\cdot , X)\). Indeed, since \(f(\cdot , X)\) has absolutely continuous characteristics it is also quasi-left continuous, hence assertions (6) and (1) of Theorem 2.18. yield
By definition of the exponential compensator and Theorem 2.19 in Kallsen and Shiryaev [19] it follows that
Therefore, \(\mathrm {e}^{f(\cdot , X)} \in {\mathcal {M}}_{\mathrm {loc}}\) if and only if \(K^{f(\cdot , X)}(1)=0\) up to indistinguishability. Equivalently,
for every t. Inserting the expressions for \(b^{f}, c^{f}\) and \(F^{f}\), cf. (A.1), into the above equality yields condition (A.3). \(\square \)
Proposition A.2
Let X be an \({\mathbb {R}^{d}}\)-valued semimartingale with absolutely continuous characteristics (b, c, F) such that
and
for some deterministic constants \(C_{1},C_{2}>0\). Moreover, let \(f: {\mathbb {R}}_{+} \times {\mathbb {R}^{d}}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}\) be a function of class \(C^{1, 2}\) and globally Lipschitz with constant \(K>0\) such that
Then, the process \(f(\cdot , X)\) is exponentially special, while the process Y defined by (A.2) and satisfying (A.3) is a uniformly integrable martingale.
Proof
The process \(f(\cdot , X)\) is exponentially special if and only if
Hence, it suffices to show that \({1}_{\{|x|>1\}} \mathrm {e}^{x} *\nu ^{f}_{T_*} < \infty \), as the integrand is positive. Since f is globally Lipschitz, we have
which holds by the Lipschitz property and (A.4).
Moreover, if \(F=\mathrm {e}^{f(\cdot , X)} \in {\mathcal {M}}_{\mathrm {loc}}\), applying Proposition 3.1 in Criens et al. [6] it is also a uniformly integrable martingale if the following condition holds:
for some constant \(C^{f} >0\). We first check the condition for the diffusion coefficient
which follows from (A.5) and the fact that \({\mathrm {D}}f(\cdot , X_{-})\) is bounded as a consequence of f being globally Lipschitz. As for the jump part, we have that
using again the Lipschitz property and (A.4). \(\square \)
Next, we provide the representation of Y as a stochastic exponential.
Lemma A.3
Let X be an \({\mathbb {R}^{d}}\)-valued semimartingale with absolutely continuous characteristics \((B,C,\nu )\) and let \(f:{\mathbb {R}}_{+} \times {\mathbb {R}^{d}}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\) be a function of class \(C^{1,2} ({\mathbb {R}}_{+} \times {\mathbb {R}^{d}})\). Define a real-valued semimartingale Y via (A.2). If \(Y \in {\mathcal {M}}_{\mathrm {loc}}\), then it can be written as
where \(X^{c}\) is the continuous martingale part of X, \(\mu ^{X}\) is the random measure of jumps of X with compensator \(\nu \) and
Proof
Theorem 2.19 in Kallsen and Shiryaev [19] yields that
using that \(f(\cdot , X)\) is quasi-left continuous since X is also quasi-left continuous. Here \(f(\cdot , X)^{c}\) denotes the continuous martingale part of \(f(\cdot , X)\) and \(\mu ^{f}\) its random measure of jumps. The result now follows using the form of the local characteristics \(c^f, F^f\) of the process \(f(\cdot ,X)\) in (A.1); see also the proof of Corollary A.6 in Goll and Kallsen [13].
Lemma A.4
Let X be an \({\mathbb {R}^{d}}\)-valued semimartingale with absolutely continuous characteristics (b, c, F) with respect to the truncation function h. Let \(f:{\mathbb {R}}_{+} \times {\mathbb {R}^{d}}\rightarrow {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\) be a function of class \(C^{1,2}({\mathbb {R}}_{+} \times {\mathbb {R}^{d}})\) and globally Lipschitz. Assume that conditions (A.3), (A.4) and (A.5) are satisfied.
Define the probability measure \({\mathbb {P}}'\sim {\mathbb {P}}\) via
Then, the \({\mathbb {P}}'\)-characteristics of the semimartingale X are absolutely continuous and provided by \((b',c',F')\), where
with \(\beta _t = {\mathrm {D}}f(t,X_{t-})\) and \(Y_t(x)= \mathrm {e}^{f(t,X_{t-}+x) - f(t,X_{t-})}\), for \(t\in {\mathbb {R}}_{+}\) and \(x\in {\mathbb {R}^{d}}\).
Proof
The result follows directly from the previous lemma and Proposition 2.6 in Kallsen [18]. \(\square \)
Rights and permissions
Copyright information
© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland
About this paper
Cite this paper
Glau, K., Grbac, Z., Papapantoleon, A. (2016). A Unified View of LIBOR Models. In: Kallsen, J., Papapantoleon, A. (eds) Advanced Modelling in Mathematical Finance. Springer Proceedings in Mathematics & Statistics, vol 189. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-45875-5_18
Download citation
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-45875-5_18
Published:
Publisher Name: Springer, Cham
Print ISBN: 978-3-319-45873-1
Online ISBN: 978-3-319-45875-5
eBook Packages: Mathematics and StatisticsMathematics and Statistics (R0)