JEL Classification

Keywords

1 Introduction

Brazil is one of the most unequal societies in contemporary world. From 1960 to 2000, the Gini coefficients of income per capita distribution remained practically constant around 0.6, one of the highest levels recorded at national level (Ipeadata 2014). In broad historical perspective, both institutional and geographic factors played fundamental roles in the generation and reproduction of Brazilian inequality in space and time. Slavery has had and still has overwhelming implications for social equity. Concentration of income and wealth and the low levels of education prevailing today are, to a large extent, her legacies. Needless to say, this is not an excuse for the ostensible lack of social concerns of government policies during most of the twentieth century.

Geographic factors were also decisive for spatial inequality. The continental size and the geographic heterogeneity of the country compounded with very high transport costs to create wide spatial disparities in the levels of productivity and income per capita. According to our estimates, The Gini coefficient of the distribution of municipal GDP per capita was above 0.45 in 1872 and remained above 0.4 from 1940 to 1980 when it started declining to reach 0.3 in 2000. Moreover, Theil decomposition exercises show that the contribution of the interregional component to inequality of municipal GDP per capita increased systematically from 20% in 1872 to almost 50% in 2000 (Barros et al. 1995; Azzoni 1997, 1999; Azzoni et al. 2000).

The historical roots of regional disparities are widely discussed in the Brazilian literature (Bértola et al. 2006; Buescu 1979; Cano 1993, 1997; Castro 1969; Denslow 1977; Furtado 1968, 1970; Leff 1972, 1973, 1991; Marcondes 2005). The discussion, however, lacks an adequate empirical basis. Statistical evidence when available is restricted to sparse data at state or macro-regional level. The sharp economic differences inside Brazilian states are completely neglected.

The chapter provides historical perspectives on spatial economic inequalities in Brazil. For this purpose it analyzes the spatial patterns of Brazilian economic growth making use of a database on Brazilian municipalities from 1872 to 2000. The first section offers a succinct account of the geographic forces shaping the secular development of the Brazilian economy highlighting the evolution of transport costs. The second section uses a series of maps to describe the spatial progression of income per capita and labor productivity from 1872 to 2000. In a more rigorous fashion, the third section estimates econometric models of growth convergence for municipal income per capita and labor productivity during the same period. The econometric analysis for the period 1919–2000 is refined in three ways. Firstly, by assuming spatial correlation among variables of the model; secondly, by disaggregating the model for urban and rural activities; and, thirdly, by enlarging the model to take account of the factors conditioning the patterns of spatial growth convergence in the twentieth century. The final section summarizes the results and proposes research extensions. The database is described in Reis (2014).

The main findings of the chapter are: (1) Municipal concentration of income per capita in Brazil, both between and within regions, is extremely high and has deep historical roots. (2) Spatial convergence of income per capita since 1872 has been very slow when compared to the economies of Europe, the USA, and Japan. (3) Spatial convergence, if any, was particularly slow during the import substitution phase from 1920 to 1980 compared to the primary export-led phases that took place in the other periods. (4) The main factors conditioning the growth of municipal income per capita from 1920 to 2000 are the conditions of accessibility (measured by the index of potential market in 1920) and transport infrastructure (measured by the presence of a railroad station in 1920), as well as the share of foreigners in total population in 1920. (5) The effects of railroad on urban output and foreigners on rural output were persistent throughout the decades. (6) Otherwise, institutional factors measured by variables like concentration of wealth (farm ownership in 1920), illiteracy rates in 1920, electoral participation in 1914, and share of slaves back in 1872, individually or jointly considered, have no significant effects on the growth of municipalities from 1920 to 2000. Thus, except by the effects of foreigner’s contribution, it is fair to say that institutions played no role and therefore the chapter endorses the preeminence of geographic factors as determinants of the growth of Brazilian municipalities during the twentieth century.

2 Geography and History

The main historical driver of the geographic patterns of economic development in Brazil was the prohibitive transport costs to the hinterland imposed by the strong declivity of the coastal mountain range running parallel to the Atlantic shoreline (Ellis 1951; Goulart Filho and Queiroz 2011; Silva 1949; Summerhill 2003). The slope of the Serra do Mar—reaching 1000 m 100 km away from the sea—complemented by the intense summer rainfall and the dense rainforest hindered the development of a transportation infrastructure and therefore the economic settlement of the Brazilian hinterland.

In the Northeast region, the Borborema Range as well as the poor soil and dry climate of the Semiarid areas made agricultural settlements hardly unsustainable beyond the seashore strip occupied by the sugar plantations since early colonial times (Milet 1881; Andrade 1973). The settlement of the mining areas in the Center-South region during the eighteenth century was made feasible by the negligible transport costs—high specific value—of precious minerals (Cano 1973). But with historical hindsight, it is fair to say that after the exhaustion of mines, high transport costs became a severe constraint to the economic development of the region during most of the nineteenth century (Martins 2004; Bergad 1999; Libby 1988). Finally, in the Amazon region where navigable rivers sanctioned low transport costs, the wild vegetation, unhealthy climate, and the poor quality of soil precluded agrarian settlement up to the last quarter of the twentieth century. Starting in 1850, however, rubber extraction supported a thriving regional economy up to 1912 when the competition of Asian plantations brought the collapse to rubber prices and export values (Santos 1980; Weinstein 1983).Footnote 1

The railroad investments in the third quarter of the nineteenth century were crucial for the viability of agrarian settlements in the hinterland. Transport cost reductions in the order of 80% pushed the coffee frontier towards western São Paulo (Matos 1974; Milliet 1982; Summerhill 1997; Pinto 1903) and southeast Minas Gerais (Lima 1981, Oliveira 2005). Concomitantly, the city of São Paulo emerged as the most important hub (the node with minimum transport cost) of the railway network, thus pulling industries to exploit economies of scale and emerging as the sustainable industrial growth pole of the country in the beginning of the twentieth century (Cano 1985). For other regions, however, the reduction in transport costs provided by railways had diverse consequences leading to the specialization in agriculture and to the loss of competitiveness in manufacturing and handcraft production which were previously protected by the high transport costs (Cano 1993; Martins 1983; Reis and Monasterio 2010; Restitutti 2008; Stein 1957; Trew 2014).

Starting in the 1890s, the concentration of industry in São Paulo was enhanced by the synergies and externalities provided by the agglomeration of technological knowledge and human capital of foreign immigrants (Cano 1993; Reis and Monasterio 2010; Versiani 1993). Conversely, subsidized foreign immigration aggravated the segmentation of the Brazilian labor market reducing their effectiveness in reducing regional disparities in productivity and income. Thus, until the 1930s, internal migration to São Paulo was relatively meager despite huge regional differences in productivity and income per capita (Graham 1972; Graham and Hollanda 1971).

In the second half of the twentieth century, government investment in transport infrastructure concentrated on highways which gradually replaced the railroads. The initial impact of the highway option, however, was to reinforce the hegemonic position of São Paulo, thus preserving regional disparities. Indeed, the dispersed network of highways reduced logistics costs of the distribution of manufactured goods in the domestic market in relation to the long haul transport cost incurred to export primary products. Analogously, it reduced the costs of internal migration, thus stimulating the migration flows to large cities and ensuring “unlimited” supply of labor that dampened pressures for urban wage increases, particularly in Sao Paulo and Rio de Janeiro (Barat 1978; Castro 2003; Galvao 1999; Graham 1972; Graham and Hollanda 1971; Oliveira 1977).

During the 1960s, the federal capital moved to Brasília and the federal government started to implement other regional development policies, combining investments in infrastructure, fiscal, and credit incentives. The priority given to highways in detriment of railways was inadequate for the transportation requirements of the agricultural exports from flatlands of the Cerrado areas in the Center-West and North regions of the country. As a consequence, the growth of agricultural productivity and output in these areas were retarded in the last quarter of the century (Castro 2002; Gasques and Yokomizo 1985; Reis and Blanco 2000; Reis and Margullis 1990; Silveira 1957; Weinhold and Reis 2008; Andersen et al. 2002).

From 1968 to 1995, the expansion of the road infrastructure reduced the costs of moving one unit of cargo to São Paulo (a good proxy for the domestic market) more than 40%. Despite that, high transport costs still remain one of the most critical obstacles to Brazilian competitiveness and development. In the Cerrado areas in the Center-West and North regions, in addition to the reduction of transport costs, the profitability of economic activities was enhanced by the possibilities of agricultural mechanization of the flatlands. Another crucial factor in this way was Embrapa’s agricultural research which adapted new cultivars—in particular soybeans, rice, and cotton—to the ecological conditions prevailing in the region (Arantes and Souza 1993; Helfand and Rezende 1998; Homma 2003). Naturally, the causal relationships between transport infrastructure, mechanization, and biogeochemical innovations are hard to disentangle.

3 Spatial Patterns of Growth, 1872–2000

This section uses a series of maps and graphs to illustrate the spatial patterns of Brazilian development. The number of Brazilian municípios increased from 642 in 1872 to 5507 in 2000. Thus, to allow consistent inter-temporal analysis, municípios are combined in 432 Minima Comparable Geographic Areas from 1872 to 2000 (MCA 1872–2000; Reis 2008, 2014; Reis et al. 2005, 2011).Footnote 2 Though the time benchmarks of the analysis are primarily determined by Census years, they are useful to provide a fairly broad characterization of the main phases of Brazilian development during the period (Reis et al. 2002).

Figure 1a, f shows the huge spatial disparities of income per capita and labor productivity in 1872. The Northeast, in particular the semiarid areas of the hinterland, was already the poorest region of the country.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Brazil: Geographic distribution (AMC 1872–2000) of income per capita (GDP/population) and of labor productivity (GDP/labor force) in (a, f) 1872, (b, g) 1919, (c, h) 1949, (d, i) 1980, and (e, j) 2000 (units and scale variable). Source: IBGE and author’s estimates

The richest areas were located around the city of Rio de Janeiro, which was then the capital and the largest port of the country, and the cities of Rio Grande and Porto Alegre in the extreme south of the country which were the main ports for the fertile Pampas. The high productivity and income per capita levels in the Amazon region are explained by the rubber boom. Note, in passing, that the economic activity in the highlands was practically restricted to the old mining areas of the Center-South region.

From 1872 to 1920, growth was mainly driven by the export of primary commodities, in particular rubber in the North region and coffee in the Center-South region which pushed the economic frontier in the southwest direction. Figure 1b, g shows that, in 1920, São Paulo and Rio Grande do Sul display the highest levels of income per capita and labor productivity, both states combining a very productive agriculture with emerging manufacturing activities. By then, the rubber exports in the Amazon had busted.

From 1920 to 1950, the country completed the first stage of industrialization mainly based upon the import substitution of consumer goods. During this period, the city of São Paulo and her surroundings consolidated their place as the dominant industrial pole of the country. Figure 1c, h shows that the concentration of income per capita in São Paulo was intensified by the mid-twentieth century when the processes of urbanization and industrialization reached their peaks. Coffee expansion explains the spread of high income per capita towards the southwest areas of São Paulo and Paraná.

From 1950 to 1980, coupled with an accelerated urbanization process, high trade protection, and strong state intervention, the import substitution industrialization deepened going into durable consumer goods, basic raw materials, and capital goods industries. Despite record high rates of growth, by the end of this period, the Brazilian economy was autarkic and inefficient with a definite policy bias against primary exports. Figure 1d, i shows that, during this period, economic activity definitely turned towards the northwest direction led by the move of the federal capital to Brasilia as well as by other regional policies which fostered the expansion of the agricultural crops like cattle, rice, soybean, and corn.

After 1980, autarky and inefficiency charged their tolls with debt crisis, hyperinflation, and stagnation. In the ensuing decades the unavoidable policies were stabilization, fiscal adjustment, and liberalization which are still lurking. Trade liberalization policies eliminated a large part of the bias against exports of primary commodities which became one of the main sources of growth during this period. On top of that, the country faced the end of the urbanization process and the emergence of population ageing. With the vanishing of import substitution policies, the high levels of income per capita started spreading towards the agricultural frontier in the Center-West and North regions. São Paulo and Rio Grande do Sul kept their leading positions while the Northeast region lagged far behind the rest of the country. By 2000, both in terms of income per capita and labor productivity, the secular divide of the country in the northwest-southeast direction still persisted.Footnote 3

Closing this section, Fig. 2 presents Lorenz curves for the municipal income per capita distribution for the Census years.Footnote 4 The highest spatial concentration took place in 1872 (Gini = 0.45) with the respective Lorenz curves practically enveloping the other years. Conversely, the lowest spatial concentration took place in 2000 (Gini = 0.32) with a Lorenz curve that is practically enveloped by all the other years. But the process of spatial dispersion of income per capita was far from monotonic. The curves display a strong dispersion from 1872 to 1919 (Gini decreases from 0.45 to 0.36), when the economy was driven by coffee and rubber exports, and more so from 1970 to 2000 (Gini decreases from 0.45 to 0.32) when growth was driven by mining and the agricultural frontier in the Cerrado areas of the Center-West region. Conversely, there is strong concentration from 1919 to 1970 (Gini increases from 0.36 to 0.45) during the heydays of urbanization and import substitution industrialization. It should be kept in mind, however, that during the import substitution period growth rates of the economy were significantly higher.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Lorenz curves of the municipal distributions of GDP according to municipal population, 1872–2000. Source: Author’s estimates

4 Secular Patterns of Convergence of Labor Productivity and Income Per Capita in Brazil, 1872–2000

This section analyzes the patterns of spatial convergence of municipal income per capita and labor productivity from 1872 to 2000. For this purpose, it estimates very simple convergence models where the growth rates of income per capita and of labor productivity in a period of time are specified as a function of the respective variable—income per capita or labor productivity—in the initial year of the period in case.

The basic specification of the convergence model is thus

$$ \log {\left({y}_{i,t}/{y}_{i,t-n}\right)}^{1/n}=\alpha +\beta \cdot \log \left({y}_{i,t-n}\right) $$

where

\( {y}_{i,t}=\left({Y}_{i,t}/{\mathrm{Pop}}_i\right) \) is GDP per capita (or GDP per labor force) in municipality i, Census year; Y i,t is GDP per capita in municipality i, Census year t; and Pop i,t is population (or labor force) in municipality i, Census year t. β is an estimated coefficient that measures the speed of convergence of income per capita (or labor productivity) of municipalities.

To further investigate the processes of convergence estimations were also made assuming spatial autocorrelation in both the dependent (SACD) and residual (SACR) variables of the equations.

The first model (SACD) assumes spatial inertia in the growth of income or of labor productivity. Thus, without specifying the underlying causes, the model assumes that growth is transmitted to contiguous municipalities through contagion. Emulation, migration of labor, capital, and/or technology are possible explanations of the contagious processes.

The second model (SACR) assumes that the residuals of the growth variables are subject to spatial autocorrelation. That is, the determinants of the growth processes other than the initial income per capita or labor productivity, though unknown, are supposed to be subject to spatial inertia as in the case of most geographic variables, or else to be subject of spatial contagion through markets, social contacts, shared local culture, or institutions. Note, however, that the speed of convergence is now measured among groups of contiguous municipalities that have some common unspecified determinants of the growth of productivity. In this way, it is a convergence conditionally measured. Spatial clusters of municipalities are converging to different steady-state levels of income per capita or labor productivity.

Estimates of β, the speed of municipal convergence, of both income per capita (GDP/Population) and labor productivity (GDP/Labor force) for the three models in the 1872–2000 period, as well as for the subperiods 1872–1919, 1919–2000, 1919–1949, 1949–1980, and 1980–2000, are presented in columns 2–5 of Table 1 (Reis 2014 for more detailed results). Columns 3 and 5 show the coefficients of spatial autocorrelations (SAC) of the dependent variables and the residuals of the respective equation.

Table 1 Brazil: estimates of beta-convergence for GDP per capita and labor productivity, 1872–2000 and subperiods

Before coming to the regression results it is interesting to observe that, in the period 1872–2000, average municipal growth rates were slightly higher for income per capita (1.80% p.a.) than for labor productivity (1.65% p.a.), thus indicating that, on average, labor force grew a bit faster than population, that is, on average, the dependency ratio increased 0.015% during this period. Equivalent figures for 1920–2000 are 3.4% p.a. and 4.5% p.a., respectively, thus indicating that, on average, the dependency ratio decreased 1.1% p.a.

For the whole 1872–2000 period, OLS estimates of β for income per capita and labor productivity are −0.006 and −0.005, both significant at 0.001 probability level. Thus, municipalities with 1% more in the level of income per capital in 1872 had 0.005 less in their annual average growth rates from 1872 to 2000. The speed of convergence is quite small and practically the same for both income per capita and labor productivity.

Spatial autocorrelation effects are relatively large for the residual of the equation of income per capita and thus taking account of them makes a difference for the estimate of the speed of convergence of income per capita. Thus, from 1872 to 2000, unexplained geographic as well as other spatially correlated factors (like quality of soil, altitude, climate, distance to sea or to the state capital, culture, institutions) had a significant effect on the growth of municipal income per capita—but not on the productivity of labor.

Looking across subperiods, note first that the speed of convergence, β, for the 1872–1919 period shows a significant increase for labor productivity but not for income per capita. A suggested explanation is the effects on labor productivity of the changes in the dependency ratio and women participation rates related to the demise of slavery and impact of foreign immigration. The second observation is that spatial autocorrelation of the residuals in the equation of labor productivity is much higher for this period but the convergence of labor productivity is not much affected.

From 1920 to 2000, the speed of convergence of income per capita and labor productivity became even slower, except for the estimation taking account of the spatial autocorrelation of residuals of the respective equations. Thus, geographic as well as other factors correlated in space played an even more important role in the processes of municipal growth during the twentieth century. Looking at specific subperiods, however, the speed convergence is relatively faster, particularly from 1980 to 2000.

It is difficult to pinpoint the forces shaping this historical pattern of convergence. From 1872 to 1919, the collapse of rubber frontier in the North Region is part of the explanation of the slower rates of convergence estimated. From 1919 to 1980, the import substitution industrialization was associated with urban concentration, economies of scale, and agglomeration, thus implying the slow rates of convergence of income and productivity. After 1970, regional government policies coupled with the natural resources content of the exports of minerals and agricultural commodities were responsible for the faster growth dispersion in both industry and agriculture. It should be kept in mind, however, that average growth rates were much higher in the import substitution phases. Finally, changes in the dependency ratio associated with migration and urbanization trends probably played differential roles across subperiods.

Compared to other countries, the convergence of municipal income per capita in Brazil was quite slow. Indeed, estimates of β are close to –0.02, both in the case of personal income in the US states in the period 1950–1980 and of income per capita of Japanese municipalities in the period 1955–1987 (Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995). Equivalent estimates for income per capita of Italian municipalities are –0.025 for the period 1951–1970, and –0.003 for the period 1970–2000 (Arbia et al. 2002; Felice 2013)). The magnitude of those estimates is significantly higher than those estimated for Brazil in the periods 1950–1980 or 1980–2000.

For the whole 1872–2000 period estimations are also disaggregated by main regions—North, Northeast, Center-South, South, and Center-West—to get a more detailed picture of geographic patterns of convergence of income per capita and labor productivity. Results not reported here (see Reis 2014) show that in all regions the speed of convergence was a bit faster than in the country as a whole, thus suggesting a secular process of divergence among regions which was counteracted by a slow process of spatial convergence inside each region. The concentration of import substitution industrialization in the Center-South region of the country and the marked regional contrasts in soil aptitude and agricultural development were, undoubtedly, major factors in process of regional divergence. Inside the regions, the speed of convergence was faster in the South and in the North Region, but slow in the Northeast. For all regions, however, β estimates were still exceedingly low in international perspective.

In what follows, the analysis of growth convergence of labor productivity in the period 1919–2000 will be detailed in two ways: first, by the disaggregation of the analysis for urban and rural activities, and, second, by assuming spatial correlation among the variables of the model as well as among equations of describing the processes of urban and rural growth. This is made possible because for the 1919–2000 period the economic censuses allow the estimation of separate convergence equations for labor productivity in rural (agriculture) and urban (nonagricultural) activities.Footnote 5

A preliminary finding is that the average growth of labor productivity was higher in agriculture (2.6% p.a.) than in urban activities (2.4% p.a.). To a large extent the explanation lies in the weight of the service sector and all kinds of low-productivity informal activities in the growth of urban output and employment.

Convergence was faster for labor productivity than for income per capita, both however extremely low when compared with other countries. The faster convergence of labor productivity is difficult to interpret without further analysis of demographic patterns of growth—dependency ratio, in particular—during this period.

Convergence equation for the growth of labor productivity in rural and urban activities in the 1920–2000 period shows that the speed of convergence was faster for urban activities, though both are still very low compared to international standards. This result sounds reasonable given the relatively footloose characteristics of urban activities, while agriculture depends on the availability of adequate soils and climate which are concentrated in specific areas—particularly in the South and Center-West regions—of the country.

It is interesting to observe that both rural and urban activities show higher speed of convergence than aggregate labor productivity in the economy, thus suggesting that there were synergies and cross-correlations between the processes of growth in labor productivity in both sectors. Rural and labor productivity grew faster or slower in the same areas, thus characterizing patterns of growth high-high or low-low in both sectors.

Finally, the last model combines the assumption of correlation of residuals of the growth convergence equations for labor productivity in urban and rural activities with the assumption of spatial autocorrelation in the residuals of each of the equations (SURE + SACR). The results are pretty similar to the ones obtained with the SACR model. Thus, what matters most for the process of convergence of labor productivity in rural and urban activities is the spatial autocorrelation observed for each of these activities and not the correlation between the growth of productivity in rural and urban activities. Thus, residual factors in the growth convergence equations of labor productivity in the rural and urban activities and the growth of labor productivity in rural and urban activities in the Brazilian economy during the twentieth century were quite independent processes with each of them subject to spatial inertia processes.

5 Factors Conditioning Convergence Patterns, 1920–2000

To analyze the determinants of the growth patterns of the Brazilian economy in the period 1920–2000, the specifications of the growth convergence equations are enlarged to incorporate the determinants of steady-state growth rates of Brazilian municipalities. This is made by the specification of a conditional model introducing variables like infrastructure, geographical attributes, institutions, and human capital, among others, as exogenous determinants of the growth of municipalities from 1920 to 2000.Footnote 6

In the case of the growth of GDP per capita, the model to be estimated becomes

$$ \log {\left({y}_{i,t}/{y}_{i,t-n}\right)}^{1/n}=\alpha +\beta \cdot \log \left({y}_{i,t-n}\right)+\gamma \cdot {X}_{i,t-n} $$

where

y i,t = Y i,t /Pop i ( or Y i,t /Labor i ) is the aggregate, urban, or rural labor productivity (GDP/labor force) or GDP per capita of município i in year t.

Y i,t is the aggregate, urban, or rural GDP of município i in year t; Pop i,t is the total, urban, or rural population of município i in year t.

Labor i,t is the aggregate urban or rural labor force of the município i in year t.

X i,tn = matrix of explanatory variables including all the exogenous variables that explain the steady-state rate of growth of Brazilian municipalities from 1920 to 2000.

The explanatory factors are listed in the first column of Table 2. They include major characteristics of the municipalities in terms of geography (area, latitude, longitude, altitude, temperature, precipitation, soil types, etc.), demography (population, foreign population, labor force), economy (GDP by sectors, landownership concentration, electricity generation, area of farms, share of coffee in cropped area), accessibility and transport (existence and age of railway station, distance to sea, and distance to capital, potential market index), human capital and education (literacy, enrollment, and number of primary schools), and a few institutional dimensions like the number of slaves in 1872 and the number of voters in 1910. Most of the variables refer to 1920. The exceptions are slavery, schools, and voters which were not available for 1920, and, obviously, geographic conditions. For a description of the definition and measurement of exogenous variables see Reis (2014) and Reis et al. (2007).

Table 2 Brazil: OLS estimation of conditional growth convergence of GDP per capita and labor productivity in urban and rural activities, 1919–2000

Estimation results presented in Table 2 show that initial socioeconomic conditions in 1920 explain more than 50% of the variance of the growth rates of Brazilian municipalities in the period 1920–2000. Note that the OLS estimations of simple growth convergence in equations of Table 2 explained around 15%.

The speed of convergence is approximately equal to 1 for both income per capita and labor productivity. For urban and agriculture activities the estimates for GDP per worker are 1.2, approximately. These values are relatively small given that they refer to estimates of the speed of conditional growth convergence of municipalities which had similar conditions in 1920. Thus, even among municipalities with similar initial conditions the speed of convergence is slow compared to other countries.

In Table 2 the variables with estimated coefficients significant at 5% level are considered relevant as growth factors and as such marked with one asterisk. Two asterisks denote the threshold of 1% significance level. Whenever meaningful, variables were specified as logarithm except when there is a high incidence of null observations in which case they were specified in per capita terms.

Estimation results show that population in 1920 is not significant in all the equations (marginally in the case of the growth labor productivity) but is kept as a normalizing variable for all the other variables.

The most important variable is the dummy for the existence of a railway station in 1920. Ceteris paribus, that would imply an increase of 14% p.a. in average growth rates from 1920 to 2000. This a huge impact but is restricted to urban activities; growth rates of agricultural productivity were not significantly affected by the existence of a railroad in 1920. The problem with the estimation of this coefficient is that railroad stations could be capturing the effects of omitted variables related to transportation costs, accessibility, and other previous locational advantages. Places which had previous advantages in terms of access and natural resources availability were likely to grow faster in the long run and to that extent railroad stations would be endogenously located and its coefficient biased upward. A possible solution would be to use as instrumental variables describing transport accessibility previous to railways like, for example, distance to main seaports by mule troops in pre-railways times. The difficulty, however, is the ubiquity of mule roads which imposes the need of some qualification. A better alternative, perhaps, would be to use transport costs to main markets instead of railroad station. Our future research will be directed in both ways.

The age of the railway station is also significant though it has very small positive effect on the average growth rate. Early comers in the railway access have had a small lasting growth advantage.

To be a state capital was also an important factor for the secular growth rate of both income per capita and labor productivity. The increases in average growth rates in the period 1920–2000 were 0.5% for GDP per capita and 0.4% for GDP per worker. The suggested explanation is the better accessibility to all kinds of infrastructure and government services. Surprisingly, perhaps, when we disaggregate the results, the effect is only marginally significant in the growth for urban activities, and, as expected, not significant for the growth of agricultural productivity.

The distance to a state capital, however, had a positive effect on the growth rate of labor productivity in agriculture but none on the other growth variables. It looks like as the consequence of home market effects or some form of access to technology, since state capital is both more rich and populated as well as sources of knowledge and human capital.

Other infrastructure variables with significant effects have to do with electricity generation. Both the number of companies of electricity generation installed in a municipality in 1920 and their capacity of generation (in Kw) in that same year had a significant positive effect on the secular growth rate of GDP per capita and per worker. Each additional company brings 0.1% of increase in the annual average secular growth of the municipality. The effect is wholly due to industry. Growth rates of GDP per worker in agriculture are not affected by electricity infrastructure, as we should expect, given the fact the electrification of rural areas was practically absent in 1920.

Apart from infrastructure, the other important factor is the potential market of the municipality in 1920 measured by the average GDP of Brazilian municipalities weighted by the inverse of their geographic distances to the municipality in case. Each percent implied 0.001% more of average growth rates in 1920–2000. Thus, municipalities that were close to rich municipalities in 1920 grew more in the 1920–2000 period. Thus, market agglomeration effects were important and, as a consequence, demand factors and historical accidents probably played important roles in the spatial pattern of growth.

Foreign-born population was also an important factor of productivity and income per capita growth. Interestingly, however, the effect was mainly felt in the growth of agricultural productivity. For the growth of urban productivity it was not significant. Suggested explanations are capital, technology, human capital, as well as cultural and institutional innovations introduced by the immigrants in the agricultural sector.Footnote 7 It could as well be that migrants anticipated the agricultural growth prospects of the areas for where they migrated. In that case, the coefficient would be biased upward. Note, however, that coffee as percent of agricultural establishments is not a significant explanatory variable. And apart from that fact, it is difficult to envisage their successful prospection methods, in particular because they were likely to be ignorant about the agronomic conditions and growth possibilities of the different areas.

Agricultural activities tend to show some inertial or cumulative features in that the growth of agricultural productivity was higher in the municipalities with larger labor force in agriculture and area of a larger share of agricultural establishments in 1920. Note, however, that the size of total labor force tends to decrease the growth of agricultural productivity.

Geographic variables have some expected effects and other quite surprising. Thus, the effects of temperature and precipitation on the growth of GDP per capita are not significant. Moreover, the significance of soils in GDP per capita growth is probably capturing the the effects of state dummy that should be introduced as shown by the joint significance tests reported below.

Finally, the model tests the importance of some institutional conditions on the development of municipalities (Engerman and Sokolloff 1997, 2012; Nunn 2007). The proxies of institutional conditions included were the share of slaves in total population in 1872; Theil index for landownership concentration in 1920; a group of variables related to education including the literacy rate of population in 1920, and four other variables describing the availability of schools as well as the attendance of schools in 1907; and, finally, political participation in 1914 as measured by the share of registered voters in total population.

The results show that, surprisingly, solely or jointly considered, none of the institutional proxies selected were statistically significant (at the 5% level) factors for the growth of Brazilian municipalities in the twentieth century. The only significant proxy of institutional factors is, therefore, the share of foreign-born population in 1920.

To test the institutional hypothesis, variables were jointly tested in three groups of variables composed as follows:

  1. (A)

    Slavery in 1872 + Registered voters in 1910 + landownership concentration in 1920

  2. (B)

    Education condition described by literacy rate in 1920 + students enrolled in public and private schools in 1910 + the number of public and private primary schools in 1910

  3. (C)

    The share of foreign-born population in 1920

As shown in Table 3, F-tests for the joint significance of A, B, A + B, and A + B + C were conducted with the result that, at 5% confidence level, A, B, and A + B are not significant in all cases. Only A + B + C is significant which is not surprising given that the share of foreign-born population was already significant when singly considered. But in the case of the growth of labor productivity in urban activities even A + B + C is not significant. Thus, climate conditions were binding factors for Brazilian agricultural growth but soil conditions and altitude were circumvented.

Table 3 F-tests of joint significance for the conditional growth equations of GDP per capita and labor productivity, 1919–2000

Finally, Table 3 also presents test of joint significance for the main geographic factors. Results show that, jointly considered, temperature and precipitation were significant explanatory factors for the growth of rural labor productivity. Surprisingly, however, altitude and geomorphology of soils were significant explanatory factors for the growth of income per capita and of labor productivity in the economy, as well as of the growth of labor productivity in urban areas, but not for the growth of rural labor productivity.

It should be pointed that the prevalence of slavery in 1872 gives a biased picture of the secular and persistent effects of the institution because concentration of the slave population in the booming coffee areas took place in a few decades during the mid-nineteenth century. Indeed, contradicting Nunn (2007), there is a strong positive correlation between the slave share of population in 1872 and the growth of income per capita from 1920 to 2000. Thus, to some extent the share of slaves in 1872 is also endogenous to the development prospects of this region. To circumvent this problem we use instead the data on free black population in 1872. The rationale is that a large share of free blacks (pardos e pretos livres in 1872) is a better proxy for the historical prevalence of slavery in the municipality and thus to capture the long-run effects of slavery. Though the correlation with secular growth is negative in this case, the coefficients of this variable in the specified model were not significant.

A final interesting question to be posed is how persistent were the effects of railroads stations and foreign-born population in 1920 on the growth of Brazilian municipalities. To analyze this question we estimate the same conditional growth convergence model for each of the subperiods 1919–1950, 1950–1980, and 1980–2000, that is, using the same specification except by the year of the lagged dependent variable. Figure 3a, b summarizes the values (and standard deviation) of the coefficients estimated for B-convergence, the station railroad dummy, and the foreign-born population in 1920 for each activity and subperiod. The capped vertical lines show the two standard deviation confidence interval of the estimates of β, and the figures in parenthesis in the horizontal axis refer to the number of observation for each estimation period.Footnote 8

Fig. 3
figure 3

Persistence in time of the effects of railroad stations in 1920 and the share of foreign-born population in 1920. (a) Impact of railroad stations in 1920 in the growth of income per capita (GDP/POP) and labor productivity (GDP/LF) in selected activities and periods (changing only the year of lagged dependence variable for each period; lines show 1 std-error). (b) Elasticity of foreign-born population in 1920 in the growth of income per capita (GDP/POP) and labor productivity (GDP/LF) in selected activities and periods (changing only the year of lagged dependence variable for each period; lines show 1 std-error)

Figure 3a shows that the effects of 1920 railroad station dummies on growth of municipalities were significant and persistent in the case of labor productivity in industrial and, to a lesser extent, in urban activities. They were practically nonsignificant for income per capita and total productivity and productivity in urban activities. Figure 3b shows that the share of foreign-born population had significant pervasive effects from 1919 to 1949 but the lasting effects were restricted to the rural activities.

6 Conclusions and Extensions

The basic hypothesis of this chapter is the overwhelming role played by the geographic factors, especially transport costs, in the historical generation and reproduction of spatial inequalities in Brazil. Empirical evidence is presented by the analysis of the spatial patterns of growth of labor productivity and income per capita of the Brazilian municipalities from 1872 to 2000.

The main result of the analysis is that spatial inequalities in the density of economic activity, income per capita, and labor productivity remained practically unchanged with negligible reductions from 1872 to 2000. The maps show clearly the secular persistent northwest-southeast divide of income per capita and productivity of the country.

Econometric estimations of models of growth convergence provide a more rigorous test of the hypotheses. Estimation reported shows that the speed of convergence of both income per capita and labor productivity was very slow compared to other countries. Disaggregation of the analysis by subperiods, regions, and sectors shows that phases of export-led growth were more dispersive than the import substitution phases; convergence was faster inside each region and thus regional disparities reinforced spatial inequalities in the country as a whole; and convergence of labor productivity was faster in urban activities than in rural activities.

More notably, estimated parameters show that conditions of access to infrastructure in 1920—as proxied by the existence of railway station in the municipality—were by far the most important factor conditioning the growth of Brazilian municipalities during the twentieth century. Other variables related to accessibility like the distance to the state capitals and the market potential of the municipality also played roles in the long-run growth of municipalities. This strong result corroborates the perception that Brazilian development strategies during the second half of twentieth century had misguidedly disregarded investment in transport infrastructure, particularly in railways, which as a consequence remains as a crucial hindrance to steady growth.

In contrast, institutional factors—as proxied by slavery (in 1872), education and human capital, political participation, and landownership concentration—did not play a significant role in long-run growth of income per capita or labor productivity of Brazilian municipalities. Even when jointly tested, their coefficients remained insignificant. The exception is the cultural and institutional innovations brought with the European immigrants as evinced by the share of foreign-born population in 1920 which shows a significant and positive effect on the secular rates of growth of both labor productivity and income per capita, specially in the agricultural activities.

Needless to say, the results are still preliminary and further extensions and scrutiny are required. A research priority, in this way, is the need of a more rigorous econometric treatment of the problems of endogeneity which affects the estimation of the coefficients of railroad station, foreign-born population, and slavery, among other variables.

A related priority is to undertake a panel data analysis including the inter-census periods from 1872 to 2010, thus allowing to circumvent some of the econometric problems and, consequently, to estimate in more rigorous way the interplay between factors conditioning the growth of Brazilian municipalities in the diverse development phases, in particular to update the analyses for the period 2000–2010 to disentangle the role played by spatial inequalities in the recent redistributive process (Rodrigues-Silveira 2012; Hoffman 2013).

In this way the tasks ahead are to complete the historical database on the conditioning factors—in particular on demographic aspects related to migration and dependency ratio; urban and transportation infrastructure; education and human capital; political participation, etc.—for the periods from 1872 to 2010.