Skip to main content

The Role of Government

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
What Is Health Insurance (Good) For?
  • 989 Accesses

Abstract

Chapter 7 examines the role of group purchasing as a form of health insurance policy. This chapter describes the role of government in terms of health insurance policy. The chapter begins with a description of the goal of government, which is to move the health insurance system to providing optimal health insurance arrangements. A beneficent “social planner” could, in theory, implement a set of prices that would maximize the utility of health insurance to society. However, many of the implied policy solutions may be infeasible. As a result, health insurance policy is concerned with “second best” policies that optimize health insurance subject to constraints facing policymakers and markets. These policies can improve health insurance by addressing market failures in the health insurance market. Policymakers have a number of policy and regulatory tools that they can use to improve health insurance. Ultimately, any health insurance policy implemented by the government relies on the benefits of scale and scope if it is to make society better off. The trade-off for any governmental intervention are the costs arising from crowd out and deadweight loss. That trade-off leads to a consideration of universal group coverage and, in particular, full group coverage provided by the government. These are two types of single payer approaches to health insurance, which is an approach with both benefits and costs. As a result, policymakers may want to consider the wider menu of health insurance policy options that fall short of a single payer approach. Finally, this chapter assesses the meaning of public health insurance. How does the federal government operate as a group purchaser? How can group insurance for large populations account for diversity and heterogeneity in preferences and the variation in prices paid by different individuals within a public system? The answers to these questions imply an ongoing role for the private sector in any governmental approach to health insurance. That conclusion also provides a segue to Chap. 9, which considers the broader range of public policy choices with respect to health insurance in the United States.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    It is also possible that a floor does not cause any shift in the supply curve, and simply “cuts off” the lowest quantity insurance plans. In that case, line 3 would be identical to line 1, with the exception that it would simply start well above the quantity zero, and plans with small quantities (α close to 1) and small prices would not be part of the supply curve. It is also possible that health insurers could “capture” health insurance subsidies rather than passing them on to consumers in the form of higher quantities of insurance. In that case, line 2 would be closer to, or coincident with, line 1, and the supply of health insurance would not shift to the right as much to as great an extent (or, it might not shift to the right at all).

  2. 2.

    The Rothschild-Stiglitz model could be considered an early example of a “revelation mechanism ” that induces individuals to reveal the truth about themselves. For more on the economics of mechanisms and mechanism design, see Borgers et al. (2015).

  3. 3.

    The right policies could also grow the economy, but the short run conservative assumption is that regulation will reallocate financial wealth rather than increase it.

  4. 4.

    Note that a private monopolist would keep the amount it earned as profits. A public monopolist could choose to use the amount earned to fund other programs, but would still be reducing consumer welfare through the lower total quantity of health insurance it would provide.

  5. 5.

    The ACA has made guaranteed renewable health insurance much less valuable and less useful through the elimination of medical underwriting.

  6. 6.

    CMS is a large employer of actuaries. The role of the Office of the Actuary (OACT) “Performs actuarial, economic and demographic studies to estimate CMS program expenditures under current law and under proposed modifications to current law” (Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services 2015). However, CMS actuaries are not responsible for ensuring that premiums are equal to payments under these plans.

  7. 7.

    Fragmented systems have almost the opposite problem—there are so many different types of plans and premium levels that trying to compare across plans is difficult or impossible (an “apples versus oranges” comparison).

  8. 8.

    It is important to note that “high-risk pools ” are not necessarily risky in the economic sense. Risk refers to a range of possible contingencies with different possibilities. Many of the individuals enrolled in high-risk pools have high costs that are quite certain. It would be more accurate to term these as “high cost” pools.

References

  • Anderson, G. F., Reinhardt, U. E., Hussey, P. S., & Petrosyan, V. (2003). It’s the prices, stupid: Why the United States is so different from other countries. Health Affairs, 22(3), 89–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagley, N., & Levy, H. (2014). Essential health benefits and the affordable care act: Law and process. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 39(2), 441–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baicker, K., Congdon, W. J., & Mullainathan, S. (2012). Health insurance coverage and take-up: Lessons from behavioral economics. Milbank Quarterly, 90(1), 107–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baicker, K., & Levy, H. (2008). Employer health insurance mandates and the risk of unemployment. Risk Management and Insurance Review, 11(1), 109–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barros, P. P. (2003). Cream-skimming, incentives for efficiency and payment system. Journal of Health Economics, 22(3), 419–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bias, T. K., Agarwal, P., & Fitzgerald, P. (2015). Changing awareness of the health insurance marketplace. American Journal of Public Health, 105(S5), S633–S636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bluhm, W. F. (2007). Individual health insurance. Winsted, CT: ACTEX Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borch, K. (1962). Equilibrium in a reinsurance market. Econometrica, 30(3), 424–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borgers, T., Strausz, R., & Krahmer, D. (2015). An introduction to the theory of mechanism design. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Buchmueller, T., & DiNardo, J. (2002). Did community rating induce an adverse selection death spiral? evidence from New York, Pennsylvania, and Connecticut. The American Economic Review, 92(1), 280–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Catlin, M. K., Poisal, J. A., & Cowan, C. A. (2015). Out-of-pocket health care expenditures, by insurance status, 2007–10. Health Affairs, 34(1), 111–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cawley, J., Moriya, A. S., & Simon, K. (2015). The impact of the macroeconomy on health insurance coverage: Evidence from the great recession. Health Economics, 24(2), 206–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. (2012). Reinsurance, risk corridors, and risk adjustment final rule. Retrieved from https://www.cms.gov/CCIIO/Resources/Files/Downloads/3rs-final-rule.pdf

  • Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. (2015). Office of the actuary. Retrieved from https://www.cms.gov/About-CMS/Agency-Information/CMSLeadership/Office_OACT.html

  • Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. (2016a). Information on essential health benefits (EHB) benchmark plans. Retrieved from https://www.cms.gov/cciio/resources/data-resources/ehb.html

  • Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. (2016b). National health expenditure data. Retrieved from https://www.cms.gov/Research-Statistics-Data-and-Systems/Statistics-Trends-and-Reports/NationalHealthExpendData/

  • Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. (2016c). Overview of the SHOP marketplace. Retrieved from https://www.healthcare.gov/small-businesses/provide-shop-coverage/

  • Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. (2016d). Benefits. Retrieved from https://www.medicaid.gov/medicaid-chip-program-information/by-topics/benefits/medicaid-benefits.html

  • Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services. (2016e). Eligibility. Retrieved from http://medicaid.gov/affordablecareact/provisions/eligibility.html

  • Chiappori, P., & Salanie, B. (2000). Testing for asymmetric information in insurance markets. The Journal of Political Economy, 108(1), 56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chollet, D. (2002). Expanding individual health insurance coverage: Are high-risk pools the answer? Health Affairs, 23(Web exclusive), W349-52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cleverley, W., Song, P., & Cleverley, J. (2010). Essentials of health care finance. Burlington, MA: Jones & Bartlett Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J. H. (1995). Time-consistent health insurance. The Journal of Political Economy, 103(3), 445–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J. H. (2009). Health-status insurance: How markets can provide health security. (No. 633). Washington, D.C.: Cato Institute. Retrieved from http://www.cato.org/publications/policy-analysis/healthstatus-insurance-how-markets-can-provide-health-security

  • Commission, Medicare Payment Advisory. (2010). Report to the Congress: Medicare payment policy. MedPAC: Washington D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D. M., Finkelstein, A., & McGarry, K. (2008). Preference heterogeneity and insurance markets: Explaining a puzzle of insurance. The American Economic Review, 98(2), 157–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D. M., & Gruber, J. (1996). Does public insurance crowd out private insurance?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(2), 391–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D. M., & Ly, D. P. (2011). The (paper)work of medicine: Understanding international medical costs. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(2), 3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D. M., & Reber, S. J. (1998). Paying for health insurance: The trade-off between competition and adverse selection. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2), 433–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dafny, L., Gruber, J., & Ody, C. (2015). More insurers lower premiums: Evidence from initial pricing in the health insurance marketplaces. American Journal of Health Economics, 1(1), 53–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duggan, M., & Hayford, T. (2013). Has the shift to managed care reduced Medicaid expenditures? evidence from state and local-level mandates. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 32(3), 505–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elias, M., Martin, W., Robin, O., & Chloe, A. (2014). International profiles of health care systems, 2014. New York: The Commonwealth Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ettner, S. L. (1997). Adverse selection and the purchase of Medigap insurance by the elderly. Journal of Health Economics, 16(5), 543–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. (1999). Tax avoidance and the deadweight loss of the income tax. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), 674–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Field, R. I. (2013). Mother of invention: How the government created “free-market” health care. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, A., Hendren, N., & Luttmer, E. F. (2015). The value of Medicaid: Interpreting results from the Oregon health insurance experiment.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folland, S., Goodman, A. C., & Stano, M. (2013). The economics of health and health care (7th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furman, J., & Fiedler, M. (2016). The Cadillac Tax—A crucial tool for delivery-system reform. New England Journal of Medicine, 374(11), 1008–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glied, S. (2009). Single payer as a financing mechanism. Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 34(4), 593–615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldfarb, Z. A., & Somashekhar, S. (2013, July 2). White house delays health-care rule that businesses provide insurance to workers. Washington Post.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. (1997). Health insurance for poor women and children in the U.S.: Lessons from the past decade. In J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Tax policy and the economy, volume 11 (pp. 169–211). Cambridge, MA: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grunow, M., & Nuscheler, R. (2014). Public and private health insurance in Germany: The ignored risk selection problem. Health Economics, 23(6), 670–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, M. A. (2012). Regulating stop-loss coverage may be needed to deter self-insuring small employers from undermining market reforms. Health Affairs, 31(2), 316–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, S. E. (2010). US health-care reform: The Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 77(3), 703–708.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herring, B., & Lentz, L. K. (2011). What can we expect from the “Cadillac tax” in 2018 and beyond?. Inquiry, 48(4), 322–337.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herring, B., & Pauly, M. V. (2006). Incentive-compatible guaranteed renewable health insurance premiums. Journal of Health Economics, 25(3), 395–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, B. (2003). Health care reform and social movements in the United States. American Journal of Public Health, 93(1), 75–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, R. W. (1995). Insurance regulation in transition. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 62(3), 363–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kronick, R., & Gilmer, T. (2002). Insuring low-income adults: Does public coverage crowd out private? Health Affairs, 21(1), 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. B., & Reinhardt, U. E. (1994). The economics of employer versus individual mandates. Health Affairs, 13(2), 34–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laudicina, S. S. (1988). State health risk pools: Insuring the ‘uninsurable’. Health Affairs, 7(4), 97–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lynch, J. W., Kaplan, G. A., Pamuk, E. R., Cohen, R. D., Heck, K. E., Balfour, J. L., et al. (1998). Income inequality and mortality in metropolitan areas of the United States. American Journal of Public Health, 88(7), 1074–1080.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon, R. M., Cobbe, S. M., Bradley, J. M., & Grubb, N. R. (2004). Surviving out of hospital cardiac arrest at home: A postcode lottery? Emergency Medicine Journal, 21(5), 619–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madden, J. M., Adams, A. S., LeCates, R. F., Ross-Degnan, D., Zhang, F., Huskamp, H. A., et al. (2015). Changes in drug coverage generosity and untreated serious mental illness: Transitioning from Medicaid to Medicare Part D. JAMA Psychiatry, 72(2), 179–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., & Taylor, M. P. (2006). Microeconomics. London: Thompson Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning, W. G., & Marquis, M. S. (1996). Health insurance: The tradeoff between risk pooling and moral hazard. Journal of Health Economics, 15(5), 609–639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D., & Green, J. R. (1995). Microeconomic theory (1st ed.). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McMorrow, S., Kenney, G. M., Long, S. K., & Anderson, N. (2015). Uninsurance among young adults continues to decline, particularly in Medicaid expansion states. Health Affairs, 34(4), 616–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myles, G. D. (1995). Public economics. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nault, B. R. (1996). Equivalence of taxes and subsidies in the control of production externalities. Management Science, 42(3), 307–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumann, P. J. (2004). Using cost-effectiveness analysis to improve health care: Opportunities and barriers. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Newhouse, J. P., Price, M., Hsu, J., McWilliams, J. M., & McGuire, T. G. (2015). How much favorable selection is left in Medicare Advantage?. American Journal of Health Economics, 1(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oberlander, J. (2003). The political life of Medicare. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). (2013). Health at a glance 2013: OECD indicators. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parente, S. T., Feldman, R., Abraham, J., & Xu, Y. (2011). Consumer response to a national marketplace for individual health insurance. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 78(2), 389–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act. (2010). 42 U.S.C. § 18001 et seq.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V. (1968). The economics of moral hazard: Comment. The American Economic Review, 58(3), 531–537.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V., Danzon, P., Feldstein, P., & Hoff, J. (1991). A plan for ‘responsible national health insurance’. Health Affairs, 10(1), 5–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V., Kunreuther, H., & Hirth, R. (1995). Guaranteed renewability in insurance. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 10(2), 143–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V., Leive, A., & Harrington, S. E. (2015). (No. w21565). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w21565

  • Pauly, M. V., & Lieberthal, R. D. (2008). How risky is individual health insurance?. Health Affairs, 27(3), w242–w249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierson, P. (2000). Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics. American Political Science Review, 94(2), 251–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, M., & Stiglitz, J. (1976). Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: An essay on the economics of imperfect information. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90(4), 629–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selim, A. J., Fincke, B. G., Rogers, W. H., Qian, S., Selim, B. J., & Kazis, L. E. (2013). Guideline-recommended medications: Variation across Medicare Advantage plans and associated mortality. Journal of Managed Care Pharmacy, 19(2), 132–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1980). Equality of what?. The Tanner Lecture on Human Values, I, 197–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sloan, F. A., & Conover, C. J. (1998). Effects of state reforms on health insurance coverage of adults. Inquiry, 35(3), 280–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Starc, A. (2014). Insurer pricing and consumer welfare: Evidence from Medigap. The Rand Journal of Economics, 45(1), 198–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. (2012a). FAQ on ACOs: Accountable care organizations, explained. Retrieved from http://kff.org/health-reform/fact-sheet/health-insurance-market-reforms-guaranteed-issue/

  • The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. (2012b). A guide to the supreme Court’s decision on the ACA’s Medicaid expansion. Retrieved from http://kff.org/health-reform/issue-brief/a-guide-to-the-supreme-courts-decision/

  • The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. (2014). Explaining health care reform: Risk adjustment, reinsurance, and risk corridors. Retrieved from http://kff.org/health-reform/issue-brief/explaining-health-care-reform-risk-adjustment-reinsurance-and-risk-corridors/

  • The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. (2015). Employer health benefits: 2015 annual survey. Menlo Park, California: Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van de Ven, W. P. M. M. (2011). Risk adjustment and risk equalization: What needs to be done?. Health Economics, Policy and Law, 6(1), 147–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van de Ven, W. P. M. M., van Vliet, R. C., Schut, F. T., & van Barneveld, E. M. (2000). Access to coverage for high-risks in a competitive individual health insurance market: Via premium rate restrictions or risk-adjusted premium subsidies?. Journal of Health Economics, 19(3), 311–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, A. (1997). Intergenerational equity: An exploration of the ‘fair innings’ argument. Health Economics, 6(2), 117–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woolhandler, S., Campbell, T., & Himmelstein, D. U. (2003). Costs of health care administration in the United States and Canada. The New England Journal of Medicine, 349(8), 768–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert D. Lieberthal .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lieberthal, R.D. (2016). The Role of Government. In: What Is Health Insurance (Good) For?. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-43796-5_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics