Skip to main content

Probability and Life Contingencies, 1650–1750: The First One Hundred Years

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
A History of British Actuarial Thought
  • 602 Accesses

Abstract

Coming at the end of the Renaissance period and some 100 years after the Reformation, the mid-seventeenth century is generally regarded by historians as part of the early modern epoch. We should not, however, infer from this label that for Britain it was a time of stability in its political institutions or sophistication in its financial institutions. England spent the middle of the seventeenth century at war with the Netherlands, Scotland, Ireland and itself. The country recovered quickly from the tyranny of Cromwell’s Commonwealth; the arrival of King William III from the Netherlands in 1689 brought peace with the Netherlands but still more wars in Europe, this time with France. In the second half of the seventeenth century, England lagged behind some of northern Europe, and most notably the Netherlands, in the sophistication of its financial systems. King William imported Dutch practices in the raising of long-term government funding, and his costly wars had much use for them.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 89.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Hacking (1975) Chapter 1 for a survey of ancient probabilistic thinking and a discussion of what may have limited it.

  2. 2.

    A total of ten can be produced by six distinct combinations: 6, 3, 1; 6, 2, 2; 5, 3, 2; 5, 4, 1; 4, 4, 2; 4, 3, 3. A total of nine can be produced by the six distinct combinations: 6, 2, 1; 5, 3, 1; 5, 2, 2; 4, 4, 1; 4, 3, 2; 3, 3, 3.

  3. 3.

    Huygens (1657).

  4. 4.

    See, for example, Section 1.3, Daston (1988) for a scholarly discussion of the legal doctrine of equity and its influence on the development of mathematical expectation.

  5. 5.

    Chapter II, Todhunter (1865).

  6. 6.

    Cox et al. (1979).

  7. 7.

    Francis (1853).

  8. 8.

    Infants that have not yet been christened.

  9. 9.

    The mortality rates implied by Graunt’s survival table increase after age 56, but this arises due to rounding of the number of remaining survivors from a pool that begins with the arbitrary total of 100 (‘for men do not die in exact proportions nor in fractions’) rather than by explicit design.

  10. 10.

    Francis (1853), Chapter 1, p. 11, Hacking (1975), Chapter 12, p. 106.

  11. 11.

    See Homer and Sylla (1996), p. 112.

  12. 12.

    De Witt (1671).

  13. 13.

    1 − 28/30 = 6.7 %; and 1 − 126/128 = 1.6 %.

  14. 14.

    Halley (1693).

  15. 15.

    Hacking (1975), p. 113.

  16. 16.

    Price (1772), Essay IV.

  17. 17.

    Hacking (1975), Chapter 13, p. 111.

  18. 18.

    Ogborn (1953), Phillips in Discussion, p. 196.

  19. 19.

    Chapter IX, Homer and Sylla (1996).

  20. 20.

    Homer and Sylla (1996) p. 127.

  21. 21.

    Francis (1853), Chapter 3, p. 55.

  22. 22.

    Leeson (1968), p. 1.

  23. 23.

    Leeson (1968), p. 1.

  24. 24.

    Daston (1988), p. 139.

  25. 25.

    Chapter IV, Walford (1868).

  26. 26.

    Francis (1853), p. 59.

  27. 27.

    For example, see Daston (1988) Section 3.4, Hacking (1975), p. 113.

  28. 28.

    Price (1772), p. 105.

  29. 29.

    Stigler (1986).

  30. 30.

    Todhunter (1865).

  31. 31.

    De Moivre (1718).

  32. 32.

    De Moivre (1724).

  33. 33.

    Stigler (1986), p. 84.

  34. 34.

    De Moivre (1724).

  35. 35.

    Chapter IX, Francis (1853).

  36. 36.

    Part A of Supple (1970) provides an excellent account of the establishment and early growth of Royal Exchange Assurance.

  37. 37.

    See, for example, Section 3.4.2, Daston (1988).

  38. 38.

    Bernoulli (1738).

  39. 39.

    De Morgan (1838), Chapter V, p. 101.

  40. 40.

    Samuelson (1960).

References

  • Bernoulli, Daniel (1738), ‘Specimen theoriae novae de mensura sortis’, Commentarii academiae scientarum imperialis Petropolitanae 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J.C., S.A. Ross and M. Rubinstein (1979), ‘Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach’, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 7, No. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daston, Lorraine (1988), Classical Probability in the Enlightenment. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Moivre, Abraham (1718), Doctrine of Chances.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Moivre, Abraham (1724), Annuities on Lives.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Morgan, Augustus (1838), An Essay on Probabilities and On Their Applications to Life Contingencies and Insurance Offices. Longman, Orme, Brown, Green & Longmans.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Wittt, Johan (1671), ‘In A Series of Letters to the States-General’, In R.G. Barnwell and F. Hendricks, A Sketch of the Life and Times of John De Witt, Grand Pensionary of Holland. New York, 1856.

    Google Scholar 

  • Francis, John (1853), Annals, Anecdotes and Legends; A Chronicle of Life Assurance. Longman, Brown, Green & Longmans.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hacking, Ian (1975), The Emergence of Probability. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halley, Edmond (1693), An Estimate of the Degrees of the Mortality of Mankind, drawn from curious Tables of the Births and Funerals at the City of Breslau, with an Attempt to ascertain the Price of Annuities upon Lives.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homer, Sidney and Richard Sylla (1996), A History of Interest Rates, Third Edition Revised. Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huygens, C. (1657), Ratiociniis in aleae ludo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, Francis (1968), A Guide to the Records of the British State Tontines and Life Annuities of the 17th and 18th Centuries. Pinhorns.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogborn, M.E. (1953), ‘On the Nature of the Function Expressive of the Law of Human Mortality’. Journal of the Institute of Actuaries, Vol. 79, pp. 170–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Price, Richard (1772), Observations on Reversionary Payments; on Schemes for Providing Annuities for Widows, and for Persons in Old Age; To Which Are Added Four Essays. T. Cadfll.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1960), ‘The St. Petersburg Paradox as a Divergent Double Limit’. International Economic Review, Vol. 1, No. 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, Stephen M. (1986), The History of Statistics. Belknap Harvard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Supple, Barry (1970), The Royal Exchange Assurance: A History of British Insurance 1720–1970. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Todhunter, Isaac (1865), History of the Mathematical Theory of Probability From the Time of Pascal to That of Laplace. London and Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walford, Cornelius (1868), The Insurance Guide and Hand-Book. Charles and Edwin Layton.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Turnbull, C. (2017). Probability and Life Contingencies, 1650–1750: The First One Hundred Years. In: A History of British Actuarial Thought. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-33183-6_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-33183-6_1

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-33182-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-33183-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics