Skip to main content

Evaluation of Redistributive and Welfare Impacts of Indirect Taxes Reform in Rwanda

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Poverty and Well-Being in East Africa

Abstract

This study evaluates the redistributive and welfare effects of reforms in indirect taxes in Rwanda. Specifically, its aim is to determine the effects of the 2002 reforms of the value added tax (VAT) rate on aggregate household welfare; assessing the impact of this reform on welfare distribution among Rwandan households; and evaluating the redistributive potential of differentiated indirect taxes in the country. A methodology based on two complementary approaches was used: a framework of the distributional characteristic of goods (Newberry 1995) and the framework of the marginal tax reforms (Ahmad and Stern 1984). Data used are from the second Integrated Survey on the Living Standards of Rwandan Households (EICV2) conducted by the government’s statistics office in 2005–06. The results show that: (1) the 2002 increase in the VAT rate slightly decreased aggregate household welfare; (2) the reforms further affected the welfare of households in the first three quintiles because they consumed relatively more of taxable necessities; and (3) differentiated indirect taxes could improve Rwandan household welfare without compromising on tax revenues.

This study borrows mainly from Ndemezo (2015a, b).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Measured in household expenditure, the inequality was valued around 0.5 of the Gini Index from 2000 to 2011. About 60 and 57 % Rwandans were considered poor respectively in 2000–01 and in 2005–06.

  2. 2.

    See details about the derivation of the change in indirect tax revenue with respect to the indirect tax rate in the Appendix.

  3. 3.

    The micro-simulation procedure was done using the following formula:\( E_{i1} = E_{i0} \left\{ {\left. {1 + \left[ {{{\left( {\pi_{i1} - \pi_{i0} } \right)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left( {\pi_{i1} - \pi_{i0} } \right)} {\left( {1 + \pi_{i0} } \right)}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\left( {1 + \pi_{i0} } \right)}}} \right]\zeta_{ii}^{c} } \right\}} \right.\) where E i0 and E i1 are expenditures on good i before and after the indirect tax reform. Variables \(\pi_{i0} {\text{and}} \pi_{i1}\) represent the implicit tax rate on good i before and after the tax reform respectively; whereas \(\zeta_{ii}^{c} \) is the elasticity of expenditure on good i with respect to the price of good i.

  4. 4.

    The implicit tax rate is computed referring to the effect of combined indirect taxes (VAT and excise) on final prices: \( q = \left( {1 + \upsilon } \right)\left( {1 + \tau } \right)p \) where \( q \) is the final price tax-included and \( p \) is the final price tax-excluded, \( \upsilon \) is the VAT rate and \( \tau \) the excise duty rate. Consequently, the implicit tax rate can be calculated as: \( 1 + \pi = \left( {1 + \upsilon } \right)\left( {1 + \tau } \right) \) or \( \pi = \upsilon + \tau + \tau \upsilon \) where all variables are defined as previously.

  5. 5.

    Goods consumed relatively more by poor people.

  6. 6.

    See parameters of demand for goods in the Appendix.

  7. 7.

    Agricultural foods occupy roughly 19 % of ultra-poor consumption, while the national average is 4 % of all households’ expenditure.

  8. 8.

    Public transportation and education represent 8 and 11 % of the fourth quintile consumption respectively; the national average is 8 and 16 % respectively.

References

  • Ahmad, E., and N. Stern. 1984. The theory of reform and Indian indirect taxes. Journal of Public Economics 2: 259–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alm, J., E. Sennoga, and M. Skidmore. 2005. Perfect competition, spatial competition, and tax incidence in the retail gasoline market. Working Paper No. 06-01. Georgia State University: Andrew Young School of Policy Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ardic, O.P., B. Erus, and G. Soydan. 2010. An evaluation of indirect taxes in Turkey. Economic Bulletin 30(4): 2787–2801.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, B.A. 1970. On the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 2: 244–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A.B., and J.E. Stiglitz. 1976. The design of tax structure: Direct versus indirect taxation. Journal of Public Economics 6: 55–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J., R. Blundell, and A. Lewbel. 1996. Tax reform and welfare measurement: Do we need demand system estimation? The Economic Journal 106(438): 1227–1241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergson, A. 1938. A reformulation of certain aspects of welfare economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 52(2): 310–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R.M., and E.M. Zolt. 2005. Redistribution via taxation: The limited role of the personal income tax in developing countries. UCLA Law Review 52(6): 1627–1695.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., and P. Pestieau. 2002. Indirect taxation and redistribution: The scope of the Atkinson-Stiglitz Theorem. Working Paper No. 1005. Queen’s Economics Department (QED).

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., and P. Pestieau. 2011. Indirect taxes for redistribution: Should necessity goods be favored? Discussion Paper No. 2011/66. CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bodier, M., and D. Cogneau. 1996. L’évolution de la structure des prix et les inégalités de Niveau de vie en France de 1974 à 1995l. Document de Travail no 1996-12/T. DIAL, Université Paris-Dauphine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Correia, I. 2010. Consumption taxes and redistribution. The American Economic Review 100(4):1673–1694.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, I., Z. Smith, and S. Tanner. 1999. Alcohol taxes, tax revenues and the single European Market. Fiscal Studies 20(3): 287–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J. 2000. Measuring welfare changes and the excess burden of taxation. Bulletin of Economic Research 52(1): 1–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J. 2001. Indirect tax reform and the role of exemptions. Fiscal Studies 22(4): 457–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., and C. Sleeman. 2006. Indirect taxation and progressivity: Revenue and welfare changes. FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis 62(1): 50–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, H., P. Pestieau, and J.-C. Rochet. 2001. Direct versus indirect taxation: The design of the tax structure revisited. International Economic Review 42(3): 781–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entin, S.J. 2004. Tax incidence, tax burden, and tax shifting: Who really pays the tax? CDA Report. The Heritage Center for Data Analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. 1972. Distributional equity and the optimal structure of public prices. The American Economic Review 62(1/2): 32–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frisch, R. 1959. A complete scheme for computing all direct and cross demand elasticities in a model with many sectors. Econometrica 27(2): 177–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gemmell, N., and O. Morrissey. 2003. Tax structure and the incidence on the poor in developing countries. Research Paper No. 03/18. CREDIT, University of Nottingham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guénard, C. 1998. Evolution de la structure des prix et impact sur les inégalités de niveau de vie à Antananarivo de 1990 à 1997. Document de Travail no DT/98/05. IEDP/DIAL, Université Paris Sud/Université de Paris-Dauphine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L. 2006. On the undesirability of commodity taxation even when income taxation is not optimal. Journal of Public Economics 90: 1235–1250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, M.A. 1983. Welfare analysis of tax reforms using household data. Journal of Public Economics 21(2): 183–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leyaro, V., O. Morrissey, and T. Owens. 2010. Food price changes and consumer welfare in Tanzania 1991–2007. Research Paper No. 10/01. University of Nottingham: CREDIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liberati, P. 2001. The distributional effects of indirect tax changes in Italy. International Tax and Public Finance 8(1): 27–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughrey, J., and C. O’Donoghue. 2012. The welfare impact of price changes on household welfare and inequality 1999–2011. The Economic and Social Review 43(1): 31–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Majumder, A. 2002. On the distributional effect of commodity tax reform. Journal of Economic Research 7: 105–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayshar, J., and S. Yitzhaki. 1995. Dalton-improving indirect tax reform. The American Economic Review 85(4): 793–807.

    Google Scholar 

  • MINECOFIN. 2002. Integrated Household Living Conditions Survey in Rwanda (2000–2001). Final Report. Kigali, September.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minot, N.W. 1992. Distributional effects of currency devaluation on households in Rwanda: An application of willingness-to-pay welfare measures. Ph.D. Dissertation, Michigan State University, Michigan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minot, N.W. 1998. Distributional and nutritional impact of devaluation in Rwanda. Economic Development and Cultural Change 46(2): 379–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munoz, S., and S.S.-W. Cho. 2003. Social impact of a tax reform: The case of Ethiopia. IMF Working Paper No. 03/232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ndemezo, E. 2015a. Assessing the perspective for indirect taxes reform in Rwanda. Conference Paper No. CSAE2015-227, presented at the CSAE Annual Conference 2015 on ‘Economic Development in Africa’, Centre for the Study of African Economies, University of Oxford, 22–24 March 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ndemezo, E. 2015b. Impact of the 2002’s VAT rate reform on household welfare in Rwanda. Conference Paper No. P05, presented at the first Annual Eastern Africa Business and Economics Watch International Conference on ‘Recent Trends in Economic Development, Finance and Management Research in Eastern Africa’, University of Rwanda and Jönköping University, Kigali, 5–6 May 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newbery, D.M. 1995. The distributional impact of price changes in Hungary and the United Kingdom. The Economic Journal 105(431): 847–863.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nygård, O.E. 2008. Optimal indirect taxation: A review of theoretical and empirical results. Working Paper No. 2008/19, Statistics Norway.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. 1991. A theory of justice. Cambridge: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Refaqat, S. 2005. Redistributive impact of GST tax reform: Pakistan, 1990–2001. The Pakistan Development Review 44(4 Part II):841–862.

    Google Scholar 

  • RRA. 2010. Annual Activity Report for 2008–2009. Kigali, September.

    Google Scholar 

  • RRA. 2012. Annual Activity Report for 2011–2012. Kigali, October.

    Google Scholar 

  • RRA. 2013. Annual Activity Report for 2012–2013. Kigali, November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E. 2004. Direct or indirect tax instruments for redistribution: short-run versus long-run. Journal of Public Economics 88: 503–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. 1949. Foundation of economic analysis. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, Harvard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Son, H.H., and N. Kakwani. 2006a. Measuring the impact of price changes on poverty. Working Paper No. 33, International Poverty Centre, UNDP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Son, H.H., and N. Kakwani. 2006b. Measuring the impact of prices on inequality with applications to Thailand and Korea. Journal of Economic Inequality 4(2):181–207.

    Google Scholar 

  • Urzúa, C.M. 2001. Welfare consequences of a recent tax reform in Mexico. Estudios Económicos 16(31): 57–72.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Etienne Ndemezo .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 3.

Table 3 Parameters of demand for goods and services (LES model)

Appendix 2

See Table 4.

Table 4 Details of commodity groups

Appendix 3

3.1 Changes in Indirect Tax Revenue with Respect to Indirect Tax Rate

We define the taxable household expenditure on commodity i as:

$$ E_{tti}^{m} = E_{tti}^{m} (q_{i} ,I_{m} ) $$
(10)

with \( E_{tti}^{m} \) meaning spending tax-included of household m on good i; \( q_{i} \) refers to the price tax-included on good i and \( I_{m} \) is household m income. We consider that only consumption expenditure is taxable and that the income is not taxed.

Taxable expenditure depends on the prices of goods and on household income. We assume that a change in the tax rate has no effect on household income. Therefore, the change in the implicit tax rate fully passes through the market price.

$$ {\text{d}}q_{i} = p_{i} {\text{d}}\pi_{i} $$

where \( p_{i} \) is the price tax-excluded; \( {\text{d}}q_{i} \) and \( {\text{d}}\pi_{i} \) are changes in the price tax-included and change in the implicit tax rate on the good i, respectively.

For household m, following the change in the tax rate, the change in consumption expenditure depends on the induced change in the vector of prices and in real income. After some manipulations, the change in expenditure can be described as:

$$ \frac{{{\text{d}}E_{tti}^{m} }}{{E_{tti}^{m} }} = \left[ {\left( {1 + \varepsilon_{ii}^{u} } \right)\frac{{{\text{d}}\pi_{i} }}{{1 + \pi_{i} }} + \sum\limits_{i \ne j} {\varepsilon_{ij}^{u} \frac{{{\text{d}}\pi_{j} }}{{1 + \pi_{j} }}} } \right] + \eta_{i} \frac{{{\text{d}}I_{m} }}{{I_{m} }} $$
(11)

with \( \varepsilon_{ii}^{u} \), \( \varepsilon_{ij}^{u} \), \( \eta_{i} \) designating, respectively the own price-elasticity of demand for good i, the cross price-elasticity of demand for good i with respect to the price of good j and the expenditure elasticity of demand for good i; variables \( \pi_{i} \) set \( {\text{d}}\pi_{i} \) represent the implicit tax rate on good i and its change, respectively.

Equation 11 can also be rewritten as:

$$ \frac{{{\text{d}}E_{tti} }}{{E_{tti} }} = \zeta_{ii}^{u} \frac{{{\text{d}}\pi_{i} }}{{1 + \pi_{i} }} + \eta_{i} \frac{{{\text{d}}I_{m} }}{{I_{m} }} $$
(12)

where the parameter \( \zeta_{ii}^{u} = 1 + \varepsilon_{ii}^{u} + \sum\nolimits_{i \ne j} {\varepsilon_{ji}^{u} } \) is the uncompensated price-elasticity of expenditure on good i, \( \varepsilon_{ii}^{u} \) is the uncompensated own price-elasticity of demand for good i, \( \varepsilon_{ji}^{u} \) represents the uncompensated cross price-elasticity of demand for good j with respect to the price of good i; other variables being defined as earlier.

Behavioral change in revenue is derived from Eq. 12, through Roy’s identity (\( {{{\text{d}}I_{m} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}I_{m} } {I_{m} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {I_{m} }} = {{w_{i}^{m} {\text{d}}q_{i} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{w_{i}^{m} {\text{d}}q_{i} } {q_{i} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {q_{i} }} \)).

$$ \Delta B_{i} = \frac{{E_{tti} }}{{1 + \pi_{i} }}\pi_{i} \left( {\zeta_{ii}^{u} + w_{i} \eta_{i} } \right)\Delta \pi_{i} $$
(13)

where \( \Delta B_{i} \) is the behavioral change in indirect tax revenue, \( E_{tti} \) is the total expenditure tax-included on good i before the tax reforms, \( \zeta_{ii}^{u} \) is the uncompensated price-elasticity of expenditure on good i, \( \pi_{i} \) and \( \Delta \pi_{i} \) are the implicit tax rate on good i in pre-reform period and its post-reform variation, respectively.

The mechanical change in tax revenue is given by the following expression:

$$ \Delta M_{i} = \frac{{E_{tti} }}{{1 + \pi_{i} }}\Delta \pi_{i} $$
(14)

with \( \Delta M_{i} \) referring to the mechanical change in tax revenues; other variables being defined as earlier.

The total tax revenue growth is the sum of all extra revenue from mechanical growth and those from behavioral growth. Using the Slutsky equation (\( \zeta_{ii}^{u} = \zeta_{ii}^{c} - w_{i} \eta_{i} \)), the change in indirect tax revenue may be written as:

$$ \frac{{\Delta R_{i} }}{{\Delta \pi_{i} }} = \frac{{E_{tti} }}{{1 + \pi_{i} }}\left( {1 + \zeta_{ii}^{c} \pi_{i} } \right) $$
(15)

where \( \Delta R_{i} \) is the total change in tax revenue from the consumption of good i; \( \pi_{i} \) and \( \Delta \pi_{i} \) are the implicit tax rate on good i (before reform) and its post-reform change; \( \zeta_{ii}^{c} \) is the compensated price-elasticity of expenditure on good i; \( E_{tti} \) is the aggregate expenditure tax-included allocated to the purchase of good i (before the tax reform). Other variables are defined as previously.

It should be noted that 15 has similarities with Eq. 6 in Crawford et al. (1999: 293), with a slight difference about the parameters used. Crawford et al. (1999) use the uncompensated price-elasticity of expenditure; they ignore the income effect.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ndemezo, E., Baye, F.M. (2016). Evaluation of Redistributive and Welfare Impacts of Indirect Taxes Reform in Rwanda. In: Heshmati, A. (eds) Poverty and Well-Being in East Africa. Economic Studies in Inequality, Social Exclusion and Well-Being. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-30981-1_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics