Advertisement

Is Culture an Underpinning or Undermining Factor in the Business Environment of the Transitional Countries?

  • Ružica Šimić BanovićEmail author
Chapter

Abstract

The interplay of formal (laws, regulations) and informal institutions (culture, tradition, norms of behaviour) has showed to be initially underestimated in the recent economic, political, and social transformation of Central and Eastern European countries. This predominantly led to a uniform approach that undervalued intangible legacy and consequently could neither predict nor address the divergence of countries’ development and evolution of their business systems.

Dominant national culture has been recognized as a very influential factor of the institutional change. Considering that favourable business environment is vital for economic progress, “institutional stickiness” of business-related laws and regulations and culture is thoroughly researched. It is further linked with overall quality of the business environment and level of economic development. This article suggests that favourable business environment is expected to be found in societies characterised by weak power distance, high individualism, low uncertainty avoidance and indulgence instead of restraint. Yet, opposite characteristics are found in numerous transition countries. The findings also suggest lesser likelihood of successful institutional import from Western to Eastern European societies.

Keywords

Business Environment Cultural Dimension Power Distance Formal Institution Uncertainty Avoidance 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

References

  1. Aldashev, G. (2009). Legal institutions, political economy, and development. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 25(2), 257–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Aligicia, P. D. (2006). Learning in time: New institutionalism and the Central and Eastern European economic reform experience. Global Business and Economics Review, 8(1/2), 25–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Alston, L., Melo, M., Mueller, B., & Pereira, C. (2010). Power, beliefs and institutions: A conceptual framework. Paper presented in the lecture “Power, beliefs and institutions: Understanding development in the modern world”. Conference “The Legacy and Work of D. C. North: Understanding Institutions and Development Economics”. Center for New Institutional Social Sciences, Washington University, Saint Louis, MO, USA.Google Scholar
  4. Amable, B. (2009). The diversity of modern capitalism. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Aoki, M. (2011). Institutions as cognitive media between strategic interaction and individual beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 79(1–2), 20–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Arias, O. (2011). Culture matters: The real obstacles to Latin American development. Foreign Affairs, 90(1), 2–6.Google Scholar
  7. Berglof, E., Bruynoooghe, L., Harmgart, H., Sanfey, P., Schweiger, H., & Zettelmeyer, J. (2012). European transition at twenty: Assessing progress in countries and sectors. In G. Roland (Ed.). Economies in transition: The long-run view (pp. 254–292). United Nations University—World Institute for Development Economics Research. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
  8. Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. J. (2008). Institutional stickiness and the new development economics. The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67(2), 331–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Cvijanovic, V., & Redzepagic, D. (2011). From political capitalism to clientelist capitalism? The case of Croatia. Zbornik radova Ekonomskog fakulteta u Rijeci, 29(2), 355–372.Google Scholar
  10. Dixit, A. K. (2004). Lawlessness and economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  11. Dixit, A. K. (2009). Governance institutions and economic activity. American Economic Review, 99(1), 5–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Ramalho, R. M. (2006). Regulation and growth. Economics Letters, 92(3), 395–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Doing Business. (2012). Official website. Retrieved 10 February, 2012, from www.doingbusiness.org/span
  14. Easterly, W. (2008). Institutions: Top down or bottom up? American Economic Review, 98(2), 95–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Elster, J., Offe, C., & Preuss, U. (1998). Institutional design in post-communist societies: Rebuilding the ship at sea. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Ensminger, J. (1997). Changing property rights: Reconciling formal and informal rights to land in Africa. In J. N. Drobak & J. V. C. Nye (Eds.), The frontiers of the new institutional economics (pp. 165–196). San Diego, CA: Academic.Google Scholar
  17. Estrin, S. (2002). Competition and corporate governance in transition. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(1), 101–124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Feldmann, M. (2006). Emerging varieties of capitalism in transition countries: Industrial relations and wage bargaining in Estonia and Slovenia. Comparative Political Studies, 39(7), 829–854.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Gorodnichenko, Y., & Roland, G. (2010). Culture, institutions and the wealth of nations (NBER Working Paper No. 16368). Retrieved April 20, 2011, from http://www.nber.org/papers/w16368.pdf
  20. Gorodnichenko, Y., & Roland, G. (2011a). Which dimensions of culture matter for long-run growth? American Economic Review, 101(3), 492–498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Gorodnichenko, Y., & Roland, G. (2011b). Understanding the individualism-collectivism cleavage and its effects: Lessons from cultural psychology. Invited Paper at the XVIth Congress of the International Economic Association, Tsinghua University, Beijing, China.Google Scholar
  22. Greif, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies. Journal of Political Economy, 102(5), 912–950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 23–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hofstede, G. (2012). Official website—dimension data matrix. Retrieved February 23, 2012, from http://www.geerthofstede.nl/research--vsm/dimension-data-matrix.aspx
  25. Hofstede, G., Hofstede, G. J., & Minkov, M. (2010). Cultures and organizations: Software of the mind: Intercultural cooperation and its importance for survival (3rd ed.). New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
  26. IFC/WB. (2006–2011). Doing business reports. Doing Business official website. Retrieved February 10, 2012, from www.doingbusiness.org
  27. Jaklič, M., & Zagoršek, H. (2002). From strengths to weaknesses: Historical development of shadow economy in Slovenia and its impact on national competitiveness. In M. Cicic & N. Brkic (Eds.), Transition in Central and Eastern Europe—challenges of 21st century: Conference proceedings (pp. 301–308). Sarajevo: Faculty of Economics, University of Sarajevo.Google Scholar
  28. Jaklič, M., & Zagoršek, H. (2003). Rationality in transition: Using holistic approach to rationality to explain some developments in the Slovenian business system (Working Paper No. 146). Ljubljana: Faculty of Economics, University of Ljubljana.Google Scholar
  29. Jellema, J., & Roland, G. (2011). Institutional clusters and economic performance. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 79(1–2), 108–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. King, L. (2002). Postcommunist divergence: A comparative analysis of the transition to capitalism in Poland and Russia. Studies in Comparative International Development, 37(3), 3–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. King, L. (2007). Central European capitalism in comparative perspective. In R. Hanké, M. Thatcher, & M. Rhodes (Eds.), Beyond varieties of capitalism (pp. 307–327). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. King, L. (2010). The role of existing theories and the need for a theory of capitalism in Central Eastern Europe. Retrieved December 10, 2011, from http://www.emecon.eu/fileadmin/articles/1_2010/emecon%201_2010%20King.pdf
  33. Kornai, J. (2008). What does ‘change of system mean’? In J. Kornai (Ed.), From socialism to capitalism (pp. 123–150). Budapest: Central University Press.Google Scholar
  34. Lal, D. (1999). Culture, democracy and development: The impact of formal and informal institutions on development. International Monetary Fund Conference on Second Generation Reforms. IMF Headquarters, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  35. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). Trust in large organizations. American Economic Review, 87(2), 333–338.Google Scholar
  36. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanez, F., & Shleifer, A. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanez, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2), 285–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Mueller, K. (2010). How culture shapes the post-communist transformations. EMECON: Employment and Economy in Central and Eastern Europe, 1. Retrieved December 10, 2011, from http://www.emecon.eu/fileadmin/articles/1_2010/emecon%201_2010%20M%C3%BCller.pdf
  39. Murrell, P. (1991). Can neoclassical economics underpin the reform of centrally planned economies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(4), 59–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Nee, V. (2003). The new institutionalism in economics and sociology (CSES Working Paper Series No. 4). Ithaca, NY: Centre for the Study of Economy and Society, Cornell University.Google Scholar
  41. Neuber, A. (1993). Towards a political economy of transition in Eastern Europe. Journal of International Development, 5(5), 511–530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton, NY: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. North, D. C. (2008). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. New York, NY: New York University Press.Google Scholar
  44. Nye, J. (2008). Institutions and institutional environment. In E. Brousseau & J.-M. Glachant (Eds.), New institutional economics—A guidebook (pp. 67–80). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Pejovich, S. (2003). Understanding the transaction costs of transition: It’s the culture, stupid. Forum Series on the Role of Institutions in Promoting Economic Growth. Mercatus Center, George Mason University, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  46. Pejovich, S. (2003a). Understanding the transaction costs of transition: It’s the culture stupid (Forum series on the role of institutions in promoting economic growth). Washington, DC: Mercatus Center, George Mason University.Google Scholar
  47. Pejovich, S. (2003b). Tranzicija, tranzicijski troškovi i kultura [Transition, Transition Costs and Culture]. Financijska teorija i praksa, 27(2), 235–250.Google Scholar
  48. Pejovich, S. (2008). Law, informal rules and economic performance: The case for common law. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Rodrik, D. (2009). One economics, many recipes: Globalization, institutions, and economic growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  50. Roland, G. (2000). Transition and economics: Politics, markets, and firms. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  51. Roland, G. (2004). Understanding institutional change: Fast-moving and slow-moving institutions. Studies in Comparative International Development, 38(4), 109–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Roland, G. (2012). The long-run weight of communism or the weight of long-run history? In G. Roland (Ed.), Economies in transition: The long-run view (pp. 153–171). United Nations University—World Institute for Development Economics Research. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
  53. Skokic, V. (2010). Tourism entrepreneurship in transition economies: Unpacking the socio-economic contexts. Doctoral dissertation, University of Strathclyde, Glasgow.Google Scholar
  54. Tabellini, G. (2008). The scope of cooperation: Norms and incentives. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(3), 905–950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: Economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(4), 677–716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Teubner, G. (2001). Legal irritants: How unifying law ends up in new divergences. In P. A. Hall & D. Soskice (Eds.), Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative advantage (pp. 417–441). Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. The International Monetary Fund. (2012, April). World economic outlook database. Retrieved May 2, 2012, from http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/index.aspx
  58. Thomas, S. A., & Mueller, S. L. (2000). A case for comparative entrepreneurship: Assessing the relevance of culture. Journal of International Business Studies, 31(2), 287–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Whitley, R. (Ed.). (1997). European business systems: Firms and markets in their national contexts. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  60. Williamson, O. (2000). The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), 595–613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Williamson, C. (2009). Informal institutions rule: Institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice, 139(3), 371–387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. World Economic Forum. (2005). The global competitiveness report 2005–2006. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  63. World Economic Forum. (2006). The global competitiveness report 2006–2007. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  64. World Economic Forum. (2007). The global competitiveness report 2007–2008. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  65. World Economic Forum. (2008). The global competitiveness report 2008–2009. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  66. World Economic Forum. (2009). The global competitiveness report 2009–2010. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  67. World Economic Forum. (2010). The global competitiveness report 2010–2011. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  68. World Economic Forum. (2011). The global competitiveness report 2011–2012. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
  69. Zupanov, J. (2002). Od komunističkog pakla do divljeg kapitalizma [From communist hell to wild capitalism]. Zagreb: Hrvatska sveučilišna naklada.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Faculty of Law, Department of EconomicsUniversity of ZagrebZagrebCroatia

Personalised recommendations