Skip to main content

Economic Regulation of Energy Networks

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1729 Accesses

Part of the book series: Power Systems ((POWSYS))

Abstract

The growing attention for the environmental effects of using fossil energy calls for an evaluation of current regulatory regimes of energy networks. In the past, tariff regulation of energy networks was mainly meant to foster competition and to improve efficiency in order to achieve lower prices for energy users. Currently, it is generally believed that regulation also has to facilitate the process of decarbonisation. In order to deal, for instance, with the growing significance of distributed generation, distribution-network operators have to upgrade their networks. The key question now is whether the existing regulatory frameworks should be adapted in order to enable these types of developments. This chapter focuses on yardstick regulation, which is a form of tariff regulation in which the allowed revenues of network operators are based on the average costs of all operators. The chapter concludes that several mechanisms exist by which yardstick regulation fosters efficient investments directed at making the grids smarter. However, such a regulatory framework may also include mechanisms potentially hindering efficient investments. These negative effects of regulation on the development of smart grids occur if the regulated firms operate in different circumstances and when externalities exist. The chapter ends by presenting a number of options to deal with such regulatory shortcomings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    More formally, an energy network is a natural monopoly if the costs are sub additive, which means that the total costs of supplying all services needed in a market by one network are below the total costs of producing these services by more than one network.

  2. 2.

    This reduction in consumption is called the deadweight loss of a monopoly.

  3. 3.

    Note that ‘economic profits’ are the profits on top of the normal profits, while the latter are defined as the reward for the opportunity costs of capital. In tariff regulation, this reward is given by including a compensation for capital costs in the revenue formula. This compensation is based on the WACC (weighted costs of capital), which is weighted sum of the costs of debt and the required return on equity.

  4. 4.

    In economics, ‘rent’ is an alternative term for ‘economic profit’.

  5. 5.

    The maximum level of revenues is translated into tariffs for the different types of services a network supplies. Operators generally may vary with these tariffs but the sum of all tariffs times the expected volumes per type of service is not allowed to exceed the maximum level of revenues.

  6. 6.

    In this case, the share of the regulated firm in the yardstick is zero, implying that the incentive power is 1.

  7. 7.

    Note that if the group consist of just one firm, its market share is 1 and the incentive power is 1 − 1 = 0, which is equal to a cost-plus type of regulation.

  8. 8.

    Network operators provide a number of different services and, hence, they have a number of different outputs. In order to be able to calculate a productivity index, these outputs needs to be standardized. This standardization can be done by using, for instance, realised average tariffs for each output category.

  9. 9.

    The costs in this formula includes both capital costs (capex) and operational costs (opex), implying that the regulatory framework can be characterised as totex-regulation, i.e. the revenues are based on an estimate of the total costs.

  10. 10.

    SAIDI means ‘System Average Interruption Duration Index’ and is calculated as the ratio between the sum of duration of interruptions in power supply for all network users during a year over the total number of network users. Hence, this ratio measures the average duration (in minutes or hours) that network users cannot make use of the power grid in a year.

  11. 11.

    In particular the risk-free interest has declined significantly over the past years. This interest rate is a component of both the cost of debt and the required rate of return on equity.

References

  • Agrell, P.J., Bogetoft, P., Mikkers, M.: Smart-grid investments, regulation and organization. Energy Policy 52, 656–666 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ajodhia, V., Lo Schiavo, L., et al.: Quality regulation of electricity distribution in Italy: an evaluation study. Energy Policy 34, 1478–1486 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Averch, H., Johnson, L.: Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. Am. Econ. Rev. 52(5), 1052–1069 (1962)

    Google Scholar 

  • Burger, A., Geymueller, P.: Can We Measure Welfare? Dynamic Comparisons of Allocative Efficiency Before and After the Introduction of Quality Regulation for Norwegian Electricity Distributors. Vienna University of Economics and Business Administration (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Cambini, C., Rondi, L.: Incentive regulation and investment: evidence from European energy utilities. J. Regul. Econ. 38, 1–26 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colak, I., Fulli, G., Sagiroglu, S., Yesilbudak, M., Covrig, C.-F.: Smart grid projects in Europe: Current status, maturity and future scenarios. Appl. Energy 152, 58–70 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra, P., Haan, M., Mulder, M.: Design of yardstick competition and consumer prices: experimental evidence. SOM Research Reports, vol. 15004-EEF. University of Groningen, SOM research school, Groningen (2015)

    Google Scholar 

  • Granderson, G., Linvill, C.: Regulation, efficiency, and Granger causality. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 20(9), 1225–1245 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haffner, R., Helmer, D., van Til, H.: Investments and regulation: the Dutch experience. Electr. J. 23(5), 34–46 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamasb, T., Pollitt, M., et al.: Productivity and efficiency of US gas transmission companies: a European regulatory perspective. Energy Policy 36(9), 3398–3412 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joskow, P.: Incentive regulation of electricity distribution networks: lessons of experience from Britain. Energy Policy 35, 6163–6187 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kay, J.: Culture and Prosperity: Why Some Nations Are Rich but Most Remain Poor. Harper Paperbacks (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, R., Mulder, M., van Sinderen, J.: Outcome van NMa-optreden: een beschrijving van de berekeningsmethode. Netherlands Competition Authority, Working Papers 1 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulder, M.: Tariff regulation and profitability of energy networks. Netherlands Competition Authority, Working Paper 3 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Movares & Kiwa: Technisch onderzoek vervangingsinvesteringen netbeheerders. Utrecht (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Nykamp, S., Andor, M., Hurink, J.L.: ‘Standard’ incentive regulation hinders the integration of renewable energy generation. Energy Policy 47, 222–237 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollitt, M.: The role of efficiency estimates in regulatory price reviews: Ofgem’s approach to benchmarking electricity networks. Utilities Policy 13(4), 279–288 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • PwC: Investeringen in energienetwerken onder druk? Een beoordeling van het reguleringskader. Amsterdam (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A.: A theory of yardstick competition. Rand J. Econ. 16(3), 319–327 (1985)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ter-Martirosyna, A.: The Effects of Incentive Regulation on Quality of Service in Electricity Markets. George Washington University (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ter-Martirosyna, A., Kwoka, J.: Incentive regulation, service quality, and standards in U.S. electricity distribution. J. Regul. Econ. 38(3), 258–273 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veldman, E., Geldtmeijer, D.A.M., Knigge, J.D., Slootweg, J.G.: Smart grids put into practice: technological and regulatory aspects. Competition Regul. Netw. Indus. 11(3), 287–306 (2010)

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W.K., Vernon, J.M., Harrington, J.E.: Economics of Regulation and Antitrust (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • WRR: Infrastructures: time to invest. Amsterdam University Press (2007)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Machiel Mulder .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Mulder, M. (2016). Economic Regulation of Energy Networks. In: Beaulieu, A., de Wilde, J., Scherpen, J. (eds) Smart Grids from a Global Perspective. Power Systems. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-28077-6_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-28077-6_8

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-28075-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-28077-6

  • eBook Packages: EnergyEnergy (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics