Skip to main content

Educational Systems and the Intergenerational Transmission of Inequality: A Complex Dynamical Systems Perspective

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Complex Dynamical Systems in Education
  • 1157 Accesses

Abstract

Human beings have many observable and measurable characteristics that distinguish and segregate them in many ways. Some segregations result from the structure of organizations through which an individual transit along—like the educational system—that interact with other modes of inherited segregations like race, income, sex, geographical area, etc. This chapter is about the intergenerational transmission of income inequalities induced by educational systems that generate persistent effects on societies. One may naturally think of the influence that aggregate characteristics of a community have on schooling decisions. Youngsters in low-income families, for example, are more likely to fail and dropout the school, starting out at a disadvantage in the labor market and restricting their future earnings. These individual decisions, in turn, affect aggregate outcomes that could potentially explain why societies show self-perpetuating inequalities in education and income distribution that reinforce each other over time. This issue is attracting significant attention recently, and new interdisciplinary knowledge is needed to inform and guide the current and future debates. A Complex Dynamical Systems (CDS ) approach is essential to understand the persistence of income inequalities that educational systems generate in the context of global trends. A CDS simulation model will be applied to track down the complex interaction of such inequalities and draw alternative causal inferences to those documented by studies using correlation methods. Baseline simulations are contrasted to data compiled from Nicaragua (2000–2010) in order to assess the model ability to replicate historical observations. The method can be extended for the purpose of designing and evaluating feasible, cost-effective policies to attenuate social and economic disparities in society. We conclude that inequality is detrimental for the operational efficiency of the educational system itself.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The dominant theory of human capital formation is rooted in economics and owns its relevance to outstanding contributions by Mincer (1958), Becker (1962), and Becker and Chiswick (1964). These celebrated authors established the central role of education to explain earnings’ differences and inequalities in society, and their ideas have been subject to mounting empirical scrutiny by authors like Hanushek (2009, 2014), Autor (2014), Ravallion (2014), among others.

  2. 2.

    By efficiency we mean the ability of an educational system to graduate the maximum number of students had children entered school at normal age and advanced one grade each year, without repetition or dropout.

  3. 3.

    The individual-based interventions which focus on cognitive skills and learning trajectories attained by students during the instruction process and the influence of school factors on those trajectories have also a great deal of interest in this book. See for instance the analysis of learning trajectories over time and the influence of the classroom interactional context by Steenbeek and van Geert (University of Groningen, Netherlands); or the use of orbital decomposition to study the predictability of learning behaviors and patterns of social interaction in educational settings by Stamovlasis (Aristotle University of Thessaloniki, Greece).

  4. 4.

    The model complies with the first two laws of physics. The First Law (conservation of the matter) states that the amount of people entering the system must not be different from that that ever goes out, ruling out the possibility that the simulation model creates people artificially due to a human error in the computer code. The Second Law proposes that the entropy of a closed system cannot decrease and time has only one direction (see Guevara, 2014).

  5. 5.

    The Lorenz curve is often used to represent income distribution and shows the proportion of income or wealth (y %) accrued by the bottom x % of the population. A perfectly equal income distribution would be one in which the bottom x % of society would always have x % of the income and can be depicted by the straight line y = x which is called the ”line of equidistribution”.

  6. 6.

    We calibrated the model using a complete set of quantitative information circa 2000 (most of data used in the model comes from the 2001 LSMS). Before 2001, primary-school data available were not disaggregated by income.

  7. 7.

    A particularity of these factors is that they cannot be developed or purchased instantaneously; they resemble stocks, which thus must be accumulated over time to reach a particular level. For instance, the state of adult literacy in a population cannot be raised immediately; it has to be developed through the transmission of basic learning capabilities on to children, which takes several years. So to explicitly use adult literacy as a critical factor in this model, the flow of primary school graduates is accumulated in a stock.

  8. 8.

    Real GDP per capita in 2000 was US$1,035 (World Bank, 2015).

  9. 9.

    Of course the entire data set used to calibrate the model is far larger than that and the one provided in the appendix is just for the sake of illustration. For the complete data set used in the calibration process please contact the authors. Similarly for a detailed description of all assumptions (feedbacks and nonlinear relationships) see Guevara et al. (2014).

  10. 10.

    Here we assume that Nicaragua’s population grows at 3 % which means that a 3 % growth in its Gross Domestic Product (GDP) would not change per-capita GDP, which is the ratio of GDP divided by population.

References

  • Andersen, L. (2001) Social mobility in Latin America: links with adolescent schooling. IADB Research Network Working Paper #R-433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arcia, G. (2003). The incidence of public education spending: impact of the education for all—fast track initiative. Consulting Report, The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Autor, D. (2014). Skills, education, and the rise of earnings inequality among the “other 99 percent”. Science, 344, 843–850.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1962). Investment in Human Capital. The Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), 9–49. part 2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Chiswick, B. R. (1964). Education and the distribution of earnings. American Economic Review, 56(1/2), 358–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Behrman, J. R., & Rosenzweig, M. R. (2005). Does increasing women's schooling raise the schooling of the next generation? American Economic Review, 95, 1745–1751.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvacanti, P., De Abreu, S., & Veloso, F. (2013). On the evolution of total factor productivity in Latin America. Economic Inquiry, 51(1), 16–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, S. (2010). From eternity to here: The quest for the ultimate theory of time. New York: Penguin Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowrick, S. (2004). Ideas and education: level or growth effects and their implications for Australia. In: Growth and Productivity in East Asia. NBER-East Asia Seminar on Economics, (pp. 9–40). National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf, S. N. (1998). What should policymakers know about economic complexity? Washington Quarterly, 21(1), 157–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guevara, P. (2014). Toward a common structure in demographic educational modeling and simulation: A complex systems approach. Complicity: An International Journal of Complexity and Education, 11(2), 86–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guevara, P., Lopez, L., Posch, A., & Zuniga, R. (2014). A dynamic nonlinear model for educational systems: a simulation study for primary education. Nonlinear Dynamics, Psychology, and Life-Sciences, 18(1), pp.91–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Guevara, P., & Posch, A. (2015). Dynamic complexity, entropy, and coordination in educational systems: A simulation of strategic and exogenous interventions. Systemic Practice and Action Research, 28(2), pp.179–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek, E. (2009). The economic value of education and cognitive skills. In G. Sykes, B. Schneider, & D. N. Plank (Eds.), Handbook of education policy research (pp. 39–56). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek, E., and Woessmann, L. (2014). Institutional structures of the education system and student achievement: A review of cross-country economic research. In: Strietholt et al (ed.) Educational Policy Evaluation through International Comparative Assessments Waxman 2014. Retrieved May, 2015 from http://hanushek.stanford.edu/sites/default/files/publications/Hanushek%2BWoessmann%202014%20EduPolEval.pdf.

  • Koopmans, M. (2014). Nonlinear change and the black box problem in educational research. Nonlinear Dynamics, Psychology, and Life Sciences, 18(1), 5–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Living Standards Measurement Surveys (LSMS 2001, 2005, 2009). Nicaragua. The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J. (1958). Investment in human capital and personal income distribution. Journal of Political Economy, 66(4), 281–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, K. (2008). Educational philosophy and the challenge of complexity theory. Educational Philosophy and Theory, 40, 19–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noble, K. G., Houston, S. M., Brito, N., Bartsch, H., Kan, E., Kuperman, J. M., et al. (2015). Family Income, parental education and brain structure in children and adolescents. Nature Neuroscience, 18(5), 773–778. doi:10.1038/nn.3983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oreopoulos, P., Page, M. E., & Stevens, A. H. (2006). The intergenerational effects of compulsory schooling. Journal of Labor Economics, 24(4), 729–760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21 st century. Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porta, E. (2011). A data set for estimating global indicators of education inequality. Washington, DC: World Bank, Human Development Network.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porta, E., Arcia, G., Macdonald, K., Radyakin, S., & Lokshin, M. (2011). Assessing sector performance and inequality in education. Washington: The World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Porta E. and Laguna, J.R. (2007). Educational Equity in Central America: A pending issue for the public agenda. USAID Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion, M. (2014). Income inequality in the developing world. Science, 344, 851–855.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SEDLAC (2015). Socio-Economic Database for Latin America and the Caribbean. CEDLAS and The World Bank, http://sedlac.econo.unlp.edu.ar/eng/. Accessed in May, 2015.

  • UNESCO (2015). Literacy Data Show a Persistent Gender Gap. http://www.uis.unesco.org/literacy/Pages/literacy-day-2014.aspx. Accessed in August, 2015.

  • World Bank (2001). Nicaragua Poverty Assessment Challenges and Opportunities for Poverty Reduction. Report No. 20488-NI.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2015). World development indicators. Washington, DC: The World Bank, http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog. Accessed in May, 2015.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Porfirio Guevara .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix

The following description of the simulation model is an excerpt from Guevara et al. (2014) reprinted with permission from the journal Nonlinear Dynamics, Psychology, and Life Sciences.

The Simulation Model

The educational model has 3 state variables: Population (P), Population in Primary School (G), and Primary School Graduates (H). These are represented by stocks (rectangles) in Fig. 15.3. P stands for the country’s total population, disaggregated into age cohorts and it is the main input to the education system (Eq. 15.1). The arrows in Fig. 15.3 are differential equations that modify the stocks; hence, population increases with births and decreases with deaths. Equation 15.1 shows that the birth rate B, is the product of a constant fractional vector β multiplied by the country’s population (i.e., the sum of all age-cohorts). Similarly, death rate D, is the result of a constant ϕ multiplied by the stock of population. In the model, aging [A(t)] represents the transition of the population from one age cohort to the next, after it has remained an average length of time (υ) in that cohort. P a (0) is the initial population.

$$ {P}_a(t)={\displaystyle \underset{t={t}_0}{\overset{T}{\int }}\left[B(t)+{A}_{a-1}(t)-{A}_a(t)-{D}_a(t)\right]\;\mathrm{d}t}+{P}_a(0) $$
(15.1)
$$ \mathrm{where}\kern1.12em B(t)=\beta {\displaystyle \sum_a{P}_a}\kern1em 0<\beta <1 $$
$$ {D}_a(t)=\phi {P}_a\kern1em 0<\phi <1 $$
$$ {A}_a(t)=\raisebox{1ex}{${P}_a$}\!\left/ \!\raisebox{-1ex}{$\upsilon $}\right.\kern1em \upsilon \kern0.5em =\kern0.5em 1, $$
$$ {P}_a(t)=\mathrm{stock}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{age}\hbox{-} \mathrm{a}\ \mathrm{population},a=0,\ 1,\ 2, \dots,\ 15,\ \mathrm{and}\ \mathrm{Adults}\ \left(16\ \mathrm{or}\ \mathrm{more}\right). $$
$$ {A}_a(t)=\mathrm{aging}\ \mathrm{rate},\kern0.37em B(t)=\mathrm{birth}\ \mathrm{rate},\;{D}_a(t)=\mathrm{death}\ \mathrm{rate}, $$

The second state variable, G, is a matrix broken down by grade and age, encompassing children currently enrolled in school. Equation 15.2 shows that it consists of 6 grades according to the official cycle length in the country. In words, G 1,a (t) represents the population of age-a students attending the first grade. Once children enter the school system they may follow three mutually exclusive directions: (1) passing to the next level through promotion (p i,a (t)) from grade i to i + 1 and growing older by 1 year (from a to a + 1); (2) repeating the year (r i,a (t)) just passing to the next age cohort (from a to a + 1) but remaining in the same grade (i); or (3), dropping-out of the grade i at age a (d i,a (t)). Note that in Eq. 15.2 intake [e 1,a (t)] only occurs in the first grade, denominated by \( {p}_{0,a-1}(t), \) and promotion replaces it as an inflow after the second grade. Thus,

$$ {G}_{i,a}={\displaystyle \underset{t={t}_0}{\overset{T}{\int }}\left[{p}_{i-1,a-1}(t)+{r}_{i,a-1}(t)-{p}_{i,a}(t)-{d}_{i,a}(t)-{r}_{i,a}(t)\right]\mathrm{d}t}+{G}_{i,a}(0) $$
(15.2)
$$ \mathrm{where}\ {G}_{i,a}(t)=\mathrm{population}\ \mathrm{in}\ \mathrm{grade}\ i=1,\;2, \dots,\;6;\;\mathrm{age}a=0,\ 1,\;2, \dots,\;15,\;16\ \left(\mathrm{age}\;16\;\mathrm{and}\ \mathrm{above}\right). $$
$$ {p}_{i,a}(t)=\mathrm{promotion}\ \mathrm{grade}\ i\ \mathrm{at}\ \mathrm{age} $$
$$ {e}_{1,a}(t)=\mathrm{intake}\ \mathrm{rate}\ \mathrm{grade}\ 1\ \mathrm{a}\mathrm{t}\ \mathrm{a}\mathrm{ge}\ \mathrm{a};\;{p}_{0,a-1}(t)\equiv {e}_a(t) $$
$$ {r}_{i,a}(t) = \mathrm{repetition}\ \mathrm{grade}\ i\ \mathrm{at}\ \mathrm{age}\ a $$
$$ {d}_{i,a}(t) = \mathrm{dropout}\ \mathrm{grade}\ i\ \mathrm{at}\ \mathrm{age}\ a $$

All transition rates are specified as the product of a vector of fractions such as intake (α 1,a ), repetition (ρ i,a ), dropout (δ i,a ), and promotion \( \left({\uppi}_{i,a}\equiv \left(1-{\delta}_{i,a}-{\rho}_{i,a}\right)\right) \) multiplied by the stock of people in the respective grade (in the case of intake, by the population stock, P). In addition, these fractional values change across grades but remain constant within grades \( \left({\delta}_{i,a},\;{\rho}_{i,a},\;{\uppi}_{i,a}={\delta}_i,\;{\rho}_i,\;{\uppi}_i\right) \). The corresponding formulations are Eqs. 15.315.6.

$$ {e}_a(t)=e\left({P}_a(t),{\alpha}_{1,a}\right)={\alpha}_{1,a}{P}_a(t) $$
(15.3)
$$ {d}_{i,a}(t)=\mathrm{d}\left({G}_{i,a}(t),{\delta}_{i,a}\right)={\delta}_i{G}_{i,a}(t) $$
(15.4)
$$ {r}_{i,a}(t)=r\left({G}_{i,a}(t),{\rho}_{i,a}\right)={\rho}_i{G}_{i,a}(t) $$
(15.5)
$$ {p}_{i,a}(t)=p\left({G}_{i,a}(t),{\uppi}_{i,a}\right)={\uppi}_i{G}_{i,a}(t) $$
(15.6)
$$ {\alpha}_{1,a},\;{\delta}_{i,a},\;{\rho}_{i,a},\;{\uppi}_{i,a}\in \left(0,\kern0.1em 1\right)\;\mathrm{f}\mathrm{o}\mathrm{r}\ \mathrm{every}\ a $$

The third stock in Fig. 15.3, H, accumulates graduates from primary education as shown in Eq. 15.7. Equation 15.8 describes the construction of an index h of per-capita human capital which is the number of living people who have completed primary school compared to the country’s population. This index ranges from 0 to 1 where 0 implies that no adult (i.e., no person aged 16 and above) has completed primary education and 1 means that all adults have at least finished it. Therefore

$$ {H}_{a=16}={\displaystyle \underset{t={t}_0}{\overset{T}{\int }}\kern0.5em \left[{\displaystyle \sum_a{p}_{6,a}(t)}-{D}_{a=16}(t)\kern0.6em \mathrm{d}t\right]}+{H}_{a=16}(0) $$
(15.7)
$$ {h}_{a=16}=\frac{H_{a=16}}{P_{a=16}},\kern1.5em \mathrm{where}\ 0\le h\le 1 $$
(15.8)

Equations 15.1 to 15.8 allow the construction of the two performance indicators: the gross enrollment rate (from Eqs. 15.1 and 15.2) and the primary completion rate (from Eqs. 15.1 and 15.6):

$$ \mathrm{G}\mathrm{E}\mathrm{R}={\displaystyle \sum_{i,a}\frac{G_{i,a}(t)}{P_{7-12}(t)}} $$
(15.9)
$$ \mathrm{P}\mathrm{C}\mathrm{R}={\displaystyle \sum_a\frac{p_{i,a}(t)}{P_{12}(t)}} $$
(15.10)

Model Calibration

To calibrate the model it is necessary having a complete dataset for at least one point in time in which all stock variables are disaggregated by age, income group, and level of education attained. In this model that data point corresponds to year 2000 (LSMS 2001, 2005 and World Bank, 2015) and Table 15.3 shows this data point for the population variable used in the model, disaggregated by age and income. Likewise, Table 15.4 presents average parameter values for repetition and dropout rates across all grades for year 2000.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Guevara, P., Porta, E. (2016). Educational Systems and the Intergenerational Transmission of Inequality: A Complex Dynamical Systems Perspective. In: Koopmans, M., Stamovlasis, D. (eds) Complex Dynamical Systems in Education. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-27577-2_15

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-27577-2_15

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-27575-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-27577-2

  • eBook Packages: EducationEducation (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics