Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Contributions to Economics ((CE))

Abstract

As explained in Chap. 2, the decoupling hypothesis essentially refers to changes in the degree of business cycle interdependence between the two groups of economies (EEs and AEs). It implies two main consequences that should be empirically observable: (1) a decreasing comovement of economic cycles between AEs and EEs over time, (2) an increasing resilience of the EEs to adverse scenarios in AEs. These two points were studied in this chapter by using two different tools: the Euclidean Distance Indicator and the Time-Varying Panel VAR Econometric Model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    An earlier version of this article was published by the same authors in NBER Working Paper 14292, 2008.

  2. 2.

    See Kose et al. (2003b) for details on this approach.

  3. 3.

    Components include the global factor, representing the economic dynamic common to all countries; group factors, representing the economic dynamics common to the EEs, developing economies, and AEs, respectively; and country-specific factors, representing the specific economic dynamic of each national economic cycle.

  4. 4.

    Wälti (2012) performs his analysis on the so called deviation cycle, which is the difference between the actual GDP and its trend.

  5. 5.

    Coefficients of the model depend on a low-dimensional vector of time-varying factors, which can capture coefficient variations that are common across countries (“global” effect); variations that are specific to the group to which the country belongs, namely, advanced or emerging groups (“group” effect); variations that are specific to each geographical region (“region” effect) and to a specific country (“country” effect); or variations that are specific to the variable (“variable” effect).

  6. 6.

    Canova and Ciccarelli (2009) change the model proposed in Canova and Ciccarelli (2004) by providing a coefficient factorization that facilitates the estimation process.

  7. 7.

    Alan Heston, Robert Summers, and Bettina Aten, Penn World Table Version 7.1, Centre for International Comparisons of Production, Income, and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania, November 2012.

  8. 8.

    Own computation on data provided by the IMF, WEO Database, April 2013.

  9. 9.

    The grade is a judgment on the quality of data expressed by the author of the dataset. The grade goes from D (low quality) to A (high quality); see the cited authors for more details.

  10. 10.

    See Appendix 2 for descriptive statistics of GDP data for each country.

  11. 11.

    See the article of Wälti for details on the Euclidean method.

  12. 12.

    The GDP growth rate of each country was standardized by subtracting its mean and dividing by its standard deviation and then the synchronicity was evaluated through the Euclidean distance indicator.

  13. 13.

    The unweighted average was chosen because the data were “per head” and, thus, already weighted by the dimension of the country.

  14. 14.

    Wälti (2012) previously applied this same approach to the GDP deviation cycles of 56 countries, covering the period from 1980 to 2008. Despite the different sets of countries and data, Wälti came to the same conclusions as presented above. However, due to the lower temporal extension of his sample period, he was unable to observe the temporary jump of the indicator in 2009.

  15. 15.

    The results of each single emerging economy are available on request to the author.

  16. 16.

    The same conclusions were got when the deviation cycle, instead of the growth cycle, was used [namely the same definition of economic cycle used by Wälti (2012)]. See the Appendix 3 for these results.

  17. 17.

    For more details on this point see the Sect. 2.5.3 in Chap. 2 of this monograph.

  18. 18.

    These two options have been adopted in the literature [e.g., see Holtz-Eakin et al. (1988) and Binder et al. (2000)].

  19. 19.

    See Canova and Ciccarelli (2009) for more details on the factorization of coefficients and its economic interpretation.

  20. 20.

    This assumption allows considerable simplification in the calculus of the posterior density functions of parameters.

  21. 21.

    Given the equal weighting scheme used in averaging the variables of the original VAR, all data have been standardized to avoid bias due to the differences in the unit dimensions.

  22. 22.

    Known as the “evolution equation” in the jargon of the state space model.

  23. 23.

    It is well known that the random walk process hits any upper or lower bound with a probability of 1. This implication of the model is clearly undesirable. However, a random walk process is very commonly assumed for the transition equation in papers that use state space models (e.g., Koop and Korobilis 2010; Primiceri 2005 or Canova et al. 2007), because Eq. (3.3) is thought to be in place for a finite period of time and not forever.

  24. 24.

    The equation for the economic variables is also known as the “observation equation” in the jargon of the state space model.

  25. 25.

    So the number of lags, indicated with \( p \) in the presentation of the model, is equal to 1.

  26. 26.

    Each series has been standardized by subtracting its mean and dividing by its standard deviation; accordingly, each series has zero mean and unit variance.

  27. 27.

    The conditional expectations are computed orthogonalizing the covariance matrix of the reduced form shocks, assuming that AEs block comes first; a natural choice given the patterns of trade, remittances and capital flows discussed in the second chapter.

  28. 28.

    Part of the experiments presented in this section have been performed also using the model estimated on the entire data sample (1970–2010). See the Appendix F for more details.

  29. 29.

    Remind that before the estimation of the model the data have been standardized. This makes coherent the equal weighting scheme in the system (2.6)–(2.7) and also makes easier to interpret the comparison across time of the results of the simulations.

  30. 30.

    Let me note that, given that data have been standardized, in all cases I am simulating a 1.0 standard deviation shock. It is assumed that the shock does not alter the law of motion (3.7), so the estimated low of motion is used to compute \( {\theta}_{t+\tau } \) over the horizon for which we are computing expectations. With my random walk assumption on Eq. (3.7), this is equivalent to freezing the coefficients at their end-of sample values (on this point see Canova and Ciccarelli 2009).

  31. 31.

    In Bayesian econometrics, the model j is preferred to the model j* if the ratio of the marginal likelihoods \( {\displaystyle \int }{\ell}_j\left({\alpha}_j;\ Y\right)P\left({\alpha}_j\right)d{\alpha}_j/{\displaystyle \int }{\ell}_{j^{*}}\left({\alpha}_{j^{*}};\ Y\right)P\left({\alpha}_{j^{*}}\right)d{\alpha}_{j^{*}} \) is greater than 1 (when the same probability is assigned to each model, as it is in this paper), where the function j (α j Y) is the likelihood under the model j and P(α j ) is the prior probability density function of the parameters of model j; mutatis mutandis for \( {\ell}_{j^{*}}\left({\alpha}_{j^{*}};\ Y\right) \) and \( P\left({\alpha}_{j^{*}}\right) \). For details, see Lancaster (2005), for example, among others.

  32. 32.

    Marginal likelihoods are computed as harmonic mean (Newton and Raftery 1994).

  33. 33.

    See Greenberg (2008, p. 35).

  34. 34.

    Recession dates: 1974Q3-1975Q1, 1981Q1-1982Q3, 1992Q1-1993Q3, 2008Q1-2009Q2.

  35. 35.

    100,000 iterated simulations have been performed.

  36. 36.

    Further results are available in Appendix 6.

  37. 37.

    The Wishart distribution is a probability distribution of symmetric positive-definite random matrices, see Greenberg (2008, p. 190).

  38. 38.

    Let me note that the block diagonality of the matrix B is preserved also a posteriori, this means that factors are orthogonal also a posteriori and this guarantees their a posteriori identifiability.

  39. 39.

    See Greenberg (2008, p. 190).

  40. 40.

    From the Bayes rule \( P\left(\xi \Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T\right)=\frac{P\left(\xi \right)\mathcal{L}\left(\xi \Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T\right)}{P\left({Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T\right)}\propto \mathcal{L}\left(\xi \Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T\right)P\left(\xi \right) \).

  41. 41.

    The Gibbs sampling is an algorithm which draws sequentially the samples of parameters from the conditional posterior distributions [see Greenberg (2008) or Gelfand (2000) for more details on the Gibbs sampling].

References

  • Abiad A, Bluedorn J, Guajardo J, Topalova P (2012) Resilience in emerging market and developing economics: will it last? In: World economic outlook, Chap. 4. IMF, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Backus DK, Crucini J (2000) Oil prices and the terms of trade. J Int Econ 50:203–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baxter M, Kouparitsas M (2005) Determinants of business cycle comovement: a robust analysis. J Monet Econ 52:113–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binder M, Hsiao C, Pesaran H (2000) Estimation and inference in short panel vector autoregressions with unit roots and cointegration. University of Maryland, College Park, Manuscript

    Google Scholar 

  • Canova F (2007) Methods for applied macroeconomic research. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Canova F, Ciccarelli M (2004) Forecasting and turning point prediction in a Bayesian panel VAR model. J Econ 120:327–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canova F, Ciccarelli M (2009) Estimating multicountry VAR models. Int Econ Rev 50(3):929–959

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canova F, Ciccarelli M (2013) Panel vector autoregressive models a survey. European Central Bank, working paper series no. 1507

    Google Scholar 

  • Canova F, Ciccarelli M, Ortega E (2007) Similarities and convergence of G-7 cycles. J Monet Econ 54:850–878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chib S, Greenberg E (1995) Hierarchical analysis of SUR models with extensions to correlated serial errors and time-varying parameter models. J Econ 68:409–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cogley T (2003) An exploration of evolving term structure relations. Working papers 03-6, University of California, Department of Economics, Davis

    Google Scholar 

  • Cogley T, Sargent TJ (2003) Drifts and volatilities: monetary policies and outcomes in the post WWII US. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, working paper 2003-25

    Google Scholar 

  • Dées S, Vansteenkiste I (2007) The transmission of US cyclical developments to the rest of the world. European Central Bank, working paper series no. 798

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Negro M, Schorfheide F (2011) Bayesian macroeconometrics. In: Geweke J, Koop G, van Dijk H (eds) The Oxford handbook of Bayesian econometrics. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Fidrmuc J, Korhonen I (2006) Meta-analysis of the business cycle correlation between the euro area and the CEECs. J Comp Econ 34:518–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flood R, Rose A (2010) Inflation targeting and business cycle synchronization. J Int Money Financ 29(2010):704–727

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J, Rose A (1998) The endogeneity of the optimum currency area criteria. Econ J 108(449):1009–1025

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelfand AE (2000) Gibbs sampling. J Am Stat Assoc 95(452):1300–1304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg E (2008) Introduction to Bayesian econometrics. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Guimarães-Filho R, Hori M, Miniane J, N’Diaye P (2008) Can Asia decouple? Investigating spillovers from the United States to Asia. In: Regional economic outlook. IMF, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtz-Eakin D, Newey W, Rosen H (1988) Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica 56:1371–1395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbs J (2004) Trade, finance, specialization, and synchronization. Rev Econ Stat 86:723–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbs J (2006) The real effects of financial integration. J Int Econ 68:296–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kadiyala KR, Karlsson S (1997) Numerical methods for estimation and inference in Bayesian VAR models. J Appl Econ 12:98–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koop G, Korobilis D (2010) Bayesian multivariate time series methods for empirical macroeconomics. Foundations and trends in econometrics, vol 3, issue 4. Publishers Inc. PO Box 1024, Hanover

    Google Scholar 

  • Kose AM, Otrok C, Whiterman CH (2003a) International business cycles: world, region, and country-specific factors. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1216–1239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kose AM, Prasad ES, Terrones ME (2003b) How does globalization affect the synchronization of business cycles? Am Econ Rev 93(2):57–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kose AM, Prasad ES, Terrones ME (2003c) Volatility and comovement in a globalized world economy: an empirical exploration. IMF, WP/03/246

    Google Scholar 

  • Kose AM, Otrok C, Prasad ES (2012) Global business cycles: converging or decoupling? Int Econ Rev 53(2):511–538

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster T (2005) An introduction to modern Bayesian econometrics. Blackwell Publishing, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Newton MA, Raftery AE (1994) Approximate Bayesian inference by the weighted likelihood bootstrap. J R Stat Soc B 56:3–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Primiceri GE (2005) Time varying structural vector autoregressions and monetary policy. Rev Econ Stud 72(3):821–852

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett L (2000) Understanding patterns of economic growth: searching for hills among plateaus, mountains, and plains. World Bank Econ Rev 14(2):221–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart CM, Rogoff K (2012) This time is different, again? The US five years after the onset of subprime. Available at www.VoxEU.org. Accessed 8 Nov 2012)

  • Rose A, Engel C (2002) Currency unions and international integration. J Money Credit Bank 34:1067–1089

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2003) Understanding changes in international business cycle dynamics. NBER working paper no. 9859

    Google Scholar 

  • Wälti S (2012) The myth of decoupling. Appl Econ 44(26):3407–3419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WEO (2012) Coping with high debt and sluggish growth. IMF, Washington

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendices

Appendix 1: Set of Countries

See Table 3.5.

Table 3.5 Countries

Appendix 2: Main Descriptive Statistics

See Table 3.6.

Table 3.6 Descriptive statistics of GDP growth rate (%) data for each country

Appendix 3: Euclidean Distance Computed on the Economic “Deviation Cycles”

See Figs. 3.9 and 3.10.

Fig. 3.9
figure 9

Euclidean distance indicator computed on deviation cycles: EEs plus DEs vs. AEs and EEs vs. AEs. (1) EEs plus DEs vs. AEs, (2) EEs vs. AEs

Fig. 3.10
figure 10

Euclidean distance indicator computed on deviation cycles: EEs regional groups vs. all AEs. (1) Latin America EEs vs. AEs, (2) MENA EEs vs. AEs, (3) Sub Sahara Africa EEs vs. AEs, (4) Asia EEs vs. AEs, (5) Europe EEs vs. AEs

Appendix 4: Priors, Posteriors Distributions and the Computational Method

The prior distributions proposed in this chapter are chosen according to previous experiences from related literature and because of their intuitiveness and convenience in the applications.

Prior densities are assumed for \( {\xi}_0=\left(\;{\Omega}^{-1},B,\;{\theta}_0\right) \), and \( {\sigma}^2 \) is assumed to be known. The elements of \( {\xi}_0 \) are assumed to be independent. They are the parameters of the probability density functions of the innovations \( {\upsilon}_t \) and \( {\eta}_t \) and the initial state of the coefficients in system (3.6)–(3.7); hence, the assumption of independencies is very reasonable and, in fact, is a very common assumption in the related literature; therefore

$$ P\left({\theta}_0,\Omega, B\right)=P\left({\theta}_0\right)P\left(\Omega \right)P(B) $$
(3.8)

The matrix \( \Omega \) with dimension \( \left(NG\times NG\right) \) is the variance/covariance matrix of the residuals \( {E}_t \) and so \( {\Omega}^{-1} \) is the precision matrix. In Bayesian statistics, the Wishart distribution,Footnote 37 namely a probability distribution of symmetric positive-definite random matrix, is often used as the prior for the precision matrix, and also in this work it is assumed that the matrix \( {\Omega}^{-1} \) has the W distribution with \( {z}_1 \) degrees of freedom and scale matrix \( {Q}_1 \), namely:

$$ {\Omega}^{-1}\sim W\left({z}_1,\;{Q}_1\right) $$
(3.9)

The matrix \( B \), whose dimension is \( R\times R \) where \( R={\sum}_{f=1}^F{dim}_f \), is the variance/covariance matrix of the innovation \( {\eta}_t \). To guarantee orthogonality of factors, the matrix \( B \) must be block-diagonal, hence, \( B= diag\left({B}_1,\dots, {B}_F\right) \). For \( f=1,\dots, F \) each block \( {B}_f \), whose dimension is \( {dim}_f\times {dim}_f \), is assumed to be \( {B}_f={b}_f{I}_f \), where \( {I}_f \) is the identity matrix with dimension \( {dim}_f \) and \( {b}_f \) is a scalarFootnote 38 which is distributed like an inverse gamma with shape parameter \( \left(\raisebox{1ex}{$\rho $}\!\left/ \!\raisebox{-1ex}{$2$}\right.\right) \) and scale parameter \( \left(\raisebox{1ex}{$\varrho $}\!\left/ \!\raisebox{-1ex}{$2$}\right.\right) \):

$$ {b}_f\sim IG\left(\raisebox{1ex}{$\rho $}\!\left/ \!\raisebox{-1ex}{$2$}\right.,\;\raisebox{1ex}{$\varrho $}\!\left/ \!\raisebox{-1ex}{$2$}\right.\right) $$
(3.10)

The law of motion for the factors (Eq. 3.5) implies that for \( t=1,\dots, T\;{\theta}_t\Big|{\theta}_{t-1},B\sim N\left({\theta}_{t-1},B\right) \), and so

$$ P\left({\theta}_1,\dots, {\theta}_T\Big|{\theta}_0,B\right)=\prod_{t=1}^TP\left({\theta}_t\Big|{\theta}_{t-1},B\right)\propto {\left|B\right|}^{-\frac{T}{2}} exp\left\{-\frac{1}{2}{\sum}_{t=1}^T{\left({\theta}_t-{\theta}_{t-1}\right)}^{\prime }{B}^{-1}\left({\theta}_t-{\theta}_{t-1}\right)\right\} $$
(3.11)

where the symbol “\( \propto \)” stands for “proportional”. The prior for \( {\theta}_0 \) is assumed to be normal

$$ {\theta}_0\sim N\left({\overline{\theta}}_0,{\overline{R}}_0\right) $$
(3.12)

The values of the vector of hyperparameters \( \mu =\left({z}_1,{Q}_1,\alpha, b,{\overline{\theta}}_0,{\overline{R}}_{0,}{\sigma}^2\right) \) are selected either to produce rather loose priors (this is the case for \( {z}_1,{Q}_1,\alpha, b,{\overline{R}}_0 \)), or chosen observing the data (the case for \( {\overline{\theta}}_0 \)), or chosen to maximize the model in-sample fit of data (the case for \( {\sigma}^2 \)).

The hyperparameter \( {z}_1 \) is set equal to \( NG+50 \), namely 162 (i.e., dimension of the squared matrix \( \Omega \) plus 50) because, for the Wishart distribution to be proper, the degrees of freedom must beFootnote 39 at least equal to the dimension of the matrix \( \Omega \). In some related literature [e.g., Cogley and Sargent (2003), Cogley (2003), Primiceri (2005), or Canova et al. (2007)], the scale matrix \( {Q}_1 \) is chosen to be the inverse of variance/covariance matrix of the corresponding Ordinary Least Square estimates on a training sample. In this work, owing to available data, there is not a training sample and the scale matrix has been set equal to the identity matrix. This prior assumption means that the prior expected variance covariance matrix of residuals is a diagonal matrix, namely uncorrelated residuals between equations, and all equal elements on the diagonal; however, also in this case the prior probability density function on Ω allows for posterior non diagonal matrix, namely allows for the case of posterior correlated residuals between equations. The hyperparameters \( \rho \) and \( \varrho \) are set at 2 and 10, respectively. Following the related literature [e.g., Canova and Ciccarelli (2009)] \( {\overline{\theta}}_0 \) is the Ordinary Least Squares estimate in the time-invariant version of the model, and the matrix \( {\overline{R}}_0 \) is assumed to be \( {\overline{R}}_0={I}_R \) where \( {I}_R \) is identity matrix whose dimension is \( R\times R \) (remind that \( R={\sum}_{f=1}^F{dim}_f \)). Since the in-sample fit improves if \( {\sigma}^2 \) goes to zero, an exact factorization of \( {\delta}_t \) is used.

To compute the posterior distribution for \( \xi =\left({\Omega}^{-1,},{b}_1,\dots, {b}_F,{\left\{{\theta}_t\right\}}_{t=1}^T\right) \) the prior is combined with the likelihood \( \mathcal{L}\left(\xi \Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T\right) \) which (conditional to the first \( p \) observations before \( {Y}_1 \)) is proportional to:

$$ \mathcal{L}\left(\xi \Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T\right)\propto {\left|\Omega \right|}^{-\frac{T}{2}} exp\left\{-\frac{1}{2}{\sum}_{t=1}^T{\left({Y}_t-{W}_t\Xi {\theta}_t\right)}^{\prime }{\Omega}^{-1}\left({Y}_t-{W}_t\Xi {\theta}_t\right)\right\} $$
(3.13)

As explained in Greenberg (2008), using the Bayes rule,Footnote 40 the likelihood of data (3.13) and the prior probability density functions (3.8)–(3.12) the posterior distribution for \( \xi \) is proportional to:

$$ \begin{array}{c}P\left({\Omega}^{-1,},{b}_1,\dots, {b}_F,{\left\{{\theta}_t\right\}}_{t=1}^T\Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T\right)\propto {\left|\Omega \right|}^{-\frac{T}{2}} exp\left\{-\frac{1}{2}{\sum}_{t=1}^T{\left({Y}_t-{W}_t\Xi {\theta}_t\right)}^{\prime }{\Omega}^{-1}\left({Y}_t-{W}_t\Xi {\theta}_t\right)\right\}\\ {}\times {\left|\Omega \right|}^{-\frac{\left({z}_1-NG-1\right)}{2}} exp\left\{-\frac{1}{2}tr\left({Q}_1{\Omega}^{-1}\right)\right\}\\ {}\begin{array}{c}\times {\prod}_{i=1}^F{b}_i^{-\left(\frac{\rho }{2}+1\right)} exp\left\{-\frac{\varrho }{2{b}_i}\right\}\\ {}\times {\left|B\right|}^{-\frac{T}{2}} exp\left\{-\frac{1}{2}{\sum}_{t=1}^T{\left({\theta}_t-{\theta}_{t-1}\right)}^{\prime }{B}^{-1}\left({\theta}_t-{\theta}_{t-1}\right)\right\}\end{array}\end{array} $$
(3.14)

and to compute the conditional posterior distribution of each parameter we can consider only the terms in the joint posterior (3.14) that contain the parameter of interest. Let be \( {\xi}_{-\mathcal{K}} \) the vector \( \xi \) excluding the parameter \( \mathcal{K} \). After few algebraic passages (see Koop and Korobilis 2010) it is obtained:

$$ {\Omega}^{-1}\Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,\;{\xi}_{-\Omega}\sim W\left({z}_1+T,\;{\left({Q}_1^{-1}+{\sum}_t\left({Y}_t-{W}_t\Xi {\theta}_t\right){\left({Y}_t-{W}_t\Xi {\theta}_t\right)}^{\prime}\right)}^{-1}\;\right) $$
(3.15)
$$ {b}_f\Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,\;{\xi}_{-{b}_f}\sim IG\left(\frac{\rho +T*{dim}_f}{2},\;\frac{\varrho +\sum_t{\left({\theta}_{ft}-{\theta}_{ft-1}\right)}^{\prime}\left({\theta}_{ft}-{\theta}_{ft-1}\right)}{2}\right),\;f=1,\dots, F $$
(3.16)

The Eqs. (3.15) and (3.16) have been used in the Gibbs sampling algorithmFootnote 41 to draw samples of the parameters \( {\Omega}^{-1} \), \( {b}_f \) for \( f=1,\dots, F \); but to complete the algorithm it is needed a means of drawing from \( P\left({\theta}_t\Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,{\xi}_{-{\theta}_t}\right) \). Canova et al. (2007) (see also Canova 2007, p. 378) show that

$$ {\theta}_t\Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,{\xi}_{-{\theta}_t}\sim N\left({\overline{\theta}}_{t\Big|T},{\overline{V}}_{t\Big|T}\right),\;t\le T $$
(3.17)

where \( {\overline{\theta}}_{t\Big|T} \) and \( {\overline{V}}_{t\Big|T} \) are the one-period-ahead forecasts of \( {\theta}_t \) and the variance/covariance matrix of the forecast error, respectively, calculated with the Kalman smoother as described in Chib and Greenberg (1995).

The posterior density functions (3.15)–(3.17) have been used for sampling in the Gibbs sampling algorithm, as follows:

  1. 1.

    Initiate the algorithm by choosing \( {b}_f^0=0.01 \) for \( f=1,\dots, F \)

  2. 2.

    At the first iteration, draw

    \( {\theta}^{(1)}=\left({\theta}_1^1,{\theta}_2^1,\dots, {\theta}_T^1\right) \) with the Kalman smoother as in Chib and Greenberg (1995) knowing \( {b}_f^0 \) for \( f=1,\dots, F \)

    \( {\Omega}^{(1)} \) from the conditional posterior distribution \( P\left(\Omega \Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,\;{\theta}^{(1)}\right) \)

    \( {b_f}^{(1)} \) from the conditional posterior distribution \( P\left({b}_f\Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,\;{\theta}^{(1)}\right) \), \( f=1,\dots, F \)

  3. 3.

    At the gth iteration, draw

    \( {\theta}^{(g)}=\left({\theta}_1^g,{\theta}_2^g,\dots, {\theta}_T^g\right) \) with the Kalman smoother as in Chib and Greenberg (1995) knowing \( {b}_f^{g-1} \) for \( f=1,\dots, F \)

    \( {\Omega}^{(g)} \) from the conditional posterior distribution \( P\left(\Omega \Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,\;{\theta}^{(g)}\right) \)

    \( {b}_f^g \) from the conditional posterior distribution \( P\left({b}_f\Big|{Y}_1,\dots, {Y}_T,\;{\theta}^{(g)}\right) \), \( f=1,\dots, F \)

until the desired number of iterations is obtained. Once the posterior distribution of \( {\theta}_t \) is available it can be constructed the posterior distribution of the indicators for example, the posterior mean of the indicator \( {GI}_t \) can be approximated by \( \left(1/\mathcal{G}\right){\sum}_{g=}^{\mathcal{G}}{\mathcal{W}}_{1t}{\theta}_{1t}^g \), where \( \mathcal{G} \) is the number of draws, and a credible 68 % interval can be obtained by ordering the draws of \( {\mathcal{W}}_{1t}{\theta}_{1t}^g \) and taking the 16th and the 84th percentiles of the distribution.

The convergence of the sampler to the posterior distribution has been checked by increasing the length of the chain. The results presented in this chapter are based on 100,000 runs of 200 elements drawn 500 times, and the last observations of the final 450 times is used for inference.

Appendix 5: Historical Decomposition of GDP Fluctuations

The Fig. 3.11 plots the historical fluctuations of GDP, the global component, the regional component and the idiosyncratic component (namely the country specific component and the residual term).

Fig. 3.11
figure 11figure 11figure 11figure 11figure 11figure 11

Historical decomposition of GDP fluctuations

Appendix 6: Additional Results

This appendix proposes additional results obtained with CAs which, differently from those presented in Sect. 3.2.3.5.2, have been performed on the model estimated on the entire data sample (1970–2010). Using the full set of data, instead of on the data until the time of the simulated shock, allows to consider a richer set of information in the estimation procedure.

The main advantage of using the model estimated on the full set of information is that the CAs can be performed also for the first years of the sample period because also the parameters estimated at the beginning of the sample period are based on a rich set of information; and so I believe that also this exercise, which is in some way in the same logic of the ex-post forecast econometric exercises often presented in the empirical literature, could confirm and make robust the results discussed in the Sect. 3.2.3.5 of Chap. 3.

Both the immediate impact and the cumulated impact have been computed on the sample period from 1981 to 2010.

Table 3.7 presents the median responses together with the lower and upper values of the credible intervals (16th and 84th percentiles, respectively) for different sub-samples.

Table 3.7 Dynamic impact of the adverse scenario in the AEs on the EEs; additional results

The resilience of EEs (see also Fig. 3.12) was higher during the last 15 years of the sample period than in the preceding 15, both when the evaluation is made in terms of the immediate impact and when it is made in terms of the cumulated impact. During the period 1996–2010, for example, the cumulated impact was about 15 % lower than in the period 1981–1995.

Fig. 3.12
figure 12

Impact (median, 16th–84th percentiles) on EEs of shocks spreading from the AEs; additional results. (1) Immediate impact, (2) Cumulated impact

Let us break down the whole sample period in smaller sub-samples (5-years). If we observe the last 15 years of the sample period, we see that the resilience of the EEs fell rather than rose. The immediate impact (also shown in Fig. 3.13, panel 1) measured during the 5-year period 2006–2010 was up 12 % from that measured in the 5-year period 2001–2005, and in turn the latter was 40 % higher than that measured during the previous 5-year period 1996–2000. The same conclusions are reached if the results obtained for the cumulated impacts are considered (Fig. 3.13, panel 2). Nevertheless it can be observed that, despite the increase in the intensity of impacts during the last 15 years (1996–2010), the cumulated effect of the shock simulated in the 5-year period 2006–2010 was approximately 9 % lower than that simulated in the 5-year period 1981–1985. Therefore, the EEs’ resilience at the end of the 2000s is greater than it was during the early 1980s.

Fig. 3.13
figure 13

Impact (median, 16th–84th percentiles) on EEs of shocks spreading from the AEs; additional results. (1) Immediate impact, (2) Cumulated impact

The above results broadly confirm the conclusion exposed in the Sect. 3.2.3.5.2 in this chapter.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Pesce, A. (2015). Is Decoupling in Action?. In: Economic Cycles in Emerging and Advanced Countries. Contributions to Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-17085-5_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics