Skip to main content

Abstract

Careful attention to ‘choice architecture’ promises to open up new possibilities for environmental protection—possibilities that may be more effective than the standard tools of economic incentives, mandates, and bans. How, for example, do consumers choose between environmentally friendly products or services and alternatives that are potentially damaging to the environment but less expensive? The answer may well depend on the default rule. Indeed, green default rules may be a more effective tool for altering outcomes than large economic incentives. The underlying reasons include the powers of suggestion, inertia, and loss aversion. If well-chosen, green defaults are likely to have large effects in reducing the economic and environmental harms associated with various products and activities. Such defaults may or may not be more expensive to consumers. In deciding whether to establish green defaults, choice architects should consider consumer welfare and a wide range of other costs and benefits. Sometimes that assessment will argue strongly in favor of green defaults, particularly when both economic and environmental considerations point in their direction. But when choice architects lack relevant information, when interest group maneuvering is a potential problem, and when externalities are not likely to be significant, active choosing, perhaps accompanied by various influences (including provision of relevant information), will usually be preferable to a green default.

Published 2014 in the Harvard Environmental Law Review, 38(1), 127-1. We thank the Harvard Environmental Law Review for permission to publish a revised version of “Automatically green: Behavioral economics and environmental protection”, Harvard Environmental Law Review, 38(1), 128-158.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a valuable collection, see Shafir (2013).

  2. 2.

    See generally Thaler and Sunstein (2008).

  3. 3.

    See Allcott (2011) and Allcott and Rogers (2012).

  4. 4.

    See Allcott, supra note 3, at p. 1093.

  5. 5.

    See Cialdini et al. (2006). Note in particular the finding that drawing public attention to the existence or pervasiveness of undesirable behavior can actually increase such behavior: “It is worthy of note that our most ineffective persuasive message simulated the sort of negatively worded, descriptive norm message that . . . is regularly sent by public health and community service officials regarding a wide variety of social problems. Our results indicate that appeals of this type should be avoided by communicators in their persuasive undertakings. Unfortunately, this is not always the case. . . . For instance, after we reported the outcomes of the present study [showing the ineffectiveness of park signs containing negatively worded, descriptive normative messages] to park administrators, they decided not to change the relevant aspects of their signage. . . . We were disappointed—but, truth be told, not surprised—that park officials weighted visitors’ subjective responses more than our empirical evidence in their signage decision.” Id.

  6. 6.

    See id. at p. 12.

  7. 7.

    It is possible, of course, that an emphasis on social norms will trigger adverse reactions and resistance, perhaps especially from younger people. See the discussion of “deviant subcultures” in Kagan and Skolnick (1993).

  8. 8.

    On individual motivations to consume, see Reisch (2003).

  9. 9.

    See generally Griskevicius et al. (2010). For a more general discussion of this phenomenon, see Akerlof and Kranton (2010).

  10. 10.

    On the diversity of social meanings and their changes over time, see generally Lessig (1995). On energy in particular, with striking findings that are implicitly about social meaning, see Costa and Kahn (2010) (showing disparate reactions, across ideological lines, to information about social norms with respect to energy usage).

  11. 11.

    See Griskevicius et al., supra note 9, at pp. 393–394; Sexton and Sexton (2011).

  12. 12.

    See Sexton & Sexton, supra note 11, at p. 22.

  13. 13.

    Starr (2009).

  14. 14.

    See generally Kahneman (2011) (comparing two modes of thinking: System 1, which is responsible for automatic, intuitive judgments, and System 2, which is responsible for deliberate, non-intuitive judgments).

  15. 15.

    See Pachur et al. (2012).

  16. 16.

    See Hartmann and Apaolaza Ibáñez (2006) (noting that some empirical research “has found that people accept mark-ups on the price of green energy brands because they want to feel better about themselves, and are not primarily interested in the objective environmental impact of their decision”).

  17. 17.

    See Schuldt (2013).

  18. 18.

    Eric Johnson and Daniel Goldstein, Decisions By Default, in The Behavioral Foundations of Policy, supra note 1, at p. 417; Brown and Krishna (2004).

  19. 19.

    On default rules in general, see Chetty et al. (2012) (concluding that automatic contributions are more effective at increasing retirement savings rates than price subsidies); Halpern et al. (2013) (concluding that patients may not hold firm individualized preferences regarding end-of-life care). For many examples in the context of green defaults, see Part II below.

  20. 20.

    See generally Ullmann-Margalit (1978) (describing invisible-hand mechanisms, which give rise to phenomena that “look[ ] to be the product of someone’s intentional design,” but are not).

  21. 21.

    For the available palette of default policies, see generally Johnson et al. (2012).

  22. 22.

    To illustrate, total generation of paper and paperboard in municipal solid waste has grown from 30 million tons in 1960 to 70 million tons in 2011 and paper comprised roughly 28 % of the total municipal solid waste in 2011 EPA (2011).

  23. 23.

    See Print Management Information, Rutgers.edu, http://perma.law.harvard.edu/03BNSKSY4oZ

  24. 24.

    See Egebark and Ekström (2013).

  25. 25.

    Id.

  26. 26.

    Id.

  27. 27.

    Id. at p. 20.

  28. 28.

    The literature is voluminous. For diverse views, see Boyle (2012), Everett et al. (2012), Meiners et al. (2011), and Zehner (2012).

  29. 29.

    See Schuldt, supra note at p. 17.

  30. 30.

    For one example, see Frequently Asked Questions, Mass Energy Consumers Alliance, http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0wkGmTsXtxJ

  31. 31.

    See generally Pichert and Katsikopoulos (2008), on which we draw throughout this section. A more recent experimental study in Germany is reported in Kaenzig et al. (2013).

  32. 32.

    See Pichert & Katsikopoulos, supra note 31, at p. 64 (citation omitted).

  33. 33.

    Id. at p. 66.

  34. 34.

    Id.

  35. 35.

    Id.

  36. 36.

    Id.

  37. 37.

    Id.

  38. 38.

    Id.

  39. 39.

    Id.

  40. 40.

    Id.

  41. 41.

    See Pichert & Katsikopoulos, supra note 31, at p. 64.

  42. 42.

    See Loewenstein et al. (2014) (“Such studies are likely to overstate behavioral reactions to the disclosure, in part because it is easier to say that one will take some kind of protective action than actually to take it, and in part because the disclosures in such studies tend to be much more salient than they typically are in real world settings. The problem is compounded when subjects are given multiple decisions to make differing only (or mainly) on disclosures, because the variation of disclosures against an otherwise constant background will artificially increase their salience.”).

  43. 43.

    Pichert & Katsikoupoulos, supra note 31, at pp. 67–68.

  44. 44.

    Id. at pp. 67–69.

  45. 45.

    Id.

  46. 46.

    Id.

  47. 47.

    Id. at pp. 68–69.

  48. 48.

    Id.

  49. 49.

    Pichert & Katsikoupoulos, supra note 31, at p. 70.

  50. 50.

    Id.

  51. 51.

    Id.

  52. 52.

    See Kahneman et al. (1991).

  53. 53.

    See Fryer et al. (2012).

  54. 54.

    See Kaenzig et al., supra note 31, at pp. 318–319.

  55. 55.

    Note, however, that 2 years after the Fukushima disaster and the initiation of the German “Energiewende” (meaning energy transition, designed to shift to environmentally superior energy sources), most energy providers offer attractive “green energy” mixes and have greatly changed their supply policy. See Reisch (2013).

  56. 56.

    See infra at nn. 82–91 and accompanying text (discussing inertia).

  57. 57.

    There is a great deal of work on the Energy Paradox, which occurs when consumers, focused narrowly on the short term, do not purchase energy-efficient products that are in their economic interest. For a valuable overview showing the complexity of the underlying issues and the amount that remains to be learned, see Allcott and Greenstone (2012). For an important discussion of externalities and internalities, see Allcott et al. (2012).

  58. 58.

    See generally Dinner et al. (2011).

  59. 59.

    See id. at p. 332 (citation omitted).

  60. 60.

    Id. at p. 341.

  61. 61.

    Id.

  62. 62.

    Id. at p. 335.

  63. 63.

    Id.

  64. 64.

    Id. at p. 334.

  65. 65.

    See, e.g., Fox-Penner (2012).

  66. 66.

    A valuable discussion can be found in Gilbert et al. (2013).

  67. 67.

    See id. at pp. 4–7.

  68. 68.

    Directive 2009/72/EC (2009).

  69. 69.

    Data privacy concerns may arise if, for example, consumers do not want others to know about their energy use.

  70. 70.

    See Renner et al. (2011).

  71. 71.

    See Dinner et al., supra note 58, at p. 335.

  72. 72.

    Ölander and Thøgersen (2013).

  73. 73.

    Id. at p. 151.

  74. 74.

    See, e.g., Gale et al. (2009), Dinner et al., supra note 58, at p. 335, and Carroll et al. (2009).

  75. 75.

    See, e.g., Johnson and Goldstein, supra note 18, at p. 417 and Brown et al. (2011).

  76. 76.

    Madrian and Shea (2001); see also McKenzie et al. (2006).

  77. 77.

    People might also have experienced for themselves the positive outcomes of controversial regulatory decisions that they might not have endorsed ex ante, if given the choice. An example would be the smoking bans for bars and restaurants imposed in the U.S. and in Europe in the 2000s. Although enacted in the face of industry opposition, polls suggest these bans enjoy widespread support. Citing this and similar examples, Elke Weber concludes that “policy makers may sometimes be well advised to shape and lead public opinion rather than follow it.” Elke U. Weber, Doing the Right Thing Willingly: Using the Insights of Behavioral Decision Research for Better Environmental Decisions, in The Behavioral Foundations of Public Policy, supra note 1, at p. 380, 393.

  78. 78.

    See Löfgren et al. (2012).

  79. 79.

    See Tannenbaum and Ditto (2012).

  80. 80.

    See Costa & Kahn, supra note 10, at p. 17.

  81. 81.

    See Johnson and Goldstein, supra note 18, at pp. 420–421.

  82. 82.

    On choice avoidance, see Sethi-Iyengar et al. (2005).

  83. 83.

    For regular product tests and price comparisons of energy providers offers conducted by a German consumer organization, see Stiftung Warentest, http://www.test.de (last visited Dec. 4, 2013). See, e.g., Warentest (2012).

  84. 84.

    Infas Energiemontor (2012).

  85. 85.

    See Pichert & Katsikopoulos, supra note 31, at p. 64.

  86. 86.

    For a broad treatment of the effects of cognitive demands, with many implications for environmental choices, see generally Mullainathan and Shafir (2013).

  87. 87.

    Fleming et al. (2010).

  88. 88.

    See Brown et al., supra note 76, at pp. 129–130.

  89. 89.

    Id.

  90. 90.

    Ryan Bubb and Richard Pildes urge that default rules are effectively mandates, because they tend to be “sticky.” Bubb and Pildes (2014). The evidence much complicates this claim. When people dislike the default, they might well opt out. See, e.g., Beshears et al. (2010). This point suggests that freedom of choice can be an important safeguard against welfare-reducing defaults, not least in the environmental area.

  91. 91.

    See, e.g., Kahneman et al. (1994) and McGraw et al. (2010). Vivid evidence of loss aversion can be found in Card and Dahl (2011) (finding an increase in domestic violence after a favored team suffers from an upset loss in football).

  92. 92.

    See Fryer et al. (2012).

  93. 93.

    See id. at p. 1.

  94. 94.

    See id.

  95. 95.

    For a valuable discussion of loss aversion and its importance in an area of great environmental interest, see Homonoff (2013). Homonoff shows that a $0.05 tax on grocery bags in the District of Columbia had a significant effect in reducing grocery bag use, while a $0.05 bonus for using reusable bags had essentially no effect.

  96. 96.

    See supra at nn. 11–13 and accompanying text.

  97. 97.

    Brown et al., supra note 76, at p. 133.

  98. 98.

    Löfgren et al., supra note 79, at pp. 67–69.

  99. 99.

    See Dinner et al., supra note 58, at pp. 335–340.

  100. 100.

    Id. Recall, however, that the study was a laboratory experiment, not a randomized trial. If people actually had to take steps to change the default—rather than merely answering questions about whether they would do so—the switch rate would likely have been smaller.

  101. 101.

    See generally Costa and Kahn, supra note 10 (finding that Republicans actually increased their energy usage after learning about social practices involving energy efficiency).

  102. 102.

    See Beshears et al., supra note 91, at p. 8.

  103. 103.

    Id.

  104. 104.

    Id. at p. 10.

  105. 105.

    See, e.g., Brown, supra note 76.

  106. 106.

    See Just and Wansink (2009).

  107. 107.

    For supportive evidence, see Costa & Kahn, supra note 10, at p. 17.

  108. 108.

    See Shah et al. (2012).

  109. 109.

    Infas Energiemontor (2012), supra note 85.

  110. 110.

    See Löfgren et al., supra note 79, at p. 69.

  111. 111.

    See Micklitz et al. (2010).

  112. 112.

    See Craig Smith et al. (2009).

  113. 113.

    There are strong indications that this is the case in Germany, and demand for green energy has in fact risen dramatically in recent years. See generally Federal Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety (2012).

  114. 114.

    See Sunstein (2013b) [hereinafter Storrs Lectures] (discussing behavioral market failures).

  115. 115.

    Id.

  116. 116.

    See generally Thaler & Sunstein, supra note 2.

  117. 117.

    The Cabinet Office Behavioural Insights Team in the United Kingdom is actively engaged in such projects, including in the domain of energy. See Cabinet Office Behavioural Insights Team (2011).

  118. 118.

    For a valuable discussion, see Johnson & Goldstein, Decisions by Default, supra note 18.

  119. 119.

    Distributional issues may of course matter as well—a point to which we will return. See infra at n. 146 and accompanying text.

  120. 120.

    On some of the foundational questions, see generally Adler (2011).

  121. 121.

    See Muller et al. (2011).

  122. 122.

    See, e.g., Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (2010). For an illuminating critique, see Nordhaus (2011).

  123. 123.

    See Technical Support Document (2010), supra note 123, at p. 39.

  124. 124.

    See Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (2013).

  125. 125.

    See, e.g., Wansink and Hanks (2013).

  126. 126.

    See infra at n. 140 and accompanying text.

  127. 127.

    See Wansink (2014).

  128. 128.

    See infra at n. 140 and accompanying text.

  129. 129.

    Sendhil Mullainathan and Eldar Shafir, supra note 87, at pp. 147–157 (discussing effects of limited “bandwidth” on decisions by low-income people).

  130. 130.

    See Rebonato (2012) (objecting to the paternalism of default rules and related approaches).

  131. 131.

    See Storrs Lectures, supra note 115, at pp. 1867–1890 (defending mild forms of paternalism); Sunstein (2014) [hereinafter Why Nudge?].

  132. 132.

    See Keller et al. (2011).

  133. 133.

    Id. at p. 379.

  134. 134.

    Id.

  135. 135.

    Id.

  136. 136.

    Id.

  137. 137.

    Id.

  138. 138.

    Id.

  139. 139.

    See Johnson et al., supra note 21, at p. 491 (discussing “sensory defaults” and “predictive defaults”).

  140. 140.

    We have noted that the ideas of “green” and “gray” are not dichotomous, and include possibilities that can themselves be arrayed along a continuum; the same is true of “costless” and “costly” opt-out.

  141. 141.

    See generally Adler, supra note 121; see also Adler and Posner (2006).

  142. 142.

    See Why Nudge?, supra note 132; Bartling et al. (2013) (noting that entrepreneurs and scientists “effectively forego earnings for their self-employment,” suggesting that individuals may, in some circumstances, suffer a monetizable loss as the result of a reduction in their autonomy).

  143. 143.

    A behavioral market failure might justify a mandate or ban, but even in the face of such a failure, freedom-preserving responses are usually best. See Storrs Lectures, supra note 115, at p. 1861.

  144. 144.

    See, e.g., Ellerman et al. (2000).

  145. 145.

    See Graham (2008) (discussing the importance of considering the effects of regulations on low-income people).

References

  • Adler MD (2011) Well-being and fair distribution: beyond cost-benefit analysis. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Adler MD, Posner EA (2006) New foundations of cost-benefit analysis. Harvard University Press, New Heaven

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA, Kranton RE (2010) Identity economics: how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Allcott H (2011) Social norms and energy conservation. J Public Econ 95:1082, 1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allcott H, Greenstone M (2012) Is there an energy efficiency gap? J Econ Perspect 26:3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allcott H, Rogers T (2012) The short-run and long-run effects of behavioral interventions 28 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 18492, 2012). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0GWx1PeUNiU

  • Allcott H, et al (2012) Energy policy with externalities and internalities (Nat’l Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 17977). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0RFg9MTq964?type=pdf

  • Bartling B et al (2013) The intrinsic value of decision rights 5 (University of Zurich, Department of Economics, Working paper no. 120). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0LRJEhP32gQ

  • Beshears J et al (2010) The limitations of defaults, at 8 (Sept. 15, 2010) (unpublished manuscript). http://perma.cc/SZN9-UL9U?type=pdf

  • Boyle G (2012) Renewable energy: power for a sustainable future. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown CL, Krishna A (2004) The skeptical shopper: a metacognitive account for the effects of default options on choice. J Consum Res 31:529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown JR, et al (2011) The downside of defaults, Nat’l Bureau of Economic Research. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0rKzf98faWC/

  • Bubb R, Pildes R (2014) How behavioral economics trims its sails and why. Harv Law Rev 127(6):1593–1678

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabinet Office Behavioural Insights Team (2011) Behaviour change and energy use. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/04XS2Ehoo9x

  • Card D, Dahl GB (2011) Family violence and football: the effect of unexpected emotional cues on violent behavior. Q J Econ 126:103, 105–106, 130–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll GD et al (2009) Optimal defaults and active decisions. Q J Econ 124:1639, 1641–1643

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty R, et al. (2012) Active vs. passive decisions and crowd out in retirement savings accounts: evidence from Denmark, pp 42–44 (Nat’l Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 18565. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0GS3JRmBiTu

  • Cialdini RB et al (2006) Managing social norms for persuasive impact. 1 Soc Influ 3:10–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Costa DL, Kahn ME (2010) Energy conservation “nudges” and environmentalist ideology: evidence from a randomized residential electricity field experiment, pp 15–19 (Nat’l Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 15939). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0dyuJG9uPma

  • Craig Smith N, Goldstein DG, Johnson EJ (2009) Smart defaults: from hidden persuaders to adaptive helpers 15–16 (INSEAD Business School, Working Paper No. 2009/03/ISIC). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0LDi3hftNon

  • Dinner I et al (2011) Partitioning default effects: why people choose not to choose. J Exp Psychol Appl 17:332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Directive 2009/72/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 July 2009 concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and repealing Directive 2003/54/EC (Text with EEA relevance), Official J Eur Union, L 211/56 (2009). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0VqrouftKUg

  • Egebark J, Ekström M (2013) Can indifference make the world greener? (IFN, Working Paper No. 975). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/05S7PEkzZak

  • Ellerman AD et al (2000) Markets for clean air: The U.S. acid rain program. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 314–320

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • EPA (2011) Municipal solid waste in the United States: 2011 facts and figures 36. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0NPexDB4f8x

  • Everett B et al (eds) (2012) Energy systems and sustainability. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Federal Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety (2012) Development of renewable energy sources in Germany 2011. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0jqYfkyVCs6

  • Fleming SM, et al (2010) Overcoming status quo bias in the human brain. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 107:6005, 6007. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0kGWgzJTWAz/

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox-Penner P (2012) Smart power: climate change, the smart grid, and the future of electric utilities. Island Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Fryer RG et al (2012) Enhancing the efficacy of teacher incentives through loss aversion: a field experiment 2 (Nat’l Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 18237). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0rT5cjZhGJ3

  • Gale WG, Mark Iwry J, Walters S (2009) Retirement savings for middle- and lower-income households: The Pension Protection Act of 2006 and the Unfinished Agenda. In: Gale WG (ed) Automatic: changing the way America saves, vol 11. Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC, pp 13–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert B, et al (2013) Dynamic salience with intermittent billing: evidence from smart electricity meters (Nat’l Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 19510). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0aZMrdrmkLc

  • Graham JD (2008) Saving lives through administrative law and economics. Univ PA Law Rev 157:395, 516–523

    Google Scholar 

  • Griskevicius V et al (2010) Going green to be seen? Status, reputation, and conspicuous conservation. J Pers Soc Psychol 98:392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halpern SD et al (2013) Default options in advance directives influence how patients set goals for end-of-life care. Health Aff 32:408, 412–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartmann P, Apaolaza Ibáñez V (2006) Green value added. Mark Intell Plan 24:673, 676

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homonoff TA (2013) Can small incentives have large effects? The impact of taxes versus bonuses on disposable bag use? (Mar 27, 2013) (unpublished manuscript). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0vc54L915aU

  • Infas Energiemontor (2012) http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0AWnxhdhJrk

  • Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (2010) Technical support document: social cost of carbon for regulatory impact analysis under executive order 12866 [hereinafter Technical Support Document 2010]. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0mBWKsKgua7

  • Interagency Working Group on Social Cost of Carbon (2013) Technical support document: technical update of the social cost of carbon for regulatory impact analysis under executive order 12866. http://perma.cc/Z6LU-3L7C?type=pdf

  • Johnson EJ et al (2012) Beyond nudges: tools of a choice architecture. Mark Lett 23:487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Just DR, Wansink B (2009) Smarter Lunchrooms: using behavioral economics to improve meal selection. Choices 24:32 at *5. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0v6q6QJjfc6

  • Kaenzig J et al (2013) Whatever the customer wants, the customer gets? Exploring the gap between consumer preferences and default electricity products in Germany. Energy Policy 53:311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kagan RA, Skolnick JH (1993) Banning smoking: compliance without enforcement. In: Rabin RL, Sugarman SD (eds) Smoking policy: law, politics, and culture. Oxford University Press, Oxford, p. 69, 78

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D (2011) Thinking, fast and slow. Penguin, Harlow, pp 20–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Knetsch JL, Thaler RH (1991) Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. In: Thaler RH (ed) Quasi rational economics. Russel Sage Foundation, New York, pp 167–168

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Knetsch JL, Thaler RH (1994) Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. In: Thaler RH (ed) Quasi rational economics. Russell Sage Foundation, New York, p 167, 169

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller PA et al (2011) Enhanced active choice: a new method to motivate behavior change. J Consum Psychol 21:376, 378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessig L (1995) The regulation of social meaning. U Chi L Rev 62: 943

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G, et al. (2014) Disclosure: psychology changes everything. Annu Rev Econ (published online 2014. doi:10.1146/annurev-economics-080213-041341 (at 12). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/07CtT5P3qzh?type=pdf

  • Löfgren A et al (2012) Are experienced people affected by a pre-set default option – results from a field experiment. J Environ Econ Manage 63:66, 69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madrian BC, Shea DF (2001) The power of suggestion: inertia in 401(k) participation and savings behavior. Q J Econ 116:1149, 1182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGraw P et al (2010) Comparing gains and losses. Psychol Sci 21:1438–1444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie CR, Liersch MJ, Finkelstein SR (2006) Recommendations implicit in policy defaults. Psychol Sci 17:414, 418–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meiners RE et al (2011) The false promise of green energy. Cato Institute, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Micklitz H-W. et al (2010) The consumer – trusting, vulnerable or responsible? Plea for a Differentiated Strategy in Consumer Policy, Statement by the Scientific Advisory Board on Consumer and Food Policies at the Federal Ministry of Consumer Protection, Food and Agriculture (Dec 2010). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0pLVxTYUwJF

  • Mullainathan S, Shafir E (2013) Scarcity: Why Having Too Little Means So Much. Harvard University, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Muller NZ et al (2011) Environmental accounting for pollution in the United States economy. Am Econ Rev 101:1649, 1650–1653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus W (2011) Estimates of the social cost of carbon: background and results from the RICE-2011 model (Oct 18, 2011) (unpublished manuscript). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0oYg7zUgJqb

  • Ölander F, Thøgersen J (2013) Informing or nudging: Which way to a more effective environmental policy? In: Scholderer J, Brunsø K (eds) Marketing, food and the consumer. Pearson, Harlow, p 141

    Google Scholar 

  • Pachur T et al (2012) How do people judge risks: availability heuristic, affect heuristic, or both? J Exp Psychol Appl 18:314–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pichert D, Katsikopoulos KV (2008) Green defaults: information presentation and pro-environmental behaviour. J Environ Psychol 28:63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rebonato R (2012) Taking liberties: a critical examination of libertarian paternalism. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp 153–209

    Google Scholar 

  • Reisch LA (2003) Consumption. In: Page EA, Proops J (eds) Environmental thought. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, p 217

    Google Scholar 

  • Reisch L (2013) Verhaltensbasierte Elemente einer Energienachfragepolitik, in Grenzen der Konsumentensouveränität 139 (Jahrbuch Normative und institutionelle Grundfragen der Ökonomik, Vol 12)

    Google Scholar 

  • Renner S et al. (2011) European smart metering landscape report 91. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0C3Xc36oUhd

  • Schuldt JP (2013) Does green mean healthy? Nutrition label color affects perceptions of healthfulness. Health Commun 28:814, 818–819. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0TdZQj6CXFG

    Google Scholar 

  • Sethi-Iyengar S, Jiang W, Huberman G (2005) How much choice is too much? Contributions to 401(k) retirement plans. In: Mitchell OS, Utkus SP (eds) Pension design and structure: new lessons from behavioral finance. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sexton SE, Sexton AL (2011) Conspicuous conservation: the Prius effect and willingness to pay for environmental bona fides 22 (June 30, 2011) (unpublished manuscript). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0QoDHjmCU4s

  • Shafir E (ed) (2013) The behavioral foundations of policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Shah AK et al (2012) Some consequences of having too little, Science 338:682, 682–683. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0g1RdR5SXoz

    Google Scholar 

  • Starr MA (2009) The social economics of ethical consumption: theoretical considerations and empirical evidence. J Socio Econ 38:916, 919–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein CR (2013a) Deciding by default. Univ PA Law Rev 162:1. http://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1000&context=penn_law_review

  • Sunstein CR (2013b) The storrs lectures: behavioral economics and paternalism. Yale Law J 122:1826, 1842–1852

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein CR (2014) Why nudge? The politics of libertarian paternalism. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT

    Google Scholar 

  • Tannenbaum D, Ditto PH (2012) Information asymmetries in default options 11–17 (unpublished manuscript). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/02CkWtkhQjK

  • Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT

    Google Scholar 

  • Ullmann-Margalit E (1978) Invisible-hand explanations. Synthese 39:263–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wansink B (2014) Slim by design: mindless eating solutions for everyday life. Harper Collins, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wansink B, Hanks AS (2013) Slim by design: serving healthy foods first in buffet lines improves overall meal selection 2 (unpublished manuscript). http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0AR1Q16FzqS?type=pdf

  • Warentest S (November 20, 2012) Stiftung Warentest empfiehlt Versorgerwechsel. http://perma.law.harvard.edu/0UY2vcejFHH

  • Zehner O (2012) Green illusions: the dirty secrets of clean energy and the future of environmentalism. University of Nebraska Press, Lincoln

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

We are grateful to Cassie Chambers and Daniel Kanter for excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cass R. Sunstein .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Sunstein, C.R., Reisch, L.A. (2016). Behaviorally Green: Why, Which and When Defaults Can Help. In: Beckenbach, F., Kahlenborn, W. (eds) New Perspectives for Environmental Policies Through Behavioral Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-16793-0_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics