Skip to main content

New York Times v. Sullivan in European Context

The Optimal Liability for Libel from the Perspective of Behavioural Law and Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
European Perspectives on Behavioural Law and Economics

Part of the book series: Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship ((EALELS,volume 2))

Abstract

The evolution of tort liability for defamation seems to create one of the most puzzling phenomena within the area of economic analysis of tort law. Whereas generally tort law evolves from negligence towards strict liability, the US Supreme Court established the platform for the revival of negligence-based tort law in case of libel and defamation. In Gertz v. Robert Welch (1974) the court explicitly advised for the application of the negligence rule if the plaintiff was a “private person”. The paper concentrates on these changes in two aspects: the relation between them and new British libel laws and the economic analysis of defamation within a context of European Convention on Human Rights (art. 10). Applying the standard rational choice theory various law and economics scholars proposed different alternatives based on the balance between public good (freedom of speech) and actual damage to the individual. The consideration having been already presented and discussed in law and economics literature concentrated on the internalization strategy, assuming full rationality and free access to information for agents (journalists, publishers) and adjudicators (courts and juries). I suggest that a more modern approach to judicial process requires the reference to cognitive limitations of adjudicators and systemic errors committed by judges. Generally the divergence between prediction and post diction may lead to a lower level of risk-aversion and a higher level of publication in case of standards such as in the Reynolds standard in English common law or the generally accepted balancing strategy applied by the ECHR in Bladet Tromso and Stensas v. Norway (1999).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Cf. Rothbart and Snyder 1970; Kahneman and Tversky 1982; Guttel and Harel 2008.

  2. 2.

    The defence has been extended by Lord Nicholls’ proposition in Reynolds v. Times Newspapers Ltd [2001] 2 AC 127, where the House of Lords acknowledged that the mass media could have been entitled to the qualified privilege, provided certain conditions were met, including the following: (1) The seriousness of the allegation (2) The public nature of the information (3) The source of the information (4) The steps taken to verify the information (5) The status of the information (6) The urgency of the matter; (7) Whether comment was sought from the plaintiff; (8) Whether the plaintiff’s side of the story was covered (9) The tone of the article (10) The circumstances of the publication including the timing. ( Ibidem at 205). This doctrine was confirmed in Loutchansky v. Times Newspapers Ltd [2002] 1 All ER 652.

  3. 3.

    New York Times Co. v. Sullivan, 376 U.S. 254 (1964), 279–280.

  4. 4.

    Gertz v. Robert Welch, Inc., 418 U.S. 323 (1974), 347–348.

  5. 5.

    Cf. Schwabe v. Austria, Judgment of 28 August 1992, par. 37, Series A No. 313.

  6. 6.

    Bladet Tromso and Stensas v. Norway, Judgment of 20 May 1999, [GC] No. 21980/93, ECHR 1999-III.

  7. 7.

    Pedersen and Baadsgaard v. Denmark, Judgement of 17 Decemner 2004, para 78, [GC], No. 49017/99.

  8. 8.

    The other explanation may link this case to the criminal procedure and criminal liability for false allegation rather than simple civil liability for defamation.

  9. 9.

    This pertains especially to English law, where defamation cases were till 2013 decided with the jury. Cf. Tolstoy Miloslavsky v. United Kingdom, Judgment of 13 July 1995, Series A No. 316-B. The plaintiff in this case was able to satisfy the ECHR that libel damages of £ 1.5 million awarded against him by the English jury was exuberant constituting a violation of his right to freedom of expression under Article 10 of the ECHR.

  10. 10.

    Brown 1973.

  11. 11.

    Brown 1973; Shavell 1980.

  12. 12.

    Lee 1981; Renas et al. 1983.

  13. 13.

    Shavell 1987.

  14. 14.

    Posner 2003; Shavell 1992; Garoupa 1999.

  15. 15.

    Epstein 1986; Spier 1997.

  16. 16.

    von Neumann and Morgenstern 1944.

  17. 17.

    Hutcheson 1934; Frank 1949.

  18. 18.

    Simon 1955.

  19. 19.

    Kahneman et al. 1982.

  20. 20.

    Sunstein 2005; Vermeule 2006.

  21. 21.

    Sunstein 1996.

  22. 22.

    Jolls et al. 1998.

  23. 23.

    Rachlinski 1998, 2011.

  24. 24.

    Vermeule 2006, 2009.

  25. 25.

    Kahneman et al. 1982.

  26. 26.

    Cf. Sloaman 2002.

  27. 27.

    Kahneman 2003.

  28. 28.

    Rachlinski 2007–2008, 2011.

  29. 29.

    Kahneman 2003.

  30. 30.

    Sloman 2002.

  31. 31.

    Glöckner and Ebert 2011.

  32. 32.

    Posner 2003.

  33. 33.

    Jolls et al. 1998.

  34. 34.

    Rachlinski 1998; Sunstein 2005; Vermeule 2009.

  35. 35.

    Rachlinski 2007–2008.

  36. 36.

    Kahneman 2003.

  37. 37.

    Nossofsky 1992.

  38. 38.

    Allen and Brooks 1991; Smith et al. 1998.

  39. 39.

    Smith et al. 1998, p. 169.

  40. 40.

    Cf. Smith and Sloman 1994.

  41. 41.

    Estes 1994.

  42. 42.

    Nosofsky 1986.

  43. 43.

    Hampton 1995.

  44. 44.

    Murphy and Medin 1985.

  45. 45.

    Cf. Smith et al. 1998.

  46. 46.

    Allen and Brooks 1991.

  47. 47.

    Guttel and Harel 2008, p. 483.

  48. 48.

    Hill v. Colorado 530 U.S. 703, 707 (2000).

  49. 49.

    Hill v. Colorado 530 U.S. 703, 729 (2000).

Bibilography

  • Allen, Scott W., and Lee Brooks. 1991. Specializing the operation of an explicit rule. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 120:3–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, John Prather. 1973. Toward an economic theory of liability. Journal of Legal Studies 2:323–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, Peter. 1974. Single activity accidents. Journal of Legal Studies 3:107–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, Richard. 1986. Was New York Times v. Sullivan wrong? University of Chicago Law Review 53:782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Estes, William Kaye. 1994. Classification and cognition. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, Jonathan. 2008. Dual-processing accounts of reasoning, judgment, and social cognition. Annual Review of Psychology 59:255–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, Jerome. 1949. Law and the modern mind. London: Stevens.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garoupa, Nuno. 1999. The economics of political dishonesty and defamation. International Review of Law & Economics 19:167–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, Gerd. 2007. Gut feelings: The intelligence of the unconscious. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glöckner, Andreas, and I. Ebert. 2011. Legal intuition and expertise. In Handbook of intuition research, ed. M. Sinclair. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golecki, Mariusz. 2011. Między pewnością a efektywnością. Marginalizm instytucjonalny wobec prawotwórczego stosowania prawa. Warszawa: Wolters Kluwer Polska.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guthrie, Chris, Jeffrey Rachlinski, and Andrew J. Wistrich. 2007. Blinking on the bench: How judges decide cases. Cornell Law Review 93:1–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guttel, Ehud, and Alon Harel. 2008. Uncertainty revisited: Legal prediction and legal postdiction. Michigan Law Review 107:467.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hampton, James A. 1995. Testing the prototype theory of concepts. Journal of Memory and Language 34:686–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutcheson, Joseph. 1934. The judgement intuitive: The unction of the ‘Hunch’ in judicial decision. In Recueil d’Etudes sur le sources du droit de l’honneur de Francois Geny, vol. 2. Paris: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jolls, Christine, R Sunstein Cass, and Richard Thaler. 1998. A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review 50:1471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Just, Marcel Adam, and Patricia A. Carpenter. 1980. A theory of reading: From eye fixations to comprehension. Psychological Review 87:329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel. 2003. A perspective on judgment and choice. Mapping bounded rationality. American Psychologist 58:697–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1982. Variants of uncertainty. Cognition 11:143–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel, Paul Slovic, and Amos Tversky. 1982. Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, Gary L. 1981. Strict liability versus negligence: An economic analysis of the law of libel. Brigham Young University Law Review 2:398–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, Gregory L, and Medin, Douglas L. 1985. The role of theories in conceptual coherence. Psychological Review 92 (3): 289–316.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, John, and Oskar Morgenstern. 1944. The theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nosofsky, Robert M. 1986. Attention, similarity, and the identification-categorization relationship. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 115:39–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nosofsky, Robert M. 1992. Exemplars, prototypes, and similarity rules. In From learning theory to connectionist theory: Essays in honor of William K. Estes, ed. W. K. Estes. Hillsdale: Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pietrzykowski, Tomasz. 2012. Intuicja prawnicza. W stronę zewnętrznej integracji teorii prawa. Warszawa: Difin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner Richard, A. 2003. Economic analysis of law. 6th ed. New York: Walters Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlinski, Jeffrey. 1998. A positive psychological theory of judging in hindsight. University of Chicago Law Review 65:571–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rachlinski, Jeffrey J. 2009. Heuristics, biases and philosophy. Tulsa Law Review 43:865–883.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlinski, Jeffrey J. 2011. Processing pleadings and the psychology of prejudgment. DePaul Law Review 60:413–429.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbart Myron, and Snyder Mark. 1970. Confidence in the prediction and postdiction of an uncertain outcome. Canadian Journal of Behavioral Science 2(1):38–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, Herbert A. 1955. Behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69 (1): 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, Steven. 1980. Strict liability versus negligence. Journal of Legal Studies 10:107–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, Steven. 1987. Economic analysis of accident law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, Steven. 1992. Liability and the incentive to obtain information about risk. Journal of Legal Studies 21:259–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, Steven. 1995. The appeals process as a means of error correction. Journal of Legal Studies 24:379–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloman, Steven A. 2002. Two systems of reasoning. In Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment, eds. T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, and D. Kahneman. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Edward E., and Steven A. Sloman. 1994. Similarity—Versus rule-based categorization. Memory and Cognition 22:377–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Edward E., Andrea L. Patalano, and John Jonides. 1998. Alternative strategies of categorization. Cognition 65:167–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spier, Kathryn E. 1997. A note on the divergence between the private and the social motive to settle under a negligence rule. Journal of Legal Studies 26:613–621.Stephen M. Renas, Rishi Kumar, Charles J. Hartmann, and Donn G. Shankland. 1983. Toward an economic theory of defamation, liability, and the press. Southern Economic Journal 50:451–460.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, Cass, ed. 1996. Behavioral law and economics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, Cass. 2005. Moral heuristics. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28 (4): 531–542.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vermeule, Adrian. 2006. Judging under uncertainty. An institutional theory of legal interpretation. London: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vermeule, Adrian. 2009. Law and the limits of reason. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

This research was supported by the European Union and the State of Hungary, co-financed by the European Social Fund in the framework of TÁMOP-4.2.4.A/ 2-11/1-2012-0001 ‘National Excellence Program’.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mariusz J. Golecki .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Golecki, M. (2015). New York Times v. Sullivan in European Context. In: Mathis, K. (eds) European Perspectives on Behavioural Law and Economics. Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship, vol 2. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-11635-8_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics