Skip to main content

Methods of Prediction in Economics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 563 Accesses

Part of the book series: Theory and Decision Library A: ((TDLA,volume 50))

Abstract

Concerning the methodological aspects of economic prediction, the first step is to take into account the methodological scope for the kind of aim and the type of process. Chapter 11 deals with the method of prediction in economics. This requires us to consider the basis of the methodological process in economics: the kind of aim, which includes to be aware of the level of concretion of the aims as well as of the realm of the goal.

Regarding the type of process for prediction, the present analysis proposes a distinction between “predictive procedures” and “methods of prediction” in economics. In this context, several aspects are studied: (1) the characteristics of the methodological process (i.e., the preconditions for rational prediction); (2) the diversity of predictive approaches (i.e., unformalized and formalized predictions); (3) predictive procedures and predictive methods in economics; and (4) the analysis of their predictive methods by economists. Thereafter, on the role of models in economic predictions, there is an analysis of their characteristics and evaluation, followed by the study of economic modeling in the predictive realm and the presence of predictive failure with economic modeling.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In other cases, he distinguishes between “prediction” and “forecasting.” Then, he sees prediction as “formed from a theoretical model,” and forecasting as “limited to the extrapolations based on empirical models or data exploration” (Granger 2012, p. 312).

  2. 2.

    The list of publications in this regard is very long. Noteworthy contributions in these thematic contexts are Granger (1990a); Pagan (1990); Hendry and Ericsson (2001a); Clements and Hendry (2002a); Newbold and Harvey (2002); Elliott et al. (2006); Clements and Hendry (2011); Elliott and Timmermann (2013a, and 2013b); and Evans (2013).

  3. 3.

    “There are numerous ways of generating economic forecasts. Many are a mix of science—based on rigorously tested econometric systems—and judgment, occasioned by unexpected events: the future is not always like the present or the past” (Hendry and Ericsson 2001c, p. 186).

  4. 4.

    “Although progress is being made, we are still some way from a position where the model answers can be accepted without further human intervention. This is standard international practice. McNees surveyed the large U.S. forecasting organizations in 1981; they attributed between 20 and 50  % of the final forecast to judgmental adjustments (…). Adjustments are made in the light of other information, commonsense judgements, past model error, and a knowledge of its deficiencies. The useful exercise of this judgement is not limited to the specialists. Non-specialists may also make a valuable contribution providing that the issues are put to them clearly” (Burns 1986, p. 104).

  5. 5.

    “Knowledge of experts” is understood here in the sense of human expertise rather than an “expert knowledge” run by a computer program.

  6. 6.

    On the distinction between “economic activity” and “economics as activity,” see Chap. 7. The historical character of economic activity is also pointed out in Sect. 8.4. The notion of “historicity” is analyzed in Gonzalez (1996e, 2011b). On the criticisms of the elbow room give to history within economic theory, cf. Hodgson (2001).

  7. 7.

    On economic forecasting, see, for example, Holden (1989), Mills (1999a, 1999b, 2002), and Newbold and Harvey (2002).

  8. 8.

    The argument is based on Salmon’s ideas on rational prediction, and it has been developed in Chap. 3, especially in Sect. 3.3.2.

  9. 9.

    Rescher’s analysis includes more elements than those which appear explicitly in the table, mainly in the area of “unformalized/judgmental” prediction. Sensu stricto, scientific predictions are—for him—predictive validation by laws and modeling.

  10. 10.

    The Delphi procedure was developed in the 1950s by Olaf Helmer, Norman Dalkey, and Nicholas Rescher, cf. Helmer and Rescher (1959).

  11. 11.

    According to Rescher, the difference between prediction by means of “expert system” and the informal judgment of experts lies in the process rather than in the data sources: the focus here is on the attempt to make explicit and systematize the reasoning process used by the experts themselves (a procedure used in medical diagnoses) (1998, p. 97).

  12. 12.

    These predictions are commonly used in economics, cf. Önkal-Atay et al. (2002). In addition, there are several ways for improving the role of judgment in economic predictions, see Goodwin et al. (2011).

  13. 13.

    “The accuracy of judgmental forecasts is, on average, inferior to statistical ones. This is because our judgment is often characterized by considerable biases and limitations” (Makridakis et al. 1998, p. 483).

  14. 14.

    Consensus in error can be found in the times of Galileo Galilei and Charles Darwin.

  15. 15.

    Fernández-Jardón, C., Personal Communication, 25 January 2014.

  16. 16.

    In my interview with Herbert Simon on 20 December 1993, he insisted on the tremendous inaccuracy of the variables predicted by the 1972 Club of Rome report. On this issue, see Chap. 1, Sect. 1.2.2. and 1.4.3.

  17. 17.

    On causal order and statistical data, cf. Spirtes et al. (1993).

  18. 18.

    “Of all predictive processes it is scientific prediction, by means of laws and law-exploiting models, that furnishes its user with the highest level of rational comfort” (Rescher 1998, p. 110).

  19. 19.

    On the relations between representation and models in science, see Gonzalez (2014).

  20. 20.

    The details of these predictive methods extend beyond the scope of this book, which is focused on the philosophico-methodological approach. A large amount of information can be found in the bibliography cited in this chapter and in the following one.

  21. 21.

    Commonly, an oracle gives a “close statement”—a result—whereas a scientist offers the process followed to reach the final result.

  22. 22.

    A different kind of statistical indicator is the diffusion index. “This provides a measure of the proportion of a given set of leading indicators that are, at any time, moving in the same direction. The pooling of indicators in the form of a diffusion index reduces the risk that false turning points in economic activity may be signalled” (Llewellyn et al. 1985, p. 127).

  23. 23.

    On the Harvard Barometer, cf. van den Bogaard (1999, pp. 289–290).

  24. 24.

    “Our results also indicate that there is still much to learn about forecasting the business cycle. In particular, changes in the interest rate alone do not appear to have been sufficient to forecast the onset or length of the 1990s recession, even with the benefit of hindsight. (…) It still remains to be seen how well the implied composite leading indicator will forecast any subsequent UK recession” (Osborn 2001, pp. 122–123).

  25. 25.

    See Chapt. 9, Sect. 9.5.2. On the specific approach of “rational expectations,” an analysis is made in the papers collected in Frydman and Phelps (1983).

  26. 26.

    Historically, “time-series analysts played the dominant role in developing theoretical methods for forecasting in the postwar period” (Clements and Hendry 1998, p. 9).

  27. 27.

    It can be discussed if time series models, such as Box-Jenkins, should be considered in the group of “predictive methods” instead of being included in the set of “predictive processes.” The difference between a Box-Jenkins model and an approach of a predictive process (e.g., trend projection or curve fitting) is mostly statistical: a Box-Jenkins model is more sophisticated than a regression on a linear tendency. But it seems that, from the economic point of view, they are somehow similar. Nevertheless, the superior statistical framework leads one to think of Box Jenkins models as methodologically more sophisticated than those cases pointed out within the “predictive processes.”

  28. 28.

    The causal models use “causal variables” as the variables that actually determine the outcome. Some authors consider that “models with no causal variables might outperform those with numerous correctly included causal variables” (Hendry and Ericsson 2001c, p. 190).

  29. 29.

    Although there were a number of important contributions dealing with AutoRegressive Integrated Moving Average (ARIMA) class of models prior to 1970, that year marked the beginning of the popularization of this model and its associated predictive methodology, cf. Pedregal and Young (2002, pp. 71–72).

  30. 30.

    On time series econometrics, in addition to the book of Michael Clements and David Hendry (1998), already cited, cf. Granger and Newbold (1977); Abraham and Ledolter (1983/[2005]); Harvey (1990, 1991); Kacapyr (1996a); Kennedy (1998), Chap. 17, pp. 263–287; Clements and Hendry (1999); and Hendry (2000b). See also Kock and Teräsvirta (2011), and Koopman and Ooms (2011).

  31. 31.

    Mary Morgan introduces the distinction between “virtual experiments” and “virtually experiments”: “Virtual experiments (entirely nonmaterial in object of study and in intervention but which may involve the mimicking of observations) and virtually experiments (almost a material experiment by virtue of the virtually material object of input)” (Morgan 2003, p. 233).

  32. 32.

    Commonly, thought experiments are used to show the possibility and the impossibility of natural phenomena, social events, and artificial designs, as well as their limits in our world. See Gonzalez (2010b, pp. 37–38).

  33. 33.

    On complexity as a typical feature or economic reality, cf. Gonzalez (1994, p. 262). See also Gonzalez (2001a, 2013b).

  34. 34.

    Roth sees a parallel between evolutionary biology and economics because they deal “largely with historical data” (1986, p. 270).

  35. 35.

    See, for example, Boland (1989); Rubinstein (1998); Granger (1999); and Mäki (2002), part III: Economic Models and Economic Reality, pp. 105–228. The three volumes of Models of Bounded Rationality written by Herbert Simon (1982a, 1982b, 1997) offer a good example of the many aspects interrelated in the models.

  36. 36.

    “To evaluate an economic model, it is essential to know its purpose. Was it built to provide forecasts, to help with a policy decision, or test a specific economic hypothesis?” (Granger 2001, p. 94).

  37. 37.

    Prima facie, the analysis has a hint paradoxical insofar as the deterministic terms are those that, in principle, have a more clear content. Underneath Hendry’s considerations can be noticed the presence of historicity of economic phenomena.

  38. 38.

    This author offers a detailed analysis in Hendry (2000c).

References

  • Abraham, B., and J. Ledolter. 1983/[2005]. Statistical methods for forecasting. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arminger, G., C. C. Clogg, and M. E. Sobel, eds. 1995. Handbook of statistical modeling for the social and behavioral sciences. New York: Plenum.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. 1980a. Effective choice in the iterated prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution 24:3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. 1980b. More effective choice in the prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution 24:379–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. 1984. The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boland, L. 1989. The methodology of economic model building: Methodology after Samuelson. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box, G., and G. Jenkins. 1970. Time series analysis, forecasting, and control. San Francisco: Holden Day.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burns, T. 1986. The interpretation and use of economic predictions. In Predictability in science and society, ed. J. Mason, P. Mathias, and J. H. Westcott, 103–125. London: The Royal Society and The British Academy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burns, T. 2001. The costs of forecast errors. In Understanding economic forecasts, ed. D. F. Hendry and N. R. Ericsson, 170–184. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clements, M. P., and D. F. Hendry. 1998. Forecasting economic time series. Cambridge: ­Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clements, M. P., and D. F. Hendry. 1999. Forecasting non-stationary economic time series. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clements, M. P., and D. F. Hendry, eds. 2002a. A companion to economic forecasting. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clements, M. P., and D. F. Hendry. 2002b. An overview of economic forecasting. In A companion to economic forecasting, ed. M. Clements and D. F. Hendry, 1–18. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clements, M. P., and D. F. Hendry, eds. 2011. The Oxford handbook of economic forecasting. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, G., and A. Timmermann, eds. 2013a. Handbook of economic forecasting, vol. 2A. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, G., and A. Timmermann, eds. 2013b. Handbook of economic forecasting, vol. 2B. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliott, G., C. W. J. Granger, and A. Timmerman, eds. 2006. Handbook of economic forecasting, vol. 1. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle, R. F., and C. W. J. Granger. 1987. Co-integration and error correction: Representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica 55:251–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle, R. F., and H. White, eds. 1999. Cointegration, causality and forecasting: A Festschrift in honour of Clive Granger. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, M. K. 2013. Practical business forecasting. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frydman, R., and E. S. Phelps, eds. 1983. Individual forecasting and aggregate outcomes. “Rational expectations” examined. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 1994. Economic prediction and human activity. An analysis of prediction in ­economics from action theory. Epistemologia 17:253–294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 1995. Reichenbach’s concept of prediction. International Studies in the Philosophy of Science 9 (1): 37–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 1996e. Caracterización del objeto de la Ciencia de la Historia y bases de su configuración metodológica. In Acción e Historia. El objeto de la Historia y la Teoría de la Acción, ed. W. J. Gonzalez, 25–111. A Coruña: Publicaciones Universidad de A Coruña.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 1998b. Prediction and prescription in economics: A philosophical and methodological approach. Theoria 13 (2): 321–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 2001a. De la Ciencia de la Economía a la Economía de la Ciencia: Marco ­conceptual de la reflexión metodológica y axiológica. In Ciencia económica y Economía de la Ciencia: Reflexiones filosófico-metodológicas, ed. A. Avila, W. J. Gonzalez, and G. Marques, 11–37. Madrid: FCE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 2007a. The role of experiments in the social sciences: The case of economics. In General philosophy of science: Focal issues, ed. T. Kuipers, 275–301. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 2010b. Recent approaches on observation and experimentation: A philosophical-methodological viewpoint. In New methodological perspectives on observation and experimentation in science, ed. W. J. Gonzalez, 9–48. A Coruña: Netbiblo.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 2011b. Conceptual changes and scientific diversity: The role of historicity. In ­Conceptual revolutions: From cognitive science to medicine, ed. W. J. Gonzalez, 39–62. A Coruña: Netbiblo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 2013b. The sciences of design as sciences of complexity: The dynamic trait. In New challenges to philosophy of science, ed. H. Andersen, D. Dieks, W. J. Gonzalez, T. Uebel, and G. Wheeler, 299–311. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, W. J. 2014. On representation and models in Bas van Fraassen’s approach. In Bas van Fraassen’s approach to representation and models in science, ed. W. J. Gonzalez, 3–37. Dordrecht: Synthese Library, Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, P., D. Önkal, and M. Lawrance. 2011. Improving the role of judgment in economic forecasting. In The Oxford handbook of economic forecasting, ed. M. P. Clements and D. F. Hendry, 163–189. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J. 1986. Developments in the study of cointegrated economic variables. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 48:213–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J. 1989. Forecasting in business and economics. 2nd ed. San Diego: Academic (1st ed., 1980).

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J., ed. 1990a. Modelling economic series: Readings in econometric methodology. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J. 1999. Empirical modeling in economics: Specification and evaluation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J. 2001. Evaluation of forecasts. In Understanding economic forecasts, ed. D. F. Hendry and N. R. Ericsson, 93–103. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J. 2004. Time series analysis, cointegration, and applications. In From les prix Nobel. The Nobel prizes 2003, ed. T. Frängsmyr, 360–366. Stockholm: Nobel Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J. 2012. The philosophy of economic forecasting. In Philosophy of economics, ed. U. Mäki, 311–327. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J., and P. Newbold. 1977. Forecasting economic time series. New York: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, F. 1993. Predicting the economy. In Predicting the future, ed. L. Howe and A. Wain, 77–95. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, A. C. 1990. The econometric analysis of times series. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, A. C. 1991. Forecasting, structural time series models and the Kalman filter. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, D. M. 1998a. Rationality and knavery. In Game theory, experience, rationality, ed. W. Leinfellner and E. Köhler, 67–79. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, D. M. 2000. ¿Necesita leyes la Economía? Argumentos de Razón Técnica 3:115–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helmer, O., and N. Rescher. 1959. On the epistemology of the inexact sciences. Management Sciences 6:25–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. 1986. The role of prediction in evaluating economic models. In Predictability in science and society, ed. J. Mason, P. Mathias, and J. H. Westcott, 25–34. London: The Royal Society and The British Academy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. 2000b. On the time-series approach to econometric model building. In Econometrics: Alchemy or science? Essays in econometric methodology, ed. D. F. Hendry, new ed., 119–128. Oxford: Oxford University Press (1st ed., 1993).

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. 2000c. Predictive failure and econometric modelling in macroeconomics: The transactions demand for money. In Econometrics: Alchemy or science? Essays in econometric methodology, ed. D. F. Hendry, new ed., 246–269. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F. 2001d. How economists forecast. In Understanding economic forecasts, ed. D. F. Hendry and N. R. Ericsson, 15–41. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F., and N. R. Ericsson, eds. 2001a. Understanding economic forecasts. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F., and N. R. Ericsson. 2001b. Editor’s introduction. In Understanding economic forecasts, ed. D. F. Hendry and N. R. Ericsson, 1–14. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendry, D. F., and N. R. Ericsson. 2001c. Epilogue. In Understanding economic forecasts, ed. D. F. Hendry and N. R. Ericsson, 185–191. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. 2001. How economics forgot history. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Holden, K. 1989. Macroeconomic forecasting. In Current issues in macroeconomics, ed. D. Greenaway, 163–181. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kacapyr, E. 1996a. Forecasting with time-series techniques. In Economic forecasting, ed. E. ­Kacapyr, 92–115. Armonk: M. E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kacapyr, E. 1996b. Forecasting with econometric models. In Economic forecasting, ed. E. Kacapyr, 116–140. Armonk: M. E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller, E. F. 2003. Models, simulation, and “computer experiments”. In The philosophy of ­scientific experimentation, ed. H. Radder, 198–215. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy, P. 1998. A guide to econometrics. 4th ed. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kock, A. B., and T. Teräsvirta. 2011. Forecasting with nonlinear time series models. In The Oxford handbook of economic forecasting, ed. M. P. Clements and D. F. Hendry, 61–87. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopman, S. J., and M. Ooms. 2011. Forecasting economic time series using unobserved components time series models. In The Oxford handbook of economic forecasting, ed. M. P. Clements and D. F. Hendry, 129–162. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Llewellyn, J., S. Potter, and L. Samuelson. 1985. Economic forecasting and policy-the international dimension. London: Routledge and K. Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mäki, U., ed. 2002. Fact and fiction: Foundational issues on economics and the economy. ­Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Makridakis, S., and M. Hibon. 2000. The M3-competition: Results, conclusions and implications. International Journal of Forecasting 16:451–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makridakis, S., S. C. Wheelwright, and R. J. Hyndman. 1998. Forecasting: Methods and applications. 3rd ed. Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malkiel, B. G. 1996. A random walk to Wall Street. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meadows, D. et al. 1972. The limits of growth. A report for the Club of Rome’s project on its predicament of mankind. New York: Signet/New American Library.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mills, T. C., ed. 1999a. Economic forecasting, vol. I. Cheltenham: E. Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, T. C. ed. 1999b. Economic forecasting, vol. II. Cheltenham: E. Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, T. C. 2002. Forecasting financial variables. In A companion to economic forecasting, ed. M. P. Clemens and D. F. Hendry, 510–538. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, M. S. 2003. Experiments without material intervention. Models experiments, virtual experiments, and virtually experiments. In The philosophy of scientific experimentation, ed. H. Radder, 216–235. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, M. S., and M. Morrison. eds. 1999. Models as mediators. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Newbold, P., and D. I. Harvey. 2002. Forecast combination and encompassing. In A companion to economic forecasting, ed. M. P. Clemens and D. F. Hendry, 268–283. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Önkal-Atay, D., M. E. Thomson, and A. C. Pollock. 2002. Judgmental forecasting. In A companion to economic forecasting, ed. M. Clements and D. F. Hendry, 133–151. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborn, D. R. 2001. Forecasting and the UK business cycle. In Understanding economic forecasts, ed. D. F. Hendry and N. R. Ericsson, 104–123. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagan, A. R. 1990. Three econometric methodologies: A critical appraisal. In Modelling economic series, readings in econometric methodology, ed. C. W. J. Granger, 97–120. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pedregal, D. J., and P. C. Young. 2002. Statistical approaches to modeling and forecasting time series. In A companion to economic forecasting, ed. M. Clements and D. F. Hendry, 69–104. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rescher, N. 1998. Predicting the future: An introduction to the theory of forecasting. Albany: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, A. 1989. Are generic predictions enough? Erkenntnis 30(1–2):43–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, A. 1992. Economics-mathematical politics or science of diminishing returns? Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. 1986. Laboratory experimentation in economics. Economics and Philosophy 2:245–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. 1988. Laboratory experimentation in economics: A methodological overview. The ­Economic Journal 98:974–1031. (Reprinted in Hey, J. D., and G. Loomes, eds. 1993. Recent developments in experimental economics, vol. I, 3–60. Aldershot: E. Elgar).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. 1998. Modeling bounded rationality. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R., and R. Stoecker. 1986. End behavior in sequences of finite prisoner’s dilemma supergames: A learning theory approach. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 7 (1): 47–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. 1982a. Models of bounded rationality, vol. 1: Economic analysis and public policy. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. 1982b. Models of bounded rationality, vol. 2: Behavioral economics and business organization. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. 1996. The sciences of the artificial. 3rd ed. Cambridge: The MIT Press (1st ed., 1969; 2nd ed., 1981).

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. 1997. Models of bounded rationality, vol. 3: Empirically grounded economic reason. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spirtes, P., C. Glymour, and R. Scheines. 1993. Causation, prediction and search. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Turner, P. 2001. Economic modeling for fun and profit. In Understanding economic forecasts, ed. D. F. Hendry and N. R. Ericsson, 42–53. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van den Bogaard, A. 1999. Past measurements and future predictions. In Models as mediators. Perspectives on natural and social science, ed. M. Morgan and M. Morrison, 282–325. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wenceslao J. Gonzalez .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Gonzalez, W. (2015). Methods of Prediction in Economics. In: Philosophico-Methodological Analysis of Prediction and its Role in Economics. Theory and Decision Library A:, vol 50. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-08885-3_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics