Advertisement

Conflict, Commitment and Well-Being

  • Ritxar ArlegiEmail author
  • Miriam Teschl
Chapter
Part of the Happiness Studies Book Series book series (HAPS)

Abstract

There are two important discussions of commitment in economic literature: one is commitment à la Elster and Schelling, which is related to self-binding choices and means that the person has the desire to restrict the future set of options. The other is commitment à la Sen, which implies a different rationality from the standard maximization rationality and means that the person can choose an option which is not necessarily best for her. In this paper, we set out to show that these two discussions of commitment are related. We do so by presenting a theory of choice under motivation conflict , followed by a discussion of the consequences that the reading of commitment through motivation conflict has on well-being.

Keywords

Hyperbolic Discount Motivation Change Goal Motivation Conflictual Action Inconsistent Behavior 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

References

  1. Arlegi, R., & Teschl, M. (2012). Theory of decision under internal conflict. Working papers of the department of economics DT 1208. Public University of Navarre.Google Scholar
  2. Arlegi, R., & Teschl, M. (2013). Commitment as a solution to conflictual choices. Mimeo.Google Scholar
  3. Bandura, A. (1977). Self-efficacy: Toward a unifying theory of behavioral change. Psychological Review, 84(2), 191–215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bazerman, M. H., Tenbrunsel, A. E., & Wade-Benzoni, K. (1998). Negotiating with yourself and losing: Making decisions with competing internal preferences. Academy of Management Review, 23(2), 225–241.Google Scholar
  5. Brim, O. G, Jr, & Kagan, J. (1980). Constancy and change in human development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  6. Cantor, N., Norem, J. K., Brower, A. M., Niedenthal, M., & Langston, C. A. (1987). Life tasks, self-concept ideals, and cognitive strategies in a life transition. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 53(6), 1178–1191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Carver, C. S., & Scheier, M. F. (1990). Origins and functions of positive and negative affect: A control-process view. Psychological Review, 97(1), 19–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Elster, J. (1989). Nuts and bolts. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Elster, J. (2000). Ulysses unbound. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Emmons, R. A., & King, L. A. (1988). Conflict among personal strivings: Immediate and long-term implications for psychological and physical well-being. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 54(6), 1040–1048.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Epstein, S. (1982). Conflict and stress. In L. Goldberger & S. Breznitz (Eds.), Handbook of stress (pp. 49–68). New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  12. Festinger, L. (1957). Theory of cognitive dissonance. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Hausman, D. (2012). Preference, value, choice, and welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  14. Higgins, E. T. (1987). Self-discrepancy: A theory relating self and affect. Psychological Review, 94(3), 319–340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Hofer, M. (2007). Goal conflicts and self-regulation: A new look at pupils off-task behaviour in the classroom. Educational Research Review, 2, 28–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2), 263–292.Google Scholar
  17. Kilian, B., Hofer, M., & Kuhnle, C. (2012). The influence of motivational conflicts on personal values. Journal of Educational Developmental Psychology, 2(1), 57–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Milkman, K. L., Rogers, T., & Bazerman, M. H. (2008). Harnessing our inner angels and demons: What we have learned about want/should conflict and how that Koledge can help us reduce short-sighted decision-making. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 3, 324–338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Mischel, W., Ebbesen, E. B., & Raskoff Zeiss, A. (1972). Cognitive and attentional mechanisms in the delay of gratification. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 21(2), 204218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Pettit, P. (2005). Construing Sen on commitment. Economics and Philosophy, 21, 15–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Ratelle, C. F., Vallerand, R. J., Sencal, C., & Provencher, P. (2005). The relationship between school-leisure conflict and educational and mental health indexes: A motivational analysis. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 35(9), 1800–1823.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Schelling, T. (2006). Strategies of commitment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  23. Sen, A. (1977). Rational fools: A critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory. Philosophy and Public Affairs, 6(4), 317–344.Google Scholar
  24. Sen, A. (1985). Goals, commitment, and identity. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 1(2), 341–355.Google Scholar
  25. Sen, A. (1993). Internal consistency of choice. Econometrica, 61(3), 495–521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Sugden, R. (2004). The opportunity criterion: consumer sovereignty without the assumption of coherent preferences. American Economic Review, 94, 1014–1033.Google Scholar
  27. Turiel, E. (1974). Conflict and transition in adolescent moral development. Child Development, 45(1), 14–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Turiel, E. (1977). Conflict and transition in adolescent moral development, II: The resolution of disequilibrium through structural reorganiszation. Child Development, 48(2), 634–637.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Economics DepartmentPublic University of NavarrePamplonaSpain
  2. 2.Economics DepartmentUniversity of ViennaViennaAustria

Personalised recommendations