Skip to main content

The Emergence and Spread of Coins in China from the Spring and Autumn Period to the Warring States Period

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Explaining Monetary and Financial Innovation

Part of the book series: Financial and Monetary Policy Studies ((FMPS,volume 39))

Abstract

It is widely believed that bronze coins appeared in China during the Spring and Autumn period and that their circulation expanded rapidly during the Warring States period.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In Greece during this period, there existed close to 1,000 polis (Greek city states). Outside the polis were the berber (βάρβαροι, non-Greek) and the xenoi (ξένος, Greeks who were outside the polis’ authority). Inside the polis were citizens, metoicoi (resident foreigners), slaves and women. For example, for Athenians, those who were Greek outside Athens were called xenoi, and those who were non-Athenian in Athens were called metoicoi (μέτοικο). According to Herman, the term xenoi had two meanings, ‘an unacquainted foreigner’ and ‘a visitor, or a foreigner with whom they share mutually hospitable relations’. Since the time of Homer, the term customarily held the latter meaning, in particular amongst the xenia. Xenia was a practice particular to the social elite and referred to the ‘bonds of affection that connected people from a different society or community’. It was a ‘ritualised friendship’ formed with mutual vows, the shaking of hands, favours and appeal. Participants exchanged goods and services with one another and provided mutual assistance. Each polis (e.g. polis A), would select a person from among the foreigners living in a foreign state (e.g. polis B) and call him the proxenos (πρόξεινος). The citizens of polis A would treat him as having relations with all citizens of polis A based on the ritualised friendship, and when citizens of polis A visited polis B, the proxenos was responsible for their care (Herman 1987). The similarities and differences between this special human relationship and the guest culture of ancient China have become points of discussion in our meetings. Certainly, the two are both ‘relationships with foreign companions based upon a custom of reciprocity’ and can be seen to contribute directly and indirectly to the construction of information networks between cities. Also, when the two parties of a xenia relationship came into conflict with the polis to which they belonged, they would agonise about whether they should prioritise their personal relations with the xenia or the profit of various kinds for the polis. This debate was the same for the guests of state in China. For example, at the end of the Warring States period, Hán Fēi (韓非), one of the Han royalty viewed as an excellent lawyer, was in the Qin as a guest, but the Qin king feared that Hán Fēi would ultimately submit policies to profit the Han. Because of this, the Qin killed Hán Fēi. The Qin king later attempted to promulgate the order for guests to leave (逐客令) because of the likelihood that guests would place greater importance upon their native state’s profit. However, in contrast to the xenoi who resided in the foreign state, the guests stayed only temporarily in the state. Also, in contrast to the xenia relationships being affectionate, based on one-to-one meetings, many guests in the political field gathered around the high prestige and economic power possessed by a lord, and thus, if the lord lost his prestige or political power through morally deviant acts, the guests suddenly took flight to distance themselves from the lord. For example, when Mèngcháng jūn (孟嘗君) was the prime minister of Qi, he hosted as many as 3,000 guests, but attracted the envy of the king. After being stripped of his rank, Mèngcháng jūn’s guests disappeared Afterwards, due to the great efforts of Féng Huān (馮驩), one of Mèngcháng jūn’s guests, he was reinstated as prime minister, and once again 3,000 guests gathered in his halls. Mèngcháng jūn meant to scold his guests, but Féng Fuān stated: ‘It is natural that those with wealth and rank will have many followers and that the poor will have few. It is natural too that when you lost your rank, your esteemed guests took their leave. Therefore, it would do no good to resent your guests or reject them in vain’ (see Record of Mèngcháng jūn). This differs from the xenia. However, on the other hand, there also existed during the Spring and Autumn and the Warring States periods the principle of communication known as Rènxiá (任侠), chivalry. This required that ‘civilians depend upon their own swords, set up groups, adhere to the groups staking their lives in a single pledge, and, especially, endeavour to save their friends and family irrespective of life, death, and personal interests’. These requirements sometimes encompassed unlawful acts. This mindset is what underlies at least a part of modern gangs, the mafia and the yakuza, but in the Spring and Autumn and the Warring States periods, many possessed this mindset (Miyazaki 1934; Masubuchi 1996). That is not to say it was a value supported by everybody at the time, but rather that it was one principle of communication alongside family, rank and money. This value’s importance depended upon the person, but those who made little of the traditional clan system in ancient China looked upon chivalry as important (Kakinuma 2011). Among the Chinese guests of state, too, there were many who viewed this ethos as important. For example, the abovementioned Féng Huān assisted Mèngcháng jūn, who had lost his title and all of his guests. For doing so, Féng Huān gained favour. In the Spring and Autumn and the Warring States periods, many assassins, starting out as guests of state, tried to attain retribution for their murdered lords (see Record of Assassins in Shiji). This kind of human relationship rooted in chivalry also involved foreigners. For example, in the last years of the Spring and Autumn period, the son of Fàn Lí (范蠡) of Yue was deemed a criminal in the Chu. Fàn Lí sent a dispatch to his old friend, Zhuāng Shēng (荘生) of the Chu, and a large sum of money. Zhuāng Shēng, not touching the money, decided to secretly save his friend’s son without compensation. Fànlí had known that Zhuāng Shēng did not want his money, but Fàn Lí’s emissary had doubted Zhuāng Shēng. When Zhuāng Shēng found out, he refused to save Fàn Lí’s son (see Biography of the Yue). This indicates that a chivalrous relationship existed between Fàn Lí and Zhuāng Shēng. This story has a strong legendary element, and there are doubts about whether the incident actually occurred in the Spring and Autumn period. Yet, because it is recorded in the Han dynasty’s Shiji and there were probably other original sources before the Han period, it is certain that the story and its contents were viewed as important from the Warring States period to the Han period. This was an interpersonal relationship similar to xenia and, in this, there can be seen a resemblance between China and Greece. At the very least, chivalry differed from xenia in that (1) it was not limited to foreigners; (2) it encompassed a mindset powerful enough that people would stake their lives; and (3) those involved were inclined to refuse an exchange of money. Please refer to Schap’s paper for more information regarding the xenia.

References

  • Adachi, K. (1990). Sensei Kokka to Zaisei & Kahei. In Minshin Chūgoku no Keizai Kōzō (pp. 345–73). Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin, 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aglietta, M., & Orléan, A. (Eds.). (1998). La Monnaie Souveraine. Paris: Odile Jacob.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for lemons: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benveniste, È. (1969). Le Vocabulaire des Institutions Indo-Européennes, 1, Economie, Parenté, Société. Paris: Èditions de Minuit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chén, W. (1996). Bāoshān Chŭjiàn Chūtàn. Wŭhàn: Wŭhàn Dàxué Chūbǎnshè.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, R. M. (1958). Speculation on the origins of coinage. Historia, 7, 257–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, M. H. (1970). Money and exchange in the Roman world. Journal of Roman Studies, 60, 40–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Montesquieu, C.-L. (1748/1989). The spirit of the laws. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dèng, C. (1994). Xiānggǎng Dàwān Chūtŭ Shāngdài Yázhāngchuàn Chūlùn. Wénwù, 12, 54–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emura, H. (2000). Syunju Sengoku Shinkan Jidai Shutudo Moji Shiryo no Kenkyū. Tokyo: Kyūko-Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emura, H. (2011). Syunju Sengoku Jidai Seido Kahei no Seisei to Tenkai. Tokyo: Kyūko-Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, T. (1996). Shinkan bakkin Kō. In Umehara, K. (Ed.), Zenkindai Chūgoku no Keibatsu. Kyoto: Kyoto Daigaku Jinbun Kagaku Kenkyūjo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, K. (2005). Chūgoku Kodai Kokka to Gunkensei. Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fukuda, T. (1889). Fukujo to Kahei no Kankei ni tsukiteno Gukō. Kokka Gakkai Zasshi, 24(7), 89–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fukui, S. (2005). Kandai Jukyō no Shiteki Kenkyū. Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, H. E. (1940). The use of cowries as money during the Shang and Chou periods. Journal of the Northern China Branch of the Royal Asiatic Society, 71, 33–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gù, J., & Shǐ, N. (Eds.). (1938). Zhōngguó Jiāngyù Yángéshǐ. Chángshā: Shāngwùyìn Shūguǎn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamada, K. (1912). Shina Kodai no Baika ni tsuite. In The collection of Hamada Kosaku , 3, Kyoto: Dōhōsha, 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hara, M. (1994). Kodai Chūgoku no Kaihatsu to Kankyō: ‘Kanshi” Chiyin-Hen Kenkyū. Tokyo: Kenbun Shuppan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hara, M. (2004). Sengoku En no Kankyō to “Ryōiki Kokka” Gainen & Sobyō. Kumatsushū, 11, 285–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hara, M. (2005). “Nōhon” Shugi to ‘Kōdo” no Hassei. Tokyo: Kenbun Shuppan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hashimoto, A. (2006). Sengoku Cho no “Kohuku Kisha”. Nagoya Daigaku Tōyōshi Kenkyū Hōkoku, 30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1976). The denationalization of money: The argument refined—an analysis of the theory and practice of concurrent currencies. London: The Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herman, G. (1987). Ritualised friendship and the Greek city. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1967). Critical essays in monetary theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirao, Y. (2001). Kodai Higashi Asia Seido no Ryūtsū. Tokyo: Tsuruyama-Dō.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty: Responses to decline in firms, organizations, and states. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hisamura, Y. (1956). So & Shin no Kanchugun ni tsuite. Shigaku Zasshi, 65(9), 46–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huáng, X. (2001). Xiānqín Huòbì Tōnglùn. Bĕijīng: Zǐjīnchéng.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. (1742). Of the Rise and Progress of the Arts and Sciences. Reprinted in Haakonssen, K. (Ed.), David Hume: Political essays (pp. 58–77). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inaba, I. (2007). Nangun no Kensetsu to Sengoku Shin no Kahei Seido. Shirin, 90(2), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kageyama, T. (1984). Chūgoku Kodai no Shōkōgyō to Senbaisei. Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakinuma, Y. (2009). Gokan Jidai ni okeru Kahei Keizai no Tenkai to Sono Tokushitsu. Shiteki, 31, 64–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakinuma, Y. (2010a). Shindai Kahei Keizai no Kōzō to Sono Tokushitsu. Tōhōgaku, 120, 18–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakinuma, Y. (2010b). Sangoku Jidai no Sōgi ni okeru Zeisei Kaikaku to Kahei Keizai no Shitsuteki Henka. Tōyō Gakuhō, 3, 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakinuma, Y. (2011). Chūgoku Kodai Kahei Keizaishi Kenkyū. Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakinuma, Y. (2012). Shŭhàn de Jūnshì Zuìyōuxiānxíng Jīngjì Tǐxì. Shǐxué Yuèkān, 9, 28–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kakinuma, Y. (2013). Sengoku Chō Bureio no Shokaikaku. Nihon Shinkanshi Kenkyu, 13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kant, I. (1784). Idea of a universal history from a cosmopolitan point of view. In P. Gardiner (Ed.), Theories of history (pp. 22–34). New York: Free Press, 1959.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katō, S. (1926). Tōsō Jidai ni Okeru Kingin no Kenkyū. Tokyo: Tōyō Bunko.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, B.-J. (1997). Jungguk Godae Jiyeok Munhwa Wa Gunhyon Jibae. Seoul: Iijogak.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kimura, M. (1955). Chūgoku Kodai Kaheisei. Tōyō Shigaku Kenkyū, 4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraay, C. M. (1964). Hoards, small change and the origin of coinage. Journal of Hellenic Studies, 84, 76–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kudo, M. (2006). Shin no Hashoku Shihai to Hōsei and Gunkensei. Asia Chi’iki Bunkagaku No Kōchiku: 21 Century COE Programme Kenkyū Shūsei (pp. 24–52). Tokyo: Yuzankaku.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuroda, A. (2003). Kahei System no Sekaishi: ‘Hi Taishōsei” wo Yomu. Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuroda, A. (2008). What is the complementarity among monies? An introductory note. Financial History Review, 15, 7–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lasch, C. (1995). The revolt of the elites and the betrayal of democracy. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laum, B. (1924). Heiliges Geld. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lévi-Strauss, C. (1962). La Pensée Sauvage. Paris: Librairie Plon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, F. (2006). Landscape and power in early China: The crisis and fall of the Western Zhou 1045-771BC. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lù, H. (1986). Zhànguó Shíqī Zhōngshān de Jiāotōng. Hébĕi Xuékān, 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lǚ, C., & Méi, L. (1994). Ānhuī Féixīxiàn Xīncāngxiāng Chūtŭ Yǐbíqián. Zhōngguó Qiánbì, 3, 45–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucassen, J. (Ed.). (2007). Wages and currency: Global comparisons from antiquity to the twentieth century. Bern: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mǎ, F. (Ed.). (1988). Zhōngguó Lìdài Huòbì Dàxì: Xiānqín Huòbì. Shànghǎi: Shànghǎi Rénmín Chūbǎn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mǎ, F. (Ed.). (2002). Zhōngguó Lìdài Huòbì Dàxì 2: Qínhàn Sānguó Liǎngjìn Nánbĕicháo Huòbì. Shànghǎi: Shànghǎi Císhū Chūbǎn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Makino, T. (1950). Chūgoku Kodai no Kazoku ha Keizaiteki Jikyu Jisokutai ni Arazu: Chūgoku Kodai Kahei Keizai no Hatten. In The collection of Makino, Tatsumi, 6: Chūgoku Shakaishi No Shomondai. Tokyo: Ochanomizu-Shobō, 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1872). Das Kapital. In Karl Marx—Friedrich Engels Werke (4th ed., Vol. 23). Berlin: Dietz, 1961.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masubuchi, T. (1996). Chūgoku Kodai no Shakai to Kokka. Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten. (New Edition).

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsui, Y. (1995). ‘‘Ōke” to Sai’. In Shūdai Kokusei no Kenkyū (pp. 94–121). Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsumaru, M. (1963). Inkyo Bokujichū no Denryōchi ni tsuite: Indai Kokka Kōzō Kenkyū no tameni. Tōyō Bunka Kenkyūjo Kiyō, 31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsumaru, M. (1992). Seishū Jidai No Jūryō Tan’i. Asia No Bunka To Shakai, 2. Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsumaru, M. (2001). Yin Shū Shunjushi Sōsetsu. Yin Shū Shinkan Jidaishi no Kihon Mondai. Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. (1923). Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftlehre (2nd ed.). Wien: Holder Pichler Tempsky.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyake, K. (2006). Kansho no Nijuttō shakusei: Seidoshi teki Kōshō. In Chūgoku Kodai Keiseishi no Kenkyū (pp. 309–346). Kyoto: Kyoto Daigaku Gakujutsu Shuppankai, 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki, I. (1934). Yūkyo ni tsuite. In The collection of Miyazaki, Ichisada, 5 (pp. 267–284). Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki, I. (1940). Ko no Kigen ni tsuite. In The collection of Miyazaki, Ichisada, 5 (pp. 264–325). Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten, 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki, I. (1962). Sengoku Jidai no Toshi. In The collection of Miyazaki, Ichisada, 3 (pp. 164–181). Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten, 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki, I. (1964). Rikuchō zuitō no Shakai’. In The collection of Miyazaki, Ichisada, 7 (pp. 119–132). Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten, 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  • Momiyama, A. (1985). Shakuseiron no Saikentō. Atarashī Rekishigaku no Tameni, 187, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Momiyama, A. (1995). Kotei Shihai no Genzo: Minshaku Shiyo wo tegakarini. In M. Matsubara (Ed.), Oken no Isō (pp. 354–376). Tokyo: Kobundo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nishijima, S. (1961). Chūgoku Kodai Teikoku no Keisei to Kozo. Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Syuppankai.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogura, Y. (2003). Saden ni okeru Ro ni tsuite. In The collection of Ogura Yoshihiko, 3, Tokyo: Ronsōsha.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ōta, Y. (2007). Chūgoku Kodai Kokka Keisei Shiron. Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peng, K. (2000). Coinage and commercial development in Eastern Zhou China (Ph.D. Dissertation). The University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quán, H. (1941). Zhōngguó Zìrán Jīngjì. In Zhōngguó Jīngjìshǐ Yánjiū, 1, Taipei: Dàoxiāng, 1980.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (2003). Saving capitalism from the capitalists: Unleashing the power of financial markets to create wealth and spread opportunity. New York: Crown Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawson, J. (1989). Statesmen or barbarians? The Western Zhou as seen through their Bronzes. Proceedings of the British Academy, 75, 71–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawson, J. (1999) Western Zhou archaeology. In M. Loewe, E. Shaughnessy (Eds.), The Cambridge history of ancient China: From the origins of civilization to 221 B.C. (pp. 352–449). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schaps, D. M. (2007). The invention of coinage in Lydia, in India, and in China. Bulletin de Cercle d’Etudes Numismatiques, 44(3), 281–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W. (2009). The monetary systems of the Han and Roman empires. In W. Scheidel (Ed.), Rome and China: Comparative perspectives on ancient world empires. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1949). Theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sekino, T. (1962). Senshin Kahei Zakko. In Chūgoku Kokogaku Ronko (pp. 55–102). Tokyo: Doseisha, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shí, Y. & Wáng, S. (1987). ‘‘Jiānshŏudāo” Huà de Chūbù Yánjiū’. Kǎogŭ yŭ Wénwù, 1, 82–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shimoda, M. (2008). Chūgoku Kodai Kokka no Keisei to Seido Heiki. Tokyo: Kyūko Shoin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shirakawa, S. (1955). Sakusatsu Ko. In The collection of Shirakawa Shizuka: Bekkan Kokotsu Kinbungaku Ronso. Tokyo: Heibonsha, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silber, W. L. (1983). The process of financial innovation. The American Economic Review, 73(2), 89–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, W. G. (1964/1965). Marketing and social structure in rural China. Journal of Asian Studies, 24 (1–3).

    Google Scholar 

  • Tierry, F. (1997). Monnaies Chinoises, I: L’antiquite Preimperiale. Paris: Bibliothèque Nationale de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomiya, I. (1998). Shinkan Keibatsu Seido no Kenkyū. Kyoto: Dōhōsha.

    Google Scholar 

  • Utsunomiya, K. (1950). Seikan Jidai no Toshi. In Kandai Shakai Keizaishi Kenkyū (2nd ed., pp. 107–140). Tokyo: Kōbundō Shobō, 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaubel, R. (1977). Free currency competition. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 113(3), 435–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Falkenhausen, L. (1997). Yŏuguān Xīzhōu Wǎnqī Lǐzhì Gǎigé jí Zhuāngbái Wēishì Qīngtóng Qìniándài Xīnjiǎshuō: Cóng Shìxì Míngwén Shuōqǐ. Zhōngguó Kǎogŭxué yŭ Lìshǐxué zhī Zhĕnghé Yánjiū (pp. 651–675). Taipei: Academia Sinica.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Glahn, R. (1996). Fountain of fortune: Money and monetary policy in China, 1000–1700. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wáng, G. (1921). Shuō Juépéng. In Guāntáng Jílín. Bĕijīng: Zhōnghuá Shūjú.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wáng, X. (1979). Zhōngguó Gŭdài Huòbì Tōngkǎo. Jǐnán: Qílŭ Shūshè.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wáng, J. (1998). Jiānshŏudāo Fēnqī Yánjiū. Bĕijīng Wénbó, 3, 17–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamada, K. (2000). Kahei no Chūgoku Kodaishi. Tokyo: Asahi Shinbunsha.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yáng, S. (2003). Bèi Shì Shāngdài de Huòbì. Zhōngguóshǐ Yánjiū, 1, 29–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoshida, T. (1933). Shina Kahei Kenkyū. Tokyo: Tō’a Keizaishi Kenkyūkai.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoshimoto, M. (1991). Seishū Kōhanki no Shū’ōchō: Sakumei Kinbun no Bunseki. In Chūgoku Senshinshi no Kenkyū. Kyoto: Kyoto Daigaku Shuppankai, 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoshimoto, M. (1997). Mōshi Syokō: Sengoku Chuki no Kokka to Shakai. Ritumeikan Bungaku, 551, 257–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yúnmèng Shuìhŭdì Qínmù Biānxiĕzŭ. (1981). Yúnmèng Shuìhŭdì Qínmù. Bĕijīng: Wénwù Chūbănshè.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zelizer, V. A. (1994). The social meaning of money. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhāng, C. (1997). Zhōngguó Dāobì Rénmín Huìkĭo. Shíjiāzhuāng: Hébĕi Rénmín Chūbănshè.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhào, D. X. (1996). Chŭguó de Huòbì. Shíjiāzhuāng. Jiàoyù Chūbănshè: Húbĕi.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhèng, J. (1958). Zhōngguó Gŭdài Huòbì Fāzhănshĭ. Bĕijīng: Shēnghuó, Dúshū, and Xīnzhī Sānlián Shūdiàn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhōu, N. (1979). Zhōngshānguó de Yùqì. Gùgōng Bówùyuàn Yuànkān, 2, 95–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhū, H. (1984). Gŭqián Xīntàn. Jŭnán: Qílŭ Shūshè.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yohei Kakinuma .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kakinuma, Y. (2014). The Emergence and Spread of Coins in China from the Spring and Autumn Period to the Warring States Period. In: Bernholz, P., Vaubel, R. (eds) Explaining Monetary and Financial Innovation. Financial and Monetary Policy Studies, vol 39. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-06109-2_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics