Skip to main content

The Political Economy of Monetary and Financial Innovation: Introduction and Overview

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1419 Accesses

Part of the book series: Financial and Monetary Policy Studies ((FMPS,volume 39))

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a history of thought on inter-governmental competition see Vaubel (2008).

  2. 2.

    Cf. Rajan and Zingales (2003).

  3. 3.

    The literature on financial innovation (e.g. Silber 1975: 62) distinguishes between innovation under distress and innovation due to success and slack. In the first case, firms are faced with adversity and innovate under pressure. In the second case, firms have been so successful that they can afford to play and experiment.

  4. 4.

    In a modern context see Rogoff (1985).

  5. 5.

    For a recent assessment of this view see Goodhart (1998).

  6. 6.

    For the same reason, we doubt the view reported and endorsed by Yohei Kakinuma that “the purpose of Lydian coinage was the payment of mercenaries” and that “the use of early coins as a medium of exchange was an accidental consequence of coinage, and not the reason for coins themselves” (p. “15”).

  7. 7.

    This has also been emphasized by Merkelbach (1992: 15): “Imagine that a Phoenician proficient in writing had sailed to Greece in 800 BC and that, after returning, he had been asked about his impressions of the Greeks. Presumably he would have answered: They live at the fringe of the civilized world and do not know any luxuries and refinements of life; they lie in a deep sleep and can only be pitied. Only two hundred years later a descendant of our Phoenician would have told quite a different story about Greece: The whole country is moving; Greek ships are cruising from the Black Sea to Spain; everywhere they open new cities and trading posts; their goods are modern and attractive; they are building temples of stone and put up statues of a kind which we have never seen before; their paintings show an incredible dynamic; they celebrate spectacular sportive events and perform music never heard before. No other land in the world can compare itself to Greece. How did this miracle come about? … I have the following explanation for this miraculous development of Greece. The Greeks were the first to develop the following two cultural inventions: alphabetical writing and the use of minted money. These two developments together have brought about such an advance as has probably never again occurred in the history of mankind” (p. 15, our translation).

  8. 8.

    We also find this hypothesis in Howgego (1995: 16): “The cultural background to the spread of coinage was a Greek world in which peer polity interaction operated both unconsciously and through deliberate competition…”.

  9. 9.

    Schaps argues that coinage did not make much impact on or penetrate deeply into the economies of the Near Eastern inland because the dynasts of the Persian Empire were entrenched and did not, for the most part, owe their power or wealth to money.

  10. 10.

    “The Greek mercenaries hired by the Persian king were the only dangerous opponents of the Macedonian-Greek army. The Great King owned incredible amounts of gold and silver received as a tribute from the subjugated peoples. But he hoarded the metal and did not mint it into coins and to be used as money. He had the supplied metal melted and cast into big clay (earthenware) jugs. When it had cooled, the clay hull was smashed and the lump of silver put into the treasury. If the Persian king needed silver, he had it chopped from these lumps.

    When Alexander conquered the capital Persepolis, the whole treasure fell into his victorious hands. If the Persian king had minted the metal into coins and had hired a threefold number of Greek mercenaries, everything would have taken another course. But the Persians had only changed in a very limited way from a barter to a monetary economy; they had not yet understood that coined money is a first-rate source of power and may decide wars if used for soldiers” (p. 28, our translation).

  11. 11.

    See, e.g., Ferguson (2008: 52): “Significantly, even as Italian banking techniques were being improved in the financial centres of Northern Europe, one country lagged unexpectedly far behind. Cursed with an abundance of precious metal, Spain failed to develop a sophisticated banking system, relying instead on the merchants of Antwerp for short-term cash advances against future silver deliveries”. Denzel agrees that the imports of metal from America diminished the willingness to innovate in Spain and Portugal.

References

  • Bogaert, R. (1994). Recherches sur la banque en Egypt Greco-romaine. In R. Bogaert (Ed.), Trapezitica Aegyptiaca, Papyrologica Fiorentina (pp. 1–24). Firenze: Edizioni Connelli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, N. (2008). The ascent of money. New York: The Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C. (1998). The two concepts of money. European Journal of Political Economy, 2, 239–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1968). Competition as a discovery procedure. In C. Nishiyama & K. R. Leube (Eds.), The essence of Hayek (pp. 254–265). Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howgego, C. (1995). Ancient history from coins. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. (1742/1985). Of the rise and progress in the arts and sciences. In E. F. Miller (Ed.), David Hume: Essays, moral, political and literary (pp. 111–137). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kant, I. (1784/1959) Idea of a universal history from a cosmopolitan point of view. In P. Gardiner (Ed.), Theories of history (pp. 22–34). New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knapp, G. F. (1905). Die Staatliche Theorie des Geldes. Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger, C. (1892). On the origins of money. Economic Journal, 2, 239–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merkelbach, R. (1992). Die Bedeutung des Geldes für die Geschichte der griechisch-römischen Welt. Leipzig: B.G. Teubner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (1990). The lever of riches. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesquieu, Charles Louis de Secondat (1748/1989) The spirit of the laws. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morcillo, M. G. (2008) Auctions, bankers and public finances in the Roman world. In K. Verboven, K. Vandorpe, & V. Chankowski (Eds.), Pistoi dia ten technen. Bankers, loans and archives in the ancient world (pp. 257–276). Studies in honour of Raymond Bogaert. Leuven: Peeters.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popper, K. (1945). The open society and its enemies (Vol. 1). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (2003). The great reversals: The politics of financial development in the twentieth century. Journal of Financial Economics, 69, 5–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rathbone, D., & Temin, P. (2008). Financial intermediation in first century AD Rome and eighteenth-century England. In K. Verboven, K. Vandorpe, & V. Chankowski (Eds.), Pistoi dia ten technen. Bankers, loans and archives in the ancient world (pp. 371–419). Studies in honour of Raymond Bogaert. Leuven: Peeters.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. S. (1985). Can international monetary cooperation be counterproductive? Journal of International Economics, 18, 199–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silber, W. L. (1975). Toward a theory of financial innovation. In W. L. Silber (Ed.), Financial innovation (pp. 53–86). D.C. Heath & Co.: Lexington, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaubel, R. (2008). A history of thought on institutional competition. In A. Bergh & R. Høijer (Eds.), Institutional competition (pp. 29–66). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Bernholz .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bernholz, P., Vaubel, R. (2014). The Political Economy of Monetary and Financial Innovation: Introduction and Overview. In: Bernholz, P., Vaubel, R. (eds) Explaining Monetary and Financial Innovation. Financial and Monetary Policy Studies, vol 39. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-06109-2_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics