1 Introduction

‘Prior to 1800, living standards in world economies were roughly constant over the very long run: per capita wage income, output, and consumption did not grow’ asserted Gary Hansen and Edward Prescott two decades ago.Footnote 1 This stylised fact has spread among economists in more simplified terms: income per person remained stagnant in human societies until the Industrial Revolution heralded the beginning of modern economic growth. The Unified Growth Theory’s depiction of preindustrial societies as Malthusian has reinforced this perception (Galor and Weil, 2000).Footnote 2

Although the Malthusian depiction of preindustrial economies enjoys the support of distinguished scholars (cf. Clark, 2007, 2008; Madsen et al., 2019), it has recently been challenged by research in economic history. Historians are now more prone to accept a transcending of the Malthusian constraint in preindustrial Western Europe, as capital accumulation and productivity gains permitted, simultaneously, higher population and income levels, but with the caveat that such achievements were limited in scope and time (i.e. after the Black Death), and only had long term effects in the North Sea Area (Pamuk, 2007). Broadberry et al.’s (2015) ground-breaking research, for example, rejects the use of the term Malthusian to portray the early modern British economy. However, Voigtländer and Voth (2013) claim that, in north-western Europe, the Black Death brought with it an increase in the endowment of land and capital per survivor, which resulted in higher output per head within a Malthusian framework.

In an attempt to break the growth-stagnation dichotomy in preindustrial societies, historians have highlighted ‘efflorescences’ (Goldstone, 2002: 333) and ‘growth recurring’ episodes (Jones, 1988; Jerven, 2011) that feature a succession of phases of growing and shrinking output per head and only give way to modern economic growth when shrinking phases become less intense and frequent (Broadberry and Wallis, 2017). Growth driven by gains from specialisation resulting from the expansion of international and domestic markets (the so-called Smithian growth) may explain these episodes of sustained but reversible per capita income gains.

Did Smithian growth episodes take place in preindustrial Europe beyond the North Sea Area? New research suggests that they did in Iberia (Palma and Reis, 2019; Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura, 2013), although qualitative perceptions of early modern Spain as a stagnant economy are deeply rooted (Kamen, 1978: 49; Cipolla, 1980: 250).

In this chapter, new yearly estimates of Spanish output and population for more than half a millennium are provided, which revise and improve on previous estimates. The new evidence offers empirical grounds to discuss the extent to which Malthusian efflorescences, recurring growth, or Smithian growth are defining elements of preindustrial Spain.

The chapter makes some methodological contributions to the literature on historical national accounts. It includes controlled conjectures on population and sectoral and aggregate output estimates. More specifically, it provides the first agricultural output estimates from the supply side, on the basis of a religious tax, the tithe, incurred by total production, for over 400 years, which are compared to estimates derived with a demand function for the entire time span considered by Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013). Their levels and long-run trends are rather similar, even though some significant discrepancies emerge at specific junctures. This result supports the use of the indirect demand approach to deduce trends in agricultural output.

The chapter is structured as follows. In Sect. 2.2, we construct quantitative conjectures about the population. Agricultural output is estimated, and output per head compared to earlier estimates derived with a demand approach in Sect. 2.3. Urban population estimates, adjusted to exclude those living from agriculture, are used in Sect. 2.4 to proxy trends in economic activity outside agriculture. Section 2.5 constructs aggregate output (total and per capita) estimates on the basis of the results obtained in previous sections and draws their long-run trends. In Sect. 2.6, these findings are discussed in the context of the historical debate and some conclusions extracted with regard to secular stagnation, the Malthusian model, and income distribution in preindustrial societies. Section 2.7 provides a long view of Spain’s performance in European perspective. Section 2.8 concludes.

The findings can be summarised as follows: (1) The peak average income levels reached in the late 1330s and the 1560s were only surpassed in the early nineteenth century. (2) However, preindustrial Spain’s economy was far from stagnant, exhibiting long phases of output per head growth and contraction. (3) Population and output per head moved together, at odds with the Malthusian narrative and supporting the hypothesis of Spain as a frontier economy. (4) Spain’s performance suggests Smithian growth episodes during distinctive phases: the long rise up to the Black Death, the century-long expansion up to 1570, and the sustained expansion of the eighteenth century, as larger markets favoured specialization and urbanisation. (5) Income appears less unequally distributed until the early sixteenth century and increasingly more unequally thereafter, as the relative importance of crops increased.

From these results, a puzzling question emerges: why were no significant long-run gains in living standards achieved in Spain’s frontier economy? In the absence of a persuasive Malthusian interpretation, an institutional explanation merits exploration.

2 Quantitative Conjectures on Population

Aggregate population figures for late medieval and early modern Spain consist of scattered benchmark estimates from household population surveys usually collected for taxation purposes—the so-called vecindarios (literally, neighbourhoods), that present the challenge of converting households into inhabitants-, national censuses for the late eighteenth century, and sporadic assessments for the early nineteenth century.Footnote 3 Available benchmark estimates allow us to derive long run population trends, and historians have relied on baptism records to represent population dynamics.Footnote 4

Baptism data are available from 1580 to the Peninsular War, and most regions are covered from 1700 onwards. Thus, total Spanish population can be derived by weighting each regional index by the regions’ population in a benchmark year (See Appendix A.1, Population, Estimate 1, and Fig. 2.14). However, inferring population trends from baptisms implies assuming that deaths rates maintained a stable short-term relationship with birth ratesFootnote 5 and that net migration flows were negligible over time.Footnote 6

Álvarez-Nogal et al. (2016) attempted to reconcile population benchmarks with decadal estimates of baptisms, available since the 1520s, so the resulting estimates capture migration (forced or voluntary) and over time variations in the proportion between birth and death rates (and between births and baptised children) (Appendix, A.1 Population, Estimate 1). Unfortunately, projecting a population benchmark with baptism indices is misleading, since population is a stock variable while baptism series, as a proxy for births, represent a flow. In fact, using baptisms as measure of population amounts to proxy capital stock by investment.

Ideally, to reconstruct annual population figures we require a reliable population figure at the beginning of a benchmark year (Nt) annually adding the natural increase in population, that is, births (bt) less deaths (dt), less net emigration (mt). Thus,

$$ {N}_{t+1}={N}_t+{b}_t-{d}_t-{m}_t $$
(2.1)

As there are population estimates available at various benchmarks (see Appendix, A.1 Population), all we need, then, is data on the natural increase in population (births less deaths) and net migration.

On migration, no yearly data are available and only guesstimates can be proposed. As regards emigration to the Americas, we have relied on Morner (1975: 64) who provides aggregate estimates for five periods over 1506–1670 (1506–1540, 1541–1560, 1561–1600, 1601–1625, 1626–1650) and has distributed them annually within each period.Footnote 7 We also allowed for the outflow of Moorish population after their expulsion, which Pérez Moreda (1988: 380), estimates to be, at least, 0.3 million. Thus, we have added a figure of 60,000 emigrants for each year between 1609 and 1613 inclusively. Estimates from 1670 onwards come from Martínez Shaw (1994: 151, 167, 249) for the periods 1670–1700, 1700–1800, 1800–1830, and 1830–1850, and have been distributed annually. As regards immigration, a figure around 0.2 million has been estimated for the sixteenth century, mostly French moving to Catalonia (Pérez Moreda, 1988: 374), which we have distributed, assuming a steady inflow of 2000 people per year.

We lack yearly crude birth (cbr) and death (cdr) rates for Spain prior to the 1850s, and although baptisms would roughly amount to b in expression (2.1), that is, cbr times population at the beginning of the year, assuming a fixed cdr, or a fixed cbr/cdr ratio, is unacceptable, as crude birth and death rates fluctuate widely in the short run, and even more so at times of pandemics. Fortunately, David Reher (1991) computed yearly crude birth and death rates for New Castile since 1565 (Appendix, Fig. 2.15). Hence, a possible provision of plausible conjectures on annual population levels consists of constructing alternative population estimates in which each population benchmark (Nbk) is projected forwards by adding the annual natural increase in population derived from yearly crude birth and death rates for New Castile (cbrnct and cdrnct), less net emigration (mt) guesstimates. This is the procedure to adopt when we move forward (that is, when starting from, say, 1787, we want to estimate population in 1788), while we need to subtract the natural increase in population and to add net emigration in the previous year when we project population backwards (namely, when starting from 1787 we want to compute population in 1786).Footnote 8 That is,

$$ {N}_{t+1}={N}_{bk}+{\left( cb{r}_{nct}- cd{r}_{nct}\right)}_{\ast }{N}_{bk}-{m}_{t\kern0.75em }\kern1em \mathrm{for}\;t> bk $$
(2.2)
$$ {N}_{t-1}={N}_{bk-}{\left( cb{r}_{nct-1-} cd{r}_{nct-1}\right)}_{\ast }{N}_{bk}+{m}_{t-1}\kern2.25em \mathrm{for}\;t< bk $$
(2.3)

Accepting crude birth and death rates from New Castile implicitly assumes that they are representative for the whole of Spain. Nonetheless, the crude death rate for New Castile matches the main famine mortality episodes not only for inland Spain, but for Spain as a whole.Footnote 9 However, such an arbitrary and unrealistic assumption is largely relaxed by the procedure we propose to reconcile the resulting series. In fact, the exercise suggested by expressions (2.2) and (2.3) provides a set of population series, one for each benchmark, that do not match each other for the years in which they overlap (Appendix, Fig. 2.16). Therefore, we need to carry out a reconciliation between these alternative estimates.

A solution is to interpolate the series, accepting the levels for each benchmark-year as the best possible estimates and distributing the gap or difference between adjacent benchmark series (say, series obtained by projecting the 1752 benchmark forward, N1752t, and the 1787 benchmark backwards, N1787t) in the overlapping year T at a constant rate over the time span in between the two benchmark years.

$$ {N^I}_{t=}{N}_{1752t\ast }{\left[{\left({N}_{1787T}/{N}_{1752T}\right)}^{1/n}\right]}^t\kern3.5em \mathrm{for}\ 0\le t\le T. $$
(2.4)

NI being the linearly interpolated new series, N1787t and N1752t the series pertaining to population obtained by projecting two adjacent population benchmarks (i.e. 1752 and 1787) with expressions (2.2) and (2.3), respectively; t, the year considered; T, the overlapping year between the two benchmarks series (say, 1787); and n, the number of years in between the two benchmark dates (that is, 35 years, 1787 less 1752, in our example).Footnote 10

Figure 2.1 presents the compromise estimate along the decadal-adjusted series and the benchmarks interpolation. The comparison reveals that the main discrepancies correspond to the pre-1700 period, and while the decadal-adjusted series peaks in the 1580, the compromise series continues expanding during the first quarter of the seventeenth century, and declines thereafter, especially, in the second half of the seventeenth century, with deep contractions in the late 1640s-early 1650s and in the mid-1680s. Furthermore, the compromise series departs from the other two in the early nineteenth century as it captures the impact of the demographic crisis in the early 1800s and during the Peninsular War.

Fig. 2.1
A multiline graph plots 3 lines for compromise, decadal adjusted baptisms-based, and benchmark interpolation. All lines partially overlap and follow ascending trends, between 3.5 and 14.5 on the y-axis and 1400 and 1844 on the x-axis. Values are estimated.

Population: Benchmarks interpolation, decadal adjusted baptisms-based, and compromise estimates, 1400–1850 (million)

In Fig. 2.2, we present our conjectures with regard to the evolution of Spanish population that combines the compromise series since 1565 with the annual population figures obtained through the decadal adjustment (with baptism data) of the benchmarks interpolated series for the period 1520–1565, and the benchmarks interpolated series for the pre-1520 period.

Fig. 2.2
A multiline graph has 3 lines for compromise, decadal adjusted baptisms-based, and benchmark interpolation. All lines follow ascending trends with fluctuations, between 3.5 and 14.7 on the y-axis and 1277 and 1847 on the x-axis. Compromise has the highest peak of (1847, 14.7). Values are estimated.

Population conjectures, 1277–1850 (million) (natural logs)

3 Agricultural Output

In pre-industrial Europe, lack of data has led to indirect estimation of agricultural output (Wrigley, 1985; Malanima, 2011; van Zanden and van Leeuwen, 2012). Using a demand function approach, Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013) computed agricultural consumption per head over 1277–1850, and assuming the net imports of foodstuffs were negligible, they used it to proxy output per head.Footnote 11 As this approach relies on proxies for per capita income and assumptions about income and price elasticities, it is worth exploring alternatives.

Early modern economic historians have used indirect information on a religious tax, the tithe, to draw trends in agricultural output and Álvarez-Nogal et al. (2016) we adopted this approach to infer the evolution of agricultural output in Spain between 1500 and 1800. In this section we start from this work but extend the coverage of produce and regions as well as the time span back to 1400 and forward to 1835 (See Appendix, A.2 Computing Agricultural Output Indices from Tithes).

Figure 2.3 presents output for the main crops on the basis of tithes. Cereals show a long-run expansion up to the 1570s. Wine and livestock produce, especially, shadow cereal tendencies. Wine and olive production expanded remarkably during the central decades of the sixteenth century, remaining at high output levels until 1590. Most crops fell during the early seventeenth century, recovering at a different pace between the mid-seventeenth and the mid-eighteenth centuries. In the late eighteenth century, opposite trends are found: fruits and legumes and olive oil production declined, while cereals, must, and livestock produce expanded. A fall is observed across the board in the early nineteenth century.

Fig. 2.3
A line graph has 5 lines for cereals, olive oil, wine, legumes and fruit, and livestock. All lines follow ascending to descending trends with fluctuations, between 3.2 and 5.2 on the y-axis and 1400 and 1807 on the x-axis. Legumes and fruit have the highest peak at (1741, 5.2). Values are estimated.

Output by main produce, 1407–1814 (1790/1799=100). 11-year centred moving average (logs)

The share of each major crop in agriculture output at current prices is presented in Fig. 2.4. Cereal and animal produce are seen to be the main contributors to agricultural output, and show opposite trends, with the share of animal produce increasing and that of cereals declining up to the 1570s and in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth century, and cereals’ share expanding at the expense of animal produce in the early seventeenth and late eighteenth century.

Fig. 2.4
A multiline graph plots 6 lines for cereals, olive oil, wine, livestock produce, legumes and fruit, and others. Legumes and fruit has a nearly horizontal trend with fluctuations and other has a nearly horizontal trend. Cereals, olive oil, and wine follow fluctuating trends.

Output composition, 1500–1820 (%) (current prices)

We have constructed a Törnqvist index of agricultural output by weighting yearly variations in each crop’s output by the average shares in adjacent years of each crop in agriculture output, at current prices, and, then, obtaining its exponential. That is,

$$ {\mathrm{lnQ}}_{\mathrm{at}}\hbox{--} {\mathrm{lnQ}}_{\mathrm{at}-1}={\Sigma}_{\mathrm{i}}\left[{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{Qit}}\left({\mathrm{lnQ}}_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{t}}-{\mathrm{lnQ}}_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{t}-1}\right)\right] $$
(2.5)

with share values computed:

$$ {\uptheta}_{\mathrm{Qit}}=\frac{1}{2}\left[\left.{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{it}}+{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{it}-1}\right)\right] $$
(2.6)

Previously, current values, V, for each crop i at year t can be derived by projecting the value of each crop in 1799, Vi1799, backwards with the quantity index built on the basis of tithes, Q, and a price index, P (expressed as 1790/1799 = 1) and then, added up in order to obtain the value of total agricultural output, Vaj.

$$ V{\mathrm{a}}_{\mathrm{t}}=\Sigma {V}_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{t}}=\Sigma {V_{\mathrm{i}1799}}^{\ast }{{\mathrm{Q}}_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{t}}}^{\ast }{\mathrm{P}}_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{jt}} $$
(2.7)

Later, the share of each crop, Vit/Vat, needs to be obtained.Footnote 12

In the evolution of agricultural output, distinctive phases can be found (Fig. 2.5). The first one was of sustained expansion that peaked in the early 1560s. A contraction between the mid-1570s and the early 1610s was followed by stagnation until 1650. A long-run expansion from the mid-seventeenth to the mid-eighteenth century, punctuated by the War of Spanish Succession (1701–1714), peaked in the 1750s, when the highest output level in four centuries was reached. Output stabilised, then, until 1790, when a decline initiated that reached a trough during the Peninsular War.

Fig. 2.5
A line graph plots 2 lines for agricultural output and agricultural output Hodrick-Prescott trend. The lines virtually overlap and follow ascending to descending trends with high fluctuations. Agriculture output has the highest peak of (1763, 4.7). Values are estimated.

Agricultural Output Törnqvist Index, 1402–1835: Level and Hodrick-Prescott Trend. (1790/1799=100) (natural logs). Sources: See the text

If we now focus on agricultural output per person (Fig. 2.6, continuous line), two main phases can be identified: a high plateau covering the fifteenth century and up to early 1570s, and a low plateau spanning between the early seventeenth century and the 1750s, with a transitional phase of decline, between the late 1570s and the 1620s, in between, in which output per person shrank by one-third. A new phase of severe contraction is apparent from the 1750s to the Peninsular War, representing one-fourth of the initial level.

Fig. 2.6
A line graph plots 4 lines for per capita agricultural consumption, per capita agricultural output, per capita agricultural consumption Hodrick-Prescott trend, and per capita agricultural output Hodrick-Prescott trend. All lines virtually overlap and follow descending trends with high fluctuations.

Agricultural output and consumption per head Törnqvist Indices, 1277–1850: Levels and Hodrick-Prescott Trend (1790/1799=100) (natural logs). Sources: Text and Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013)

How does the new tithes-based agricultural output per head compare to the consumption per head estimates derived with the demand approach? Both series present roughly the same trends since the early sixteenth century (Fig. 2.6). However, some differences emerge. While the demand approach series were already on high plateau since 1400, the tithes-based series show lower levels and higher volatility up to the 1500s. The shift from a high to a low path of output per head is also common to both estimates, reaching a trough in the early seventeenth century, but the tithes-based series present a sharper and neater decline, starting in the mid-late 1570s. Lastly, although the lower plateau covers roughly the same period in the two set of estimates, the post-1650 recovery is stronger and exhibits less volatility in the tithes-based ones.

It is worth noting that the parallel behaviour of the demand-approach and tithes-based series supports the view that crop and livestock destruction appears as the main factor behind the sharp decline in tithes collection during the Peninsular War, rather than peasants’ lack of compliance with the religious tax. However, Fig. 2.6 also shows that the tithes-based output departs sharply from the demand approach estimates from 1819 onwards, and the fact that the years between 1820 and 1833 correspond to a period of peace, suggests that it is non-compliance with the religious tax that explains the widening gap between the two indices. The so-called Trienio Liberal (1820–1823), a phase of liberalisation, weakened Ancien Régime institutions and discouraged tithe compliance (Anes and García Sanz, 1982; Canales, 1982; Torras, 1976). The bottom line is, therefore, that the parallel trends of the tithe-based and the demand approach estimates endorse the use of tithes as a reliable indicator of agricultural output tendencies until 1818. Moreover, our findings challenge the dismissal of the demand approach as simple controlled conjectures. Lacking direct sources of agricultural production, as it is often the case in preindustrial societies, the demand approach appears to provide a reasonable procedure to infer agricultural output trends.

Since our goal here is to provide the best possible estimate for long-run agricultural output, we propose a new index that accepts the demand approach estimates for 1818–1850 and the tithe-based ones for 1402–1818, and projects its level for 1402 back to 1277 with the demand approach index (dotted and dashed lines in Fig. 2.7).Footnote 13

Fig. 2.7
A line graph plots 4 lines for agricultural output, agricultural output Hodrick-Prescott trend, agricultural output C A N and L P E projection, and agricultural output C A N and L P E projection trend. All lines virtually overlap and follow ascending trends with high fluctuations.

Agricultural Output Törnqvist Index (spliced), 1277–1850: Level and Hodrick-Prescott Trend (1850/1859=100) (natural logs). Sources: Text

4 Output in Non-agricultural Activities: Urbanization as a Proxy

A reconstruction of trends in industrial and services output is beyond the scope of this chapter. It would require a thorough investigation of industrial output, sector by sector, most probably on the basis of a variety of indirect indicators among which taxes merit analysis. In the case of services, the prospects of obtaining a proper assessment of output are even bleaker. A crude short cut to proxy trends in economic activity outside agriculture is urbanization, more specifically, the use of changes in the urbanization rate (ratio between urban and total population) to infer trends in non-agricultural output per head.Footnote 14 In this section, we follow Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013) and improve on their estimates by including additional urbanization benchmarks and better population data.

We have adopted the definition of ‘urban’ population as dwellers in towns of 5000 inhabitants or more.Footnote 15 However, a caveat is necessary. Urban population has been accepted here as a proxy for output in non-agricultural activities after excluding those living on agriculture. The reason is that the existence of ‘agro-towns’ (namely, towns in which a sizable share of the population was dependent on agriculture for living) appears to be a feature of pre-industrial Spain. ‘Agro-towns’ have their roots in the Reconquest. In a frontier economy, towns provided security and lower transactions costs during the re-population following the southwards advance (Ladero Quesada, 1981; Rodríguez Molina, 1978). In the thirteenth century, Christian settlers from Aragon, Catalonia, and Southern France acquired farms but preferred to live in towns (MacKay, 1977: 69). It has been claimed that, in southern Spain, “agro-towns” were the legacy of highly concentrated landownership after the acceleration in the pace of the Reconquest and the Black Death, which increased the proportion of landless agricultural workers (Vaca Lorenzo, 1983; Valdeón Baruque, 1966), although Cabrera (1989) attributes the rise of latifundia to the generalization of the seigniorial regime during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries. In our estimates, ‘agro-towns’ appear as mainly located in Andalusia, and since the late eighteenth century, also in Murcia and Valencia. Thus, we have computed trends in the rate of adjusted urbanization—that is, the share of non-agricultural urban population in total population—in an attempt to capture those in industry and services output per head (See Appendix, A.4 Adjusted Urban Population).Footnote 16

Notwithstanding the existence of ‘agro-towns’, urban economic activity was closely associated to industry and services. In sixteenth-century Old Castile, Yun-Casalilla (2004) calculates, only 1 in 12 in the urban labour force worked in agriculture. Pérez Moreda and Reher (2003: 129) suggest, for 1787, a similar proportion of farmers in Spain’s urban population.Footnote 17 Moreover, the rural population carried out non-agricultural activities (storage, transportation, domestic service, construction, light manufacturing) especially during the slack season in agriculture (Herr, 1989, López-Salazar, 1986).Footnote 18

Spain’s urban population, adjusted to exclude population living on agriculture, has been computed at benchmark years for the period 1530–1857 (Correas, 1988; Fortea, 1995). Total and adjusted urban population levels for 1530 were projected backwards with Bairoch et al. (1988: 15–21) estimates.Footnote 19 The urban population for Spain in 1530, 1561, and 1646 has been inferred from data for the Kingdom of Castile (Fortea, 1995). Adjusted urbanization rates, that is, urban population not living on agriculture expressed as a share of total population, are presented at benchmark years in Table 2.1. Annual figures of ‘adjusted’ urbanization rates have been derived via linear interpolation of the benchmark estimates.

Table 2.1 Adjusted urbanization rates, 1277–1857: Benchmark estimates (%)

The accelerated expansion of the early 1500s slowed down in its second half of the century and was reversed during the first half of the seventeenth century. Then, urbanization recovered slowly, accelerating after the War of Succession to surpass the late sixteenth-century peak by the second half of the eighteenth century. Interestingly, these figures are at odds with the rather stable rate of urbanization (around 20%) widely used in estimates by Bairoch et al. (1988).

5 Aggregate Output

The next stage is to construct an index of aggregate output (Q). Rather than estimating long-run output with fixed weights, which introduces an index number problem, as it implicitly assumes that relative prices do not change over time, we have computed a Törnqvist index in which real GDP is obtained by weighting yearly output variations in agriculture, Qat, and industry and services, proxied by ‘adjusted’ urban population, urb-nonagr t, with the average, in adjacent years, of the shares of agriculture, θQat, and non-agricultural activities, θQi+st, in GDP at current prices.Footnote 20 That is,

$$ \ln {Q}_{\mathrm{t}}\hbox{--} \ln {Q}_{\mathrm{t}-1}={\uptheta}_{\mathrm{Qat}}\left(\ln {Q}_{\mathrm{at}}\hbox{--} \ln {Q}_{\mathrm{at}-1}\right)+{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{Qi}+\mathrm{st}}\left(\ln {N}_{urb-{nonagr}_{\mathrm{t}}}^{\prime }-\ln {N}_{urb-{nonagr}_{\mathrm{t}-1}}^{\prime}\right) $$
(2.8)

where agricultural, θQat, and non-agricultural, θQi+st, share values are computed as:

$$ {\uptheta}_{\mathrm{Qat}}=\frac{1}{2}\left[\left.{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{at}}+{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{at}-1}\right)\right]\mathrm{and}\;{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{Qi}+\mathrm{st}}=\frac{1}{2}\left[\left.{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{i}+\mathrm{st}}+{\uptheta}_{\mathrm{i}+\mathrm{st}-1}\right)\right] $$
(2.9)

and, then, Qt is obtained as its exponential.

In order to get sector shares in current GDP, θit, current values, V, for each sector i at year t are derived by projecting each sector’s value added average in 1850/1859, Vi1850/9, backwards with the quantity, Q, and price P, indices previously built for each sector, Qat and Pat for agriculture, and urb-nonagr t (‘adjusted’ urban population) and Pi+st, for industry and services, respectively, (expressed as 1850/1859 = 1) and, then, added up to attain the value of total output, V.t

$$ {\mathrm{V}}_{\mathrm{a}\mathrm{t}}={\mathrm{V}}_{\mathrm{a}1850/9}{\mathrm{Q}}_{\mathrm{a}\mathrm{t}}{\mathrm{P}}_{\mathrm{a}\mathrm{t}} $$
(2.10)
$$ {\mathrm{V}}_{\mathrm{i}+\mathrm{s}\mathrm{t}}={\mathrm{V}}_{\mathrm{i}+\mathrm{s}1850/9}{N}_{urb-{nonagr}_{\mathrm{t}}}^{\prime }{\mathrm{P}}_{\mathrm{i}+\mathrm{s}\mathrm{t}} $$
(2.11)
$$ \mathrm{V}{.}_{\mathrm{t}}={\mathrm{V}}_{\mathrm{at}}+{\mathrm{V}}_{\mathrm{i}+\mathrm{st}} $$
(2.12)

Later, the shares of agricultural and non-agricultural activities were obtained, respectively, as θQat = Vat/Vt. and θQi + st = Vi + st/Vt.

As regards price indices, the price index already built in the section on agriculture has been accepted. For non-agricultural activities, an unweighted Törnqvist index was computed with industrial goods and consumer price indices and nominal wages.Footnote 21 This amounts to allocating one-third of the weight to industry (the industrial price index) and two-thirds to services (nominal wage and consumer price indices), which represents a good approximation to these sector shares in non-agricultural output in the 1850s (Prados de la Escosura, 2017). (For the source of prices see Appendix, A.3 Commodity and Factor Price Indices.)

What does the long run evolution of total output show? Distinctive phases can be observed (Fig. 2.8). Three phases of expansion: (1) between 1277 (the earliest date for which we have estimates) and the early 1340s, whose origins possibly go as far back as to the late eleventh century; (2) from the 1470s to 1570, disrupted in the early decades of the sixteenth century; and (3) from the mid-seventeenth to mid-nineteenth century, interrupted during the Spanish Succession (1701–1714) and Napoleonic (1793–1815) Wars. Two phases of sustained decline complete the picture: the first one, triggered by the Black Death (1348), very intense until the 1370s, followed by stagnation until the first quarter of the fifteenth century; and a second one, from the late sixteenth to the mid-seventeenth century.

Fig. 2.8
A line graph illustrates 2 lines for G D P Hodrick-Prescott trend and G D P. Both the lines virtually overlap and follow an ascending trend, between 2.7 and 4.6 on the y-axis and 1277 and 1847 on the x-axis. Values are estimated.

Real GDP Törnqvist Index, 1277–1850: Level and Hodrick-Prescott Trend (1850/1859=100) (natural logs). Sources: See the text

If we now turn to output per head, its evolution follows a wide W shape, with phases of growth which peak in 1341, 1566, and 1850, separated by deep contractions in the late fourteenth and early seventeenth century (Fig. 2.9). Each phase of expansion up to the Napoleonic Wars (1277–1341, 1472–1566, and 1643–1850) shows similar trend growth but, as output per head declined sharply during shrinking episodes, each subsequent phase of growth started from a lower level and, hence, evolved along a lower path, with the result that, in the very long run, the trend growth rate is practically nil and per capita income levels hardly change at all (Table 2.2, Panel A).

Fig. 2.9
A line graph plots 2 lines for G D P per head Hodrick-Prescott trend and G D P per head. Both the lines virtually overlap and follow the fluctuating trend, between 4.0 and 4.7 on the y-axis and 1277 and 1847 on the x-axis. G D P per head has the highest peak of (1562, 4.62). Values are approximate.

Real GDP per head Törnqvist Index, 1277–1850: Level and Hodrick-Prescott Trend (1850/1859=100) (natural logs). Sources: See the text

Table 2.2 Output and population trend growth, 1277–1850 (%)a (annual average logarithmic rates)

Trend growth ratesFootnote 22 for the new estimates (Table 2.2) show that in phases of economic expansion and contraction, total output responded more than proportionally to population and confirm the view that output per head and population trends were directly associated.

When we compare the new index of output per head to earlier estimates by Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013), it is noticeable that in the new series, the economic collapse in the late sixteenth century began earlier, in the 1570s, not in the late 1580s, and was deeper. Nonetheless, the use of supply and demand methods to assess trends in agricultural production provides similar long-term results in both levels and trends over 1402–1818 (Fig. 2.10).Footnote 23 This key methodological finding supports the use of an indirect approach such as a demand function when no sources for a direct estimation are available.Footnote 24

Fig. 2.10
A multiline graph plots 4 lines for G D P per head Hodrick-Prescott trend, G D P per head, Alvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura, and Alvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura Hodrick-Prescott trend. All lines virtually overlap and follow the fluctuating trends throughout the graph.

Real GDP per head, 1277–1850: New and Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013) Törnqvist Indices: Level and Hodrick-Prescott Trend (1850/1859=100) (logs). Sources: See the text and Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013)

6 Interpreting the Results: Evidence and Hypotheses

Are there any lessons to be drawn from the new quantitative evidence on preindustrial Spain’s performance? Some stylised facts about preindustrial societies can perhaps be put to the test. An initial example is that of stagnant average incomes. Although living standards did not experience a noticeable improvement over the very long run, the expansive and contracting phases in the W-shaped evolution of Spain’s real output per head contradict this view (Fig. 2.9). Instead, our results lend support to the idea of growth recurring over six centuries. Moreover, Broadberry and Wallis (2017) claim that, as shrinking phases become shorter and less frequent after growing phases, modern economic growth emerges, appears to be confirmed by Spain’s early nineteenth century experience.

A second stylised fact is the Malthusian nature of preindustrial economies. Trends in Spanish population and per capita income, expressed in logs, are offered in Fig. 2.11.Footnote 25 Population and real output per head expanded simultaneously up to the Black Death, during the late fifteenth and the sixteenth century, and from the early eighteenth to the mid-nineteenth century; conversely, population and income per person shrank in the late fourteenth and in the early seventeenth centuries. How can we explain these results, at odds with the Malthusian view? A plausible explanatory hypothesis is the existence of a frontier economy, resource abundant in preindustrial Spain, but how long did Spain remain a frontier economy? Labour productivity moved together with the labour force in agriculture, so when population and labour declined or grew, labour productivity did so too, and this pattern, which applied not only to Habsburg Spain but also to Bourbon Spain, may have lasted until the mid-nineteenth century. Furthermore, land rent and labour productivity in agriculture also moved together (Álvarez-Nogal et al., 2016: 466–467). Moreover, the fact that in Spain the Black Death was not the watershed that it constituted in central and Western Continental Europe and the British Isles may be explained by its specific traits. In Western Europe, by wiping out between one-half and one-third of the population, the Black Death reduced demographic pressure on resources, raised land- and capital-labour ratios, and led to higher returns to labour vis-à-vis land or capital and higher relative prices for non-agricultural goods. Cheaper capital and labour scarcity led to lower interest rates and higher wages that incentivised physical and human capital accumulation and stimulated labour saving technical innovation and female participation (Pamuk, 2007). The fact that factor proportions in post-Plague Western Europe were apparently similar to pre-Plague Spain’s helps to explain why the negative economic consequences of the Black Death, despite its comparatively milder demographic impact, prevailed in Spain during the late fourteenth and early fifteenth century. In Spain, population density before the Plague (8.9 inhabitants per square kilometre in 1300) was much lower than in most Western European countries after the Plague in 1400 (Álvarez-Nogal et al., 2020) and the Plague destroyed a pre-existing fragile equilibrium between population and resources (Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura, 2013).Footnote 26 Furthermore, the collapse in the late sixteenth century and its lasting effects do not adjust to the Malthusian narrative.Footnote 27 The fall in real output per head that, in its early stage (−0.65% over 1567–1610), was as sharp as the one associated with the Black Death (−0.67% from 1342 to 1377), seems crucial to Spain’s falling behind. From 1570 to 1650, while population stagnated and per capita income shrank, the economy shifted from commercial and trade-oriented to inward looking and rural.

Fig. 2.11
A line graph illustrates 2 lines. G D P per head Hodrick-Prescott trend follows a fluctuating trend with high fluctuations. Population Hodrick-Prescott trend follows an ascending trend throughout the graph.

GDP per head and population Hodrick-Prescott Trends, 1277–1850: (1850/1859=100) (logs). Sources: See the text

Long-run performance has been discussed, so far, in average terms, but how were the gains and losses over successive growing and shrinking phases of per capita income distributed among social groups? The Williamson Index, defined here as the nominal (that is, current price) ratio between output per head and unskilled wage rates and expressed with 1790/1799=100, makes it possible to draw trends in inequality. The rationale underlying the Williamson Index is that GDP captures the returns to all factors of production, while the unskilled wage only captures the returns accruing to one factor, raw labour.Footnote 28 This way, average returns are compared with returns to unskilled labourers, that is, those at the middle of distribution are compared with those at the bottom. We cannot establish precisely, however, how close to the absolute poverty line unskilled wages were, although attempts to compute welfare ratios (namely, the ratio between a male labourer’s yearly returns and the cost of maintaining his family) suggest that unskilled workers were living close to subsistence in early modern Spain (Allen, 2001; but see López Losa and Piquero Zarauz, 2021). The new Williamson Index improves on the one used in Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura (2013) by employing current prices and, hence, avoiding the distortions introduced by the use of different deflators for GDP and wages (see Appendix, A.3 Commodity and Factor Price Indices, for the sources of wages), and more reliable GDP estimates.

Inequality trends followed those of GDP per head, expanding and contracting accordingly. Two phases in the evolution of income distribution can be distinguished, however. One of lower inequality, from the late thirteenth century (and probably earlier) up to the early sixteenth century, and another, of higher inequality, from the mid-sixteenth century onwards (Fig. 2.12), which presents an upward trend and matches the experience of early modern Europe (Hoffman et al., 2002; Alfani, 2021).

Fig. 2.12
A line graph plots 2 lines. The Nominal Williamson Index H-P trend follows an ascending trend with high fluctuations. G D P per head H-P trend follows a fluctuating trend throughout the graph.

Nominal Williamson Index and real GDP per head Hodrick-Prescott Trends, 1277–1850 (1790/1799=100) (natural logs). Sources: See the text

7 Spain in an International Perspective

How did Spain perform internationally? Angus Maddison (1995, 2006) compared average incomes across countries and over time in a common monetary unit and at constant prices. Maddison’s set of international estimates of real income per head in 1990 Geary-Khamis dollars international prices resulted from projecting per capita GDP levels in 1990 dollars, expressed in purchasing power parity (PPP) terms—that is, adjusted for differences in price levels across countries-, back and forth with volume indices taken from historical national accounts. Although Maddison’s approach has been widely used, it can certainly be challenged. Its main shortcoming derives from the severe index number problem it introduces in the comparisons, since the basket of goods and services produced and consumed in 1990, and their prices, become less and less representative as one moves back and forth in time.Footnote 29

If, with all the caveats about the reliability of income levels derived with a remote benchmark, we follow Maddison’s approach and express product per head in 1990 Geary-Khamis (G-K) dollars, Spain’s average income ranged between G-K 1990 $600–1100 over half a millennium.Footnote 30 As the absolute poverty line was set by the World Bank at 1985 $1 a day per person, that is, 1990 $426, preindustrial Spain’s average income always remained above the absolute poverty line, more than doubling it in the early fourteenth century, in the late fifteenth and the sixteenth century and, again, since the late eighteenth century (See Appendix, Table 2.3).Footnote 31

How does Spain compare to major economies in preindustrial Western Europe? At the time of the Black Death, average income levels in Spain were above those of the North Sea Area (Netherlands and the United Kingdom) and France (Fig. 2.13). Then, in 1560s, at the peak of its expansion, Spain’s per capita GDP still remained ahead the U.K and France’s, but way below that of the Netherlands. The collapse from the 1570s represented a watershed and Spain fell behind during the seventeenth century. In the early eighteenth century and the post-Napoleonic Wars economic recovery, Spain partially caught up with France but not with the U.K., and its growth was not strong enough to prevent another episode of falling behind during the early nineteenth century.

Fig. 2.13
A multiline graph plots 4 lines for Spain, France, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom. All lines follow ascending trends with fluctuations, between 6.2 and 7.8 on the y-axis and 1277 and 1838 on the x-axis. Values are estimated.

Real GDP per head Hodrick-Prescott Trends 1270–1850: European Perspective ($1990) (logs). Sources: Spain, see the text; France, Ridolfi and Nuvolari (2020); Netherlands, van Zanden and van Leeuwen (2012); United Kingdom, Broadberry et al. (2015)

8 Concluding Remarks

In this chapter, we have attempted to make the most of scattered data. The results, conjectural as they may be, offer some preliminary conclusions and hypotheses for further research.

  1. 1.

    Our aggregate output estimates revise and improve on previous work by (Álvarez-Nogal and Prados de la Escosura, 2013; Álvarez-Nogal et al. 2016). In particular, our agricultural output estimates based on tithes largely confirm those previously obtained with a demand approach. This represents a relevant methodological finding for the reconstruction of historical national accounts: the use of indirect methods such as a demand function to assess trends in agricultural output is warranted in the absence of direct sources.

  2. 2.

    Although no significant long-term change in per capita output emerges over more than half a millennium, Spain’s preindustrial economy was far from stagnant and long phases of absolute and per capita growth and decline alternated. ‘Smithian’ and ‘growth recurring’ episodes seem to be present in Spain’s performance.

  3. 3.

    Population and output per head moved together, at odds with the conventional depiction of preindustrial societies as Malthusian. This finding is consistent with the high land-labour ratios found in a frontier economy.

  4. 4.

    In a frontier economy, living standards are usually relatively high and incomes not very unequally distributed. These features seem to reflect Spain’s experience until the early sixteenth century.

  5. 5.

    If we project Spain’s per capita income trend growth during 1470–1570 until the onset of the Napoleonic Wars, we obtain similar levels to the U.K.’s. Why was Spain’s performance up to the 1570s cut short, giving way to a sustained falling behind? Why did Spain never return to the virtuous path initiated in the late fifteenth and consolidated during the sixteenth century? Conventional Malthusian narratives do not appear persuasive in a context of simultaneous growth or decline of population and per capita income. The answer seems to be in policymakers’ economic decisions and new incentives. The long-run unintended consequences of Spain’s attempt to preserve its European Empire provides an explanatory hypothesis that needs to be explored. Sustained increases in fiscal pressure on dynamic urban activities to finance imperial wars in Europe triggered de-urbanisation and led to a collapse in average real incomes, from which early modern Spain never fully recovered. Furthermore, post-1570s Spain appears to present a mirror image of the North Sea Area’s experience where the pull of urban demand triggered an agricultural revolution, as peasants had an incentive to raise their purchasing power to access the new urban goods and services.