Skip to main content

Project Analysis and Environmental Effects

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Project Analysis in Developing Countries
  • 69 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter addresses how the environmental effects of projects can be incorporated in project analysis. It begins by briefly discussing the basis for environmental values used in project economics before explaining the main approaches in the literature for putting numerical values on these effects. These values need to be incorporated in a project resource statement and like other effects in the future need to be given a value in the present. How to discount environmental effects has been a topic of considerable debate and the chapter reviews the main alternatives for doing so.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 44.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A definition of an ecosystem is provided by the UN Convention on Biological Diversity: ‘a dynamic complex of plant, animal and micro-organism communities and their non-living environment interacting as a functional unit’. Ecosystem services are the benefits from an ecosystem.

  2. 2.

    These figures come the studies collected in the Ecosystem Services Database reported in de Groot et al. (2020). The authors treat these averages as no more than illustrative of the wide range found and caution against their use for benefit transfer.

  3. 3.

    A review of different approaches is given in UN (2021) and USAID (2018). Often estimates of environmental value make little or no reference to the issue of the numeraire and the procedures discussed in Chaps. 5 and 6. Where this is the case, implicitly a domestic price numeraire is used. As discussed in Chap. 5 this requires that, where necessary, a shadow exchange rate is applied to the value of traded items, including any environmental effect that involves traded goods.

  4. 4.

    Some classifications, such as USAID (2018), define revealed preference most widely and for example, include cost-based approaches under revealed preference, on the grounds that expenditures reveal a minimum valuation of a service.

  5. 5.

    See Markandya (2016).

  6. 6.

    A focus on tangible output changes created by a project’s environmental effects involves an environmental production function, where the environmental service is an input into production [see Barbier et al., 2023].

  7. 7.

    Ug is the metric measure of milligram.

  8. 8.

    Multiplication by 100 is required due to the logarithmic form used.

  9. 9.

    Carson et al. (2003) explain the original study. The review of the methodology and recommendations is Arrow et al. (1993).

  10. 10.

    USAID (2018) summarises these. The best documented of the databases is the Ecosystem Services Value Database (ESVD) [see De Groot et al., 2020].

  11. 11.

    Barbier et al. (2023, Table 1) give another summary of case studies estimating ecosystem benefits.

  12. 12.

    The example is adapted from USAID (2018).

  13. 13.

    Emissions can also have local effects, for example, where the health of the population in the vicinity of a project is affected. In principle, these health damage costs should also be estimated.

  14. 14.

    Pindyck (2017) has a critical assessment of these models.

  15. 15.

    See Stern et al. (2021).

  16. 16.

    As discussed further below, there is considerable disagreement on how best to discount future environmental effects. The study cited here used a baseline discount rate of 4.25% (calculated as an average of the opportunity cost of capital in the US and other economies), which gave a most likely value for CO2 of $37 in 2020 (in 2010 dollars). This is a relatively low figure for CO2 and much less than that obtained with discount rates that are defined in terms of social time preference.

  17. 17.

    If the electricity supplied to a project is valued at economic prices, with a cost of carbon included in the cost, it will be unnecessary to add the indirect emissions arising from the use of electricity. Provided the appropriate carbon price is used, inclusion of this indirect effect will be double-counting.

  18. 18.

    The discount factor for year 100 at a 6% discount rate is (1/1+0.06)50, which is 0.002947 and 50 times 0.002947 equals 0.15.

  19. 19.

    This suggestion, for example in Markandya and Pearce (1994), was made in part to allow a conventional discount rate to be applied to projects with major environmental effects.

  20. 20.

    The contrast was a rate of close to 4% or one between 1% and 0 [see Nordhaus, 2007; Stern, 2007].

  21. 21.

    Weikard and Zhu (2005) show theoretically that the difference between the discount rate for consumption in general and for the environment is given by the price change for environmental assets relative to consumption goods.

  22. 22.

    Nordhaus (2017), for example, uses a 3% relative price increase.

  23. 23.

    As these are simple projects, investment is in year zero.

  24. 24.

    The implication is that by increasing emissions this abatement expenditure per tonne of CO2 will have to be incurred to meet the national carbon target.

  25. 25.

    As non-residents it is conventional to assume that any consumer surplus of foreigners is not part of national benefits. Hence only funds collected from them in charges are relevant.

Bibliography

  • Anand, P. (2012). Environmental Valuation. In J. Weiss & D. Potts (Eds.), Current Issues in Project Analysis for Development. Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., Solow, R., Portney, P., Leamer, E., Radner, R., & Schuman, H. (1993). Report of the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation. Federal Register, 58(10), 4601–4614.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbier, E., Mensah, A., & Wilson, M. (2023). Valuing the Environment as an Input, Eco-system Services and Developing Countries. Environmental and Resource Economics, 84, 677–694.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, R., Mitchell, M., Hanemann, M., Kopp, R., & Presser, S. (2003). Contingent Valuation and Lost Passive Use: Damages from the Exxon Valdez Oil Spill. Environmental and Resource Economics, 25(3), 257–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costanza, R., Perez-Maqueo, O., Martinez, M. L., Sutton, P., Anderson, S. J., & Mulder, K. (2008). The Value of Coastal Wetlands for Hurricane Protection. Ambio, 37, 241–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Groot, R. Brainder, L., vsn der Ploeg, S., Costanza, R., Bernard, F., Braat, L., Christie, M., Crossman, N., Ghermandi, A., Hein, L., Hussain, S., Kumar, P., McVittie, A., Portela, R., Rodriguez, L., ten Brink, P., van Beukering, P. (2012). Global Estimates of the Value of Ecosystems and Their Services in Monetary Units. Ecosystem Services, 1, 50–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Groot, R., Brander, L., & Solomonides, S. (2020). Update of Global Eco-System Service Valuation Database. Foundation for Sustainable Development, Report 2020-06, Wageningen, Netherlands.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godoy, R., Overman, H., Demmer, J., Apaza, L., Byron, E., Huanca, T., Leonard, W., Pérez, E., Reyes-Garcia, V., Vadez, V., Wilkie, D., Cubas, A., Mcsweeney, K., & Brokaw, N. (2002). Local Financial Benefits of Rain Forests: Comparative Evidence from Amerindian Societies in Bolivia and Honduras. Ecological Economics, 40(3), 397–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karp, D. S., Mendenhall, C. D., Sandí, R. F., Chaumont, N., Ehrlich, P. R., Hadly, E. A., & Daily, G. C. (2013). Forest Bolsters Bird Abundance, Pest Control and Coffee Yield. Ecology Letters, 16(11), 1339–1347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markandya, A. (2016). Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment: How to Best Cover Impacts on Biodiversity and Eco-system Services. OECD Environment Working Paper 101, OECD, .

    Google Scholar 

  • Markandya, A., & Pearce, D. (1994). Natural Environments and the Social Rate of Discount. In J. Weiss (Ed.), The Economics of Project Appraisal and the Environment. Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulwa, R., Kabubo-Mariara, J., & Nyangena, W. (2018). Recreational Value and Optimal Pricing of National Parks: Lessons from Maasai Mara in Kenya. Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy, 7(2), 204–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narayan, T., Foley, L., Haskell, J., Cooley, D., & Hyman, E. (2017). Cost-Benefit Analysis of Mangrove Restoration for Coastal Protection and an Earthen Dike Alternative in Mozambique. United States Agency for International Development. Climate Economic Analysis Development, Investment and Resilience (CEADIR).

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (2007). A Review of the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Journal of Economic Literature., 45(3), 686–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. (2017). Revisiting the Social Cost of Carbon. Downloaded from www.pnas.org

  • OECD. (2018). Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment: Further Developments and Policy Use, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D., Atkinson, G., & Mourata, S. (2006). Cost Benefit Analysis and the Environment. OECD, 128–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D., Pearce, C., & Palmer, C. (Eds.). (2002). Valuing the Environment in Developing Countries. Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck, R. (2017). The Use and Misuse of Models for Climate Policy. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 11, 100–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ricketts, T., Daily, G., Ehrlich, P., & Michener, C. (2004). Economic Value of Tropical Forest to Coffee Production. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 101(34), 12579–12582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sathirathai, S., & Barbier, E. (2001). Valuing Mangrove Conservation in Southern Thailand. Contemporary Economic Policy, 19(2), 109–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern, N. (2007). The Economics of Climate Change: Stern Review. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stern, N., J. Stiglitz, and C. Taylor. (2021). Economics of Immense Risk, Urgent Action and Radical Change. NBER Working Paper 28472. National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • UN. (2021). Monetary Valuation of Ecosystem Services and Assets for Ecosystem Accounting, NCAVE and MAIA. UN.

    Google Scholar 

  • USAID. (2018). Integrating Ecosystem Values in Cost Benefit Analysis. USAID.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogl, A., Bryan, B., Hunink, J., Wolny, S., Apse, C., & Droogers, P. (2017). Valuing Investments in Sustainable Land Management in the Upper Tana River Basin, Kenya. Journal of Environmental Management, 198, 78–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watson, K., Ricketts, T., Galford, G., Polasky, S., & Oniel-Dunne, J. (2016). Quantifying Flood Mitigation Services: The Economic Value of Otter Creek Wetlands and Floodplains to Middlebury, VT. Ecological Economics, 130, 16–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weikard, H., & Zhu, X. (2005). Discounting and the Environment: When Should Dual Rates By Used? Economic Modelling, 22, 868–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2017). Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices. World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yingdan, M., Gao, L., Zhang, J., & Wang, J. (2020). Valuing Urban Air Quality: A Hedonic Price Analysis in Beijing, China. Environmental Science and Pollution Research, 27(2), 1373–1385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendices

Appendix 1: Depletion Premium

Discussions of environmental valuation have refocused attention on the fact that development projects may use resources whether natural habitats and ozone layers or minerals or fossil fuels, which cannot be renewed or replaced. The point of principle is that the cost of using such resources is not just the cost of their extraction, but also the foregone opportunity of using them in the future arising from the fact that because of their finite supply current use means that future income (or future benefits that are equivalent to a value in income) from these resources are lost. The cost of this income forgone is what constitutes the depletion premium. The full economic cost of using a non-renewable resource is its cost of extraction plus the depletion premium, which captures the use-value that others forgo as a result of current use. Hence, an important part of environmental valuation relates to its estimation.

There are two issues here, one relating to ex ante appraisal and the other to pricing policy. First, the full economic cost of non-renewable natural resources must be included in the appraisal of any project using these resources. Unless the benefits from a resource extraction project are high enough to cover costs, including the depletion premium, by definition the project cannot be making the best use of the limited resources involved. Second, unless the depletion premium is included in the price charged for the resource, current users will not be paying a price that reflects the negative impact of their use of the resource on society’s future income.

Estimation of the depletion premium is based on the principle that for a particular rate of resource extraction to be justified the net unit value of the resource—that is, the price per unit minus the cost of extraction—must rise at the same rate as the discount rate. If the discount rate is an opportunity cost rate, the logic is that if the net unit value rises by less than the rate of discount it will pay to increase the extraction rate to obtain more resources and invest the proceeds from their sale at the discount rate. If the reverse holds and the price rise is greater than the rate of discount it will pay to extract less, keep the resource in its natural state and let it appreciate in value. Similar arguments apply if the discount rate is one of time preference. The interpretation is that if the appreciation in price is less than the cost of waiting it makes sense to extract the resource, and if the appreciation is greater than the cost of waiting it makes sense to keep it in its natural state.

The application of this principle allows the formulation of the depletion premium (DP) in any year t as:

$$ {DP}_t=\left({P}_{t+n}-{E}_{t+n}\right)/{\left(1+r\right)}^n $$
(11.3)

where

  • Pt + n is the value of the resource at the time it is exhausted

  • Et + n is the extraction cost in the year of exhaustion

  • r is the discount rate

  • n is the number of years between year t and the point of resource exhaustion.5

The depletion premium is the per unit opportunity cost of the depletable resource. Equation (11.3) implies that in any year it is given by the future value of the resource at the point that it is fully depleted (P) minus the extraction cost saved (E), since the resource is no longer depleted, discounted back to the year in question. Hence there are four influences on the DP: the value placed on the resource at the time of its exhaustion, the extraction cost, the discount rate, and the length of life of the depletable resource.

Of these, in Eq. (11.3) the discount rate is that rate used for the project concerned, while extraction costs can be estimated from technical data. Of greater uncertainty are likely to be the length of life of the resource involved and the economic value of the latter at the point of depletion. In principle these latter parameters are interdependent and will also vary with the discount rate and extraction costs. Formally their correct valuation requires a programming model that solves for the different parameters simultaneously. In practice empirical estimation may be much more approximate.

A further complication is that the final value of the resource P can be defined in two alternative ways. Where the resource has a substitute, its unit value at the point of full depletion will be determined by the equivalent per unit cost of the substitute. The charge for the resource cannot go beyond this since by definition there will be a cheaper substitute available. For example, fuels have substitutes and the value of a natural gas deposit per million Btu at the point of depletion could be specified as the cost of the quantity of fuel oil required to give the same energy as a million Btu of gas. As a traded good, fuel oil should be valued at its world price. Hence, if the gas field is estimated to have roughly 15 years of working life, the forecast price of oil 15 years in the future gives the basis for the estimation of the value of gas at depletion.

However, there will be some non-renewable environmental resources with no substitutes. If environmental assets like wetlands and endangered species of animals or plants are treated as completely non-substitutable resources, so the value becomes infinite, and Eq. (11.3) cannot be applied. Hence where environmental assets have no replacement value, the concept of a depletion premium is meaningless. For non-renewable minerals and fossil fuels, where the terms in Eq. (11.3) are quantifiable, the policy concern is that users should pay the full cost of using the resource, including the depletion premium in the price they are charged. Moreover, there is a case for taxing the depletion premium component of the charge rather than letting it remain as profit in the hands of the resource owners. This is on the grounds that as tax revenue the income from the depletion premium can be set aside in a fund to finance the development of substitutes for the non-renewable resources that are currently being depleted.

These principles can be illustrated with a simple numerical example using the case of a natural gas field. Extraction cost of gas is $0.5 per mill Btu, while the field is estimated to have an approximate working life of 15 years on the basis of current projections of demand (although strictly these will vary with the price charged for the gas). Fuel oil is taken as the substitute fuel and after 15 years, the equivalent economic cost of fuel oil is estimated at $4.0 per mill Btu. The discount rate is 10%. It is assumed that both fuel oil and extraction costs are already at economic prices (including emissions effect) and thus reflect economic values. With this information Eq. (11.3) can be used to derive both the depletion premium and the full cost of using natural gas on new projects for each year from 1 to 15 (Table 11.8).

Table 11.8 Economic value of gas

In Table 11.8 the cost of using natural gas (and its economic value) rises gradually to the replacement cost of the gas in year 15 of $4.0 per million Btu. The increase in the cost of gas usage is due to the rise in the depletion premium at the rate of discount of 10% annually. The figures in the final column give the full economic value of gas. This is the figure for the cost of gas to be used in each year of the project calculations and also to be charged to gas users.

Appendix 2: Meta-Analysis Using Ecosystem Service Database (ESVD)

A meta-analysis is a more sophisticated version of a benefit function transfer, where the coefficients to be applied to project-specific data, come from a statistical analysis of data from a large number of studies in the literature, with control variables included for the methodology used in each study and checks on data consistency and quality. The existence of large databases on environmental values, such as the ESVD, make this approach possible. However, it will only be applicable for certain types of service where there is a large enough and sufficiently consistent literature and where benefits from the service can be defined clearly enough. Furthermore, there is the important question of whether a project study conducts an original meta-analysis or uses one from the literature. It is clearly more complicated to do the former.

De Groot et al. (2012) has a useful illustration of how the ESVD data can be used in meta-analysis to provide guidance values. They use the illustration of valuation of wetland services based on 244 studies from the database. The results from these studies are used in a cross-sectional regression of the form

$$ {lny}_{\mathrm{i}}=\mathrm{a}+ bw.{Xw}_{\mathrm{i}}+ bc.{Xc}_{\mathrm{i}}+ bs.{Xs}_{\mathrm{i}}+{\mathrm{u}}_{\mathrm{i}} $$
(11.4)

where i is 1 … 244 and refers to individual studies from the ESVD, yi is a vector of wetland service values from the ESVD, a is a constant, b is a vector of coefficients on the explanatory variables and u is a vector of residuals.

Three types of explanatory variables are included. Xw cover characteristics of the wetland involved, such as geographical area in hectares, and wetland types, such as freshwater, wooded or salt brackish marshes. Xc refer to socio-economic and geographic characteristics of the study site, such as GDP per capita, population within 50 kms radius of study site, and measures in hectares of wetland and rivers/lake abundance within 50 kms radius. Xs covers the estimation approach used in the different studies whose results are used in the analysis, with a dummy of 1.0 to reflect use of a particular method, such as hedonic pricing or production function. Hence to derive a site-specific value, the b coefficients from Eq. (11.4) must be combined with X values for the site concerned.

Table 11.9 reports the variables used and the results. Statistically significant results are found for the wetland area size (with a negative sign indicating diminishing returns per hectare as scale is increased); income per capita and population within the 50 km radius (with a positive sign indicating the value of services rise with income and population); dummies for certain types of wetland (with freshwater marshes appearing to generate a lower value of services); wetland abundance within 50 kms (with a negative sign indicating a substitution effect with some service benefits captured by adjacent wetlands); finally the negative signs on some of the dummies indicate that studies using these methods generate a lower value of services than that in the omitted method in the regression, which is contingent valuation).

Table 11.9 Illustration of meta-analysis

In a meta-analysis the data on an individual site can be combined with the coefficients from the cross-sectional study to give a first approximation estimate for a new location. However, the authors enter a series of caveats on the need to check the accuracy of this result. They stress values for services will be site and time-specific and that the type of averages reported in large databases will be illustrative not definitive. They caution that if environmental service valuation is critical to a project, it can be ‘duly informed’ by a transfer value, but this should not be a substitute for a detailed original calculation.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Curry, S., Weiss, J. (2023). Project Analysis and Environmental Effects. In: Project Analysis in Developing Countries. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-40014-8_11

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-40014-8_11

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-031-40013-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-031-40014-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics