Skip to main content

Particularities of the Digital Economy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Restrictions of EU Competition Law in the Digital Age

Part of the book series: Studies in European Economic Law and Regulation ((SEELR,volume 25))

  • 238 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter illustrates the changes digitisation brought with respect to the digital economy and digital markets. It will be shown why markets online differ from markets offline and why established classical economic theory and models might need to be revised and adapted to the novelties related to digitisation and a digital economy. Whether or not markets function similarly or not is crucial in particular for the context analysis necessary for the establishment of an object infringement of competition. Hence, whether a measure offline is, with respect to its potential detrimental impact on competition, to be assessed equally or differently as the very same practice in an online environment depends a lot on whether we can conclude that the context of digital markets is or is not to be equated with (market) mechanisms known from the analogue world. As mentioned initially, a fact one could arguably doubt. Hence, the changing economic environment, that is, economic trends and phenomena evolving due to digitisation (such as, for example, platforms in any form whatsoever) are particularly interesting and crucial when trying to define a coherent approach for the meaning and role of effects in competition law cases.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    As mentioned above, e.g. the role of digital markets, FAANG as multi-sided platforms etc.

  2. 2.

    Kuttner (1998).

  3. 3.

    Ibid.

  4. 4.

    Anderson (1997).

  5. 5.

    Explained by collecting data and low marginal costs.

  6. 6.

    For example, Report of the Committee for the Study of Digital Platforms, Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report dated 1 July 2019, George J. Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State, The University of Chicago Booth School of Business, available at <https://research.chicagobooth.edu/-/media/research/stigler/pdfs/market-structure-report.pdf?la=en&hash=E08C7C9AA7367F2D612DE24F814074BA43CAED8C> accessed 6 February 2023 (‘Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report’); OECD, Maintaining competitive conditions in the era of digitalisation – OECD report to G-20 finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors, July 2018, available at <http://www.oecd.org/g20/Maintaining-competitive-conditions-in-era-of-digitalisation-OECD.pdf> accessed 6 February 2023 (‘OECD Digitisation Report’).

  7. 7.

    Arguing similarly Precht (2018).

  8. 8.

    Ezrachi and Stucke (2018), p. 39.

  9. 9.

    This explains why the online environment is prone to lead to an increase of the free rider problem.

  10. 10.

    Petropoulus (2018), para 5.

  11. 11.

    Ibid.

  12. 12.

    For example, the changes the invention of the automobile brought, such as new laws and regulations to safeguard the functioning of traffic.

  13. 13.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6) 4.

  14. 14.

    The invisible hand according to Adam Smith leading to a self-regulation of markets.

  15. 15.

    Report of the Committee for the Study of Digital Platforms, Media Subcommittee Report dated 1 July 2019, George J. Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State The University of Chicago Booth School of Business, available at <https://research.chicagobooth.edu/-/media/research/stigler/pdfs/media%2D%2D-report.pdf?la=en&hash=B9C175BCDBF29606704740B23D290CD447D1F3BA> accessed 6 February 2023 (‘Media Subcommittee Report’).

  16. 16.

    To name only a few examples, University institutions and centres (for example, the Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State) the OECD, the EU, national competition authorities (e.g. UK, Australia, Germany), the German Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy and the German Monopolies Commission, etc.

  17. 17.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6) 4.

  18. 18.

    Report of the Committee for the Study of Digital Platforms, Politics Subcommittee Report dated July 2019, George J. Stigler Center for the Study of the Economy and the State The University of Chicago Booth School of Business, available at <https://research.chicagobooth.edu/-/media/research/stigler/pdfs/politics%2D%2D-report.pdf?la=en&hash=79EBF1EB16FFDF1316F7A1F907BD4F0A543AC402> accessed 6 February 2023 (‘Politics Subcommittee Report’).

  19. 19.

    Media Subcommittee Report (n 15).

  20. 20.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 5.

  21. 21.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 4.

  22. 22.

    OECD Digitisation Report (n 6), para 9.

  23. 23.

    Ibid.

  24. 24.

    Commission, ‘Report from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament – Final report on the E-commerce Sector Inquiry’, COM(2017) 229 final (E-Commerce Sector Inquiry Report).

  25. 25.

    Posner (2000), p. 2.

  26. 26.

    E-Commerce Sector Inquiry Report (n 24), para 16.

  27. 27.

    Robertson (2020), pp. 161–190.

  28. 28.

    For example, Communication from the Commission, Online Platforms and the Digital Single Market – Opportunities and Challenges for Europe, COM(2016) 288 final (‘Online Platform Communication’).

  29. 29.

    Green Paper on Digital Platforms, German Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy (May 2016) 23, available at <https://www.bmwi.de/Redaktion/EN/Publikationen/green-paper-digital-platforms.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=4> accessed 6 February 2023 (‘Green Paper on Digital Platforms’) 4.

  30. 30.

    Ibid.

  31. 31.

    Cremer et al. (2019), p. 112; Furman et al. (2019), p. 75; Australian Competition & Consumer Commission, ‘Digital Platforms Inquiry: Preliminary Report’ (December 2018), available at <https://www.accc.gov.au/focus-areas/inquiries-finalised/digital-platforms-inquiry-0/preliminary-report> accessed 6 February 2023, p. 35; Heike Schweitzer et al, German Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy, ‘Modernising the law on abuse of market power – Summary of the report’s recommendations’ (4 September 2018), available at <https://www.bmwk.de/Redaktion/DE/Downloads/Studien/modernisierung-der-missbrauchsaufsicht-fuer-marktmaechtige-unternehmen-zusammenfassung-englisch.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=3> accessed 6 February 2023, p. 2.

  32. 32.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 8.

  33. 33.

    Linklaters contribution ahead of the conference ‘Shaping competition policy in the era of digitisation’ hosted by the European Commission on 17 January 2019 (30 September 2018) available at <https://ec.europa.eu/competition/information/digitisation_2018/contributions/linklaters.pdf> accessed 6 February 2023, p. 1.

  34. 34.

    See to this effect, for example, the Digital Markets Act: Regulation (EU) 2022/1925 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 14 September 2022 on contestable and fair markets in the digital sector and amending Directives (EU) 2019/1937 and (EU) 2020/1828 (Digital Markets Act) [2022] OJ L265/1.

  35. 35.

    See, for example, Nazzini (2018); Filistrucchi et al. (2013); OECD, ‘Maintaining competitive conditions in the era of digitalisation – OECD report to G-20 finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors’ (July 2018), available at <http://www.oecd.org/g20/Maintaining-competitive-conditions-in-era-of-digitalisation-OECD.pdf> accessed 6 February 2023.

  36. 36.

    Competition Policy: The challenge of digital markets, Special Report by the Monopolies Commission pursuant to section 44(1)(4) of the Act Against Restraints on Competition (2015), available at <https://www.monopolkommission.de/images/PDF/SG/s68_fulltext_eng.pdf> accessed 6 February 2023 (Monopolies Commission Report), paras 16–33.

  37. 37.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 11.

  38. 38.

    Green Paper on Digital Platforms (n 29), p. 26.

  39. 39.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 54.

  40. 40.

    Green Paper on Digital Platforms (n 29), p. 26.

  41. 41.

    Online Platform Communication (n 28), p. 2.

  42. 42.

    Facebook, Amazon, Apple, Netflix and Google (acronym).

  43. 43.

    Uber, Tinder, Airbnb, Tripadvisor, eBay etc.

  44. 44.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 11.

  45. 45.

    Federal Cartel Office (BKartA), B6-113/15, ‘Working Paper – The Market Power of Platforms and Networks – Executive Summary’ (June 2016), available at <https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/EN/Berichte/Think-Tank-Bericht-Zusammenfassung.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=4> accessed 6 February 2023, 9 (Federal Cartel Office Working Paper).

  46. 46.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 36.

  47. 47.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 17.

  48. 48.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 3.

  49. 49.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 15.

  50. 50.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 3.

  51. 51.

    Frishammara et al. (2008), p. 35 (‘Shopping Mall Case Study’).

  52. 52.

    Ibid.

  53. 53.

    Shopping Mall Case Study (n 51), p. 4.

  54. 54.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 42.

  55. 55.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), paras 39–40.

  56. 56.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 35.

  57. 57.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 5, see also Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 42.

  58. 58.

    Ibid.

  59. 59.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 42.

  60. 60.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 43.

  61. 61.

    Despite cost savings as there is no need to duplicate fixed costs.

  62. 62.

    Market tipping describes markets where the increase in a firm’s market share dominance is caused by indirect network effects.

  63. 63.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 17.

  64. 64.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 46.

  65. 65.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 13.

  66. 66.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 49.

  67. 67.

    Federal Cartel Office Working Paper (n 45), p. 14.

  68. 68.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 7, see also Monopolies Commission Report (n 36) para 49.

  69. 69.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 7.

  70. 70.

    Ibid.

  71. 71.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 8.

  72. 72.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 9.

  73. 73.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), paras 198–220.

  74. 74.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 9.

  75. 75.

    Federal Cartel Office Working Paper (n 45), p. 14.

  76. 76.

    Federal Cartel Office Working Paper (n 45), p. 16.

  77. 77.

    Federal Cartel Office Working Paper (n 45), p. 15.

  78. 78.

    There is a vast body of literature on the topic of data, privacy and competition law considering different angles. To this effect see the following excerpt: Robertson (2020); Majcher and Robertson (2022), pp. 622–646; Kemp (2020), pp. 628–672; Volmar and Helmdach (2018), pp. 195–215; Townley et al. (2017), pp. 638–748; Kerber (2016), pp. 856–866.

  79. 79.

    Federal Cartel Office, Competition Law and Data (Report 10th May, 2016) available at <https://www.bundeskartellamt.de/SharedDocs/Publikation/DE/Berichte/Big%20Data%20Papier.pdf?__blob=publicationFile&v=2> accessed 6 February 2023, 8 (Competition Law and Data Report).

  80. 80.

    Haucap and Heimeshoff (2013), p. 8.

  81. 81.

    Competition Law and Data Report (n 79), p. 11.

  82. 82.

    Monopolies Commission Report (n 36), para 72.

  83. 83.

    Ibid.

  84. 84.

    Competition Law and Data Report (n 79), p. 9.

  85. 85.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6), p. 17.

  86. 86.

    Some online platform businesses do have marginal or distribution costs such as ‘a piece of hardware, ecommerce warehouses, or maintenance of scooters for example’ (Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report [n 6], p. 17).

  87. 87.

    Market Structure and Antitrust Subcommittee Report (n 6) 17.

  88. 88.

    Petropoulus (2018), para 8.

  89. 89.

    Ibid.

  90. 90.

    Mandrescu (2017), pp. 353–365.

  91. 91.

    E-Commerce Sector Inquiry Report (n 24), paras 14–15.

  92. 92.

    E-Commerce Sector Inquiry Report (n 24), para 16.

  93. 93.

    Petropoulus (2018), para 2.

  94. 94.

    Ibid.

  95. 95.

    European Commission, ‘Sector inquiry into e-commerce’ available at <https://ec.europa.eu/competition-policy/sectors/ict/sector-inquiry-e-commerce_en> accessed 6 February 2023; Commerce Sector Inquiry Report (n 24), para 9.

  96. 96.

    Akman and Sokol (2017), p. 137.

  97. 97.

    Akman and Sokol (2017), p. 137.

  98. 98.

    Zelger (2018), p. 451.

  99. 99.

    Ibid.

  100. 100.

    Akman and Sokol (2017), p. 137.

  101. 101.

    Furthermore, RPM would also address such problem by eliminating the possibility of undercutting the price of the product by determining or guaranteeing the retailers a certain margin. However, although there are voices pleading for an effect-based approach of RPM (Ioannidou and Nowag 2015) tendencies to actually shift this view and align it with the US approach seem rather unlikely (for more details see above under Sect. 3.1.3).

  102. 102.

    To name a few examples, ist transparency, ist fast-changing and dynamic nature, low or no marginal cost, platforms and two-sided markets, global reach, etc.

  103. 103.

    See above Sects. 5.2.2–5.2.3.

  104. 104.

    Posner (2000), p. 2; Monopolkommission, ‘Wettbewerbspolitik: Herausforderung digitale Märkte – Sondergutachten der Monopolkommission gemäß § 44 Abs. 1 Satz 4 GWB – Kurzfassung’, available at <https://www.monopolkommission.de/images/PDF/SG/SG68/S68_Kurzfassung.pdf> accessed 6 February 2023 (Monopolies Commission Report Summary), para K50.

  105. 105.

    For reading as regards new phenomena to collude via algorithms and AI, see, for example: Ezrachi and Stucke (2016); Ezrachi and Stucke (2015); Ezrachi and Stucke (2018); Ezrachi (2018b).

Bibliography

Monographies, Commenteries, Book Contributions and Articles

  • Akman P, Sokol D (2017) Online RPM and MFN under antitrust law and economics. Rev Ind Org 50:133–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ezrachi A, Stucke ME (2016) Virtual competition the promise and perils of the algorithm-driven economy. Harvard University Press, Harvard

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Filistrucchi L, Gerard D, van Damme E, Affeldt P (2013) Market definition in two-sided markets: theory and practice. Tilburg Law School Legal Studies Research Paper Series No. 09/2013

    Google Scholar 

  • Frishammara J, Cenamorb J, Cavalli-Björkmanc H, Hernelld E, Carlsson J (2008) Digital strategies for two-sided markets: a case study of shopping malls. Decis Supp Syst 108:34–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haucap J, Heimeshoff U (2013) Google, Facebook, Amazon, eBay: Is the Internet Driving Competition or Market Monopolization?, Discussion Paper. Düsseldorf Institute for Economics (January 2013)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ioannidou M, Nowag J (2015) Can two wrongs make it right? Reconsidering minimum resale price maintenance in the light of Allianz Hungaria. Eur Compet J 11:340–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp K (2020) Concealed data practices and competition law: why privacy matters. Eur Compet J 16:628–672

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerber W (2016) Digital markets, data, and privacy: competition law, consumer law and data protection. J Intell Prop Law Pract 11:856–866

    Google Scholar 

  • Majcher K, Robertson V (2022) Protecting personal data and the environment: doctrinal challenges for EU competition law in our day and age. Eur Law Rev 47:622–646

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandrescu D (2017) Applying EU competition law to online platforms: the road ahead – Part 1 (May 17, 2017). Eur Compet Law Rev 38(8): 353-365., Part I (last paragraph) available at SSRN <https://ssrn.com/abstract=3117840> Accessed 6 Feb 2023.

  • Petropoulus G (2018) Vertical restraints and e-commerce. Concurrence N 1-2018. Law Econ

    Google Scholar 

  • Robertson V (2020) Excessive data collection: Privacy considerations and abuse of dominance in the era of big data. Common Mark Law Rev 57:161–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Townley C, Morrison E, Yeung K (2017) Big data and personalized price discrimination in EU competition law. Yearb Eur Law 36:638–748

    Google Scholar 

  • Volmar MN, Helmdach KO (2018) Protecting consumers and their data through competition law? Rethinking abuse of dominance in light of the Federal Cartel Office’s Facebook investigation. Eur Compet J 14:195–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zelger B (2018) Restrictions of online sales and vertical agreements: Bundeskartellamt vs. Commission? Why Coty and Asics are compatible. Eur Compet J 14(2–3):445–461

    Google Scholar 

Government and Ministry White Papers, Reports, Working Papers

Online Contributions

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Zelger, B. (2023). Particularities of the Digital Economy. In: Restrictions of EU Competition Law in the Digital Age. Studies in European Economic Law and Regulation, vol 25. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-31339-4_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-31339-4_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-031-31338-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-031-31339-4

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics