Skip to main content

Relative Absence Concerns, Positional Consumption Preferences and Working Hours

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Power and Responsibility

Abstract

Positional income or consumption preferences can induce individuals to work too much to enhance their relative standing. Empirical evidence suggests that people are also characterised by relative considerations with respect to sickness-related absence from work. We analyse theoretically how relative consumption and absence concerns interact. Although relative absence concerns may mitigate the consequences of relative consumption preferences, the market outcome will never be efficient. Hence, we derive the income tax rate and the level of sick pay which induce efficient behaviour as the market outcome.

Manfred Holler’s list of publications (in Google Scholar) contains more than 400 entries. Few of them explicitly deal with labour issues—although he has written two textbooks in German on labour economics (Goerke & Holler, 1997; Holler, 1986). My academic interests, which developed during the work as Manfred’s chair in Hamburg, attest to the climate of intellectual openness and curiosity, which he created. Braham and Steffen (2008, p. vi) write in their introduction to the Festschrift for Manfred’s 60th birthday: ‘(H)e has always made every effort to free his staff from unnecessary administrative burdens and he never burdened anyone with his own work’. This implied that staff members were free to pursue their own research projects, also if only modestly linked to or even without any relationship to Manfred’s work. While, to the best of my knowledge, Manfred has not worked on positional concerns, the present analysis was certainly inspired by his attitude of openness and tolerance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    See, for example, Seidman (1988), Choudhary and Levine (2006) and Arrow and Dasgupta (2009). Gómez (2008) presents a growth model in which the market equilibrium is efficient if the consumption and leisure externality have the same intensity. In the set-up by Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2013), there is asymmetric information with respect to ability, such that the two externalities would not balance out, even if they were equally strong. Alpizar et al. (2005) and Carlsson et al. (2007) present evidence based on hypothetical choice experiments that positional leisure preferences are less pronounced than relative income considerations.

  2. 2.

    See, inter alia, Duesenberry (1949), Boskin and Sheshinski (1978), Persson (1995), Ireland (1998), Corneo (2002), Gómez (2008), Dodds (2012), Aronsson and Johansson-Stenman (2013), Eckerstorfer (2014), Wendner (2014) and Goerke and Neugart (2021).

  3. 3.

    There are further contributions which point into the same direction. Aronsson et al. (1999) analyse the implications of interdependent labour supply behaviour for estimated labour supply elasticities, using repeated cross-sectional data from Sweden. They find that average working hours in a reference group raise individual labour supply. Pingle and Mitchell (2002) set up a hypothetical choice experiment. They present individuals with combinations of working time and income and report that the average level of hours worked affect individuals’ choices.

  4. 4.

    Palme and Persson (2020, Sect. 4) concisely review pertinent empirical studies. Miraglia and Johns (2021) provide a much broader survey of the literature on social determinants of absence behaviour, also including contributions from economics. To the best of our knowledge, the implications of relative absence concerns have not yet been analysed in a theoretical model. Somewhat related to our analysis, Skåtun and Skåtun (2004) analyse an efficiency wage model in which individuals can choose hours of work. The authors interpret this choice as a decision about absence behaviour. They assume that fewer hours worked by colleagues raise the workload of individuals and, hence, reduce the individual's working hours as well. The main prediction of the model is that, in contrast to traditional shirking frameworks, employment may be higher in the presence of efficiency wages than in their absence.

  5. 5.

    Bradley et al. (2014) investigate the impact of a move from temporary to permanent employment on absenteeism for public sector employees in Australia. In some of their specifications they include an indicator of the average absence level at the employee's workplace. The estimated coefficients are consistently positive and significant.

  6. 6.

    Absence can also have detrimental effects on future wages and employment (see, e.g., Hansen, 2000; Hesselius, 2007; Markussen, 2012; Scoppa & Vuri, 2014). While we do not model such consequences explicitly, one feasible short-cut in order to incorporate them into the model is the above assumption that utility from absence is distinct from that due to leisure.

  7. 7.

    Carrieri (2012) found that a higher sickness level of a reference group reduces well-being. If (1) higher sickness induces people to be absent more and (2) utility from absence can be approximated by subjective well-being, Carrieri’s (2012) result suggests v2 < 0. However, this line of argument may be problematic, given survey results that positional concerns with regard to health are relatively weak (cf. Solnick & Hemenway, 2005; Grolleau & Saïd, 2008; Wouters et al., 2015). These findings from surveys contrast with evidence from panel data for Australia (cf. Mujcic & Frijters, 2015) according to which the self-assessed health status of a peer group is consistently and strongly associated with a reduction in life satisfaction.

  8. 8.

    The subsequent findings are unaffected by the assumption that sick pay is untaxed, unless noted below (cf. Proposition 3). To focus on relative absence and consumption concerns, the model developed below is static. As mentioned above, there is substantial evidence that sickness-related absence has detrimental long-term labour market effects (Hansen, 2000; Hesselius, 2007; Markussen, 2012; Scoppa & Vuri, 2014). An alternative or additional way of including this empirical observation in the present static setting is the assumption that sick pay is less than the net wage, i.e. s < w[1 − t].

  9. 9.

    Note that terms in square brackets describe multiplicative components, while parentheses indicate a functional dependence.

  10. 10.

    It could be argued that absence has a distinct, positive utility effect. If, therefore, preferences were given by u(c, \(\overline{c}\)) − H(h, a) + v(a, γ\(\overline{a}\)), where the partial derivatives are \(\tilde{H}_{1}\) < 0 < \(\tilde{H}_{2}\), the nature of the first-order conditions for individual choices and for the characterisation of Pareto-efficiency would not be altered under mild additional restrictions (see Appendix 4). Hence, the findings derived below are unlikely to be affected.

  11. 11.

    Since effort is too low in market equilibrium and declines with sick pay, such payments can be argued to reduce presenteeism (see Pichler and Ziebarth (2017) for according empirical evidence).

  12. 12.

    Since the Pareto-efficient consumption level may be higher or lower if there are absence externalities than in a setting without such externalities, the magnitude of t*(c*, γ), relative to \(\hat{t}\), cannot be determined. An exception arises if consumption levels are the same, as it will be true for an iso-elastic utility function u. Since the Pareto-efficient consumption level does not vary with γ in such a setting, tax rates are also the same, i.e. t*(c*, γ) = \(\hat{t}\).

  13. 13.

    If sick pay were taxed, the level inducing efficient behaviour would have to be higher in absolute terms in order to counteract the mitigating impact of taxes and given by s*(c*, a*, γ) = γv2(a*, γ)/(u1(c*, c*, γ) + u2(c*, c*, γ)).

References

  • Alpizar, F., Carlsson, F., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2005). How much do we care about absolute versus relative income and consumption? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 56(5), 405–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez-Cuadrado, F. (2007). Envy, leisure, and restrictions on working hours. Canadian Journal of Economics, 40(6), 1286–1310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson, T., Blomquist, S., & Sacklén, H. (1999). Identifying interdependent behaviour in an empirical model of labour supply. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 14(4), 607–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson, T., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2010). Positional concerns in an OLG-model: Optimal labor and capital income taxation. International Economic Review, 51(4), 1071–1095.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson, T., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2013). Conspicuous leisure: Optimal income taxation when both relative consumption and relative leisure matter. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 115(1), 155–175.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson, T., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2018). Paternalism against Veblen: Optimal taxation and non-respected preferences for social comparisons. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 10(1), 39–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., & Dasgupta, P. S. (2009). Conspicuous consumption, inconspicuous leisure. The Economic Journal, 119(541), F497-516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boskin, M. T., & Sheshinski, E. (1978). Optimal redistributive taxation when individual welfare depends upon relative income. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 92(4), 589–601.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Bracha, A., Gneezy, U., & Loewenstein, G. (2015). Relative pay and labor supply. Journal of Labor Economics, 33(2), 297–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley, S., Green, C., & Leeves, G. (2007). Worker absence and shirking: Evidence from matched teacher-school data. Labour Economics, 14(5), 319–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley, S., Green, C., & Leeves, G. (2014). Employment protection, threat and incentives effects on worker absence. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 52(2), 333–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braham, M., & Steffen, F. (Eds.). (2008). Power, freedom, and voting—Essays in honour of Manfred J. Holler. Springer-Verlag.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Breza, E., Kaur, S., & Shamdasani, Y. (2018). The morale effects of pay inequality. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(2), 611–663.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Cahuc, P., & Postel-Vinay, F. (2005). Social status and the overworked consumer. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, 78, 143–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrieri, V. (2012). Social comparison and subjective well-being: Does the health of others matter? Bulletin of Economic Research, 64(1), 31–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, F., Johansson-Stenman, O., & Martinsson, P. (2007). Do you enjoy having more than others? Survey evidence of positional goods. Economica, 74(No. 296), 586–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choudhary, M. A., & Levine, P. (2006). Idle worship. Economics Letters, 90(1), 77–83.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. E., Frijters, P., & Shields, M. A. (2008). Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(1), 95–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, G. (2002). The efficient side of progressive income taxation. European Economic Review, 46(7), 1359–1368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dale-Olsen, H., Østbakken, K. M., & Schøne, P. (2015). Imitation, contagion, or exertion? Using a tax reform to reveal how colleagues’ sick leave influences worker behaviour. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 117(1), 57–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Paola, M. (2010). Absenteeism and peer interaction effects: Evidence from an Italian Public Institute. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 39(5), 420–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dodds, S. (2012). Redistributive taxation with heterogeneous relative consumption concerns. Canadian Journal of Economics, 45(1), 220–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolan, P., Peasgood, T., & White, M. (2008). Do we really know what makes us happy? A review of the economic literature on the factors associated with subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Psychology, 29(1), 94–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry, J. S. (1949). Income, savings and the theory of consumer behavior. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dupor, B., & Liu, W.-F. (2003). Jealousy and equilibrium overconsumption. American Economic Review, 93(1), 423–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckerstorfer, P. (2014). Relative consumption concerns and the optimal tax mix. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16(6), 936–958.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, W. H., & Hof, F. X. (2008). The quest for status and endogenous labor supply: The relative wealth framework. Journal of Economics, 93(2), 109–144.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1985). The demand for unobservable and other nonpositional goods. American Economic Review, 75(1), 101–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frick, B., & Malo, M. Á. (2008). Labor market institutions and individual absenteeism in the European Union: The relative importance of sickness benefit systems and employment protection legislation. Industrial Relations, 47(6), 505–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godøy, A., & Dale-Olsen, H. (2018). Spillovers from gatekeeping—Peer effects in absenteeism. Journal of Public Economics, 167, 190–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goerke, L. (2019). Absence from work, sick pay and positional consumption concerns. Labour: Review of Labour Economics and Industrial Relations, 33(2), 187–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goerke, L., & Hillesheim, I. (2013). Relative consumption, working time and trade unions. Labour Economics, 24, 170–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goerke, L., & Holler, M. J. (1997). Arbeitsmarktmodelle. Springer-Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goerke, L., & Neugart, M. (2021). Social preferences, monopsony, and government intervention. Canadian Journal of Economics, 54(2), 864–891.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gómez, M. A. (2008). Consumption and leisure externalities, economic growth and equilibrium efficiency. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 55(2), 227–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grolleau, G., & Saïd, S. (2008). Do you prefer having more or more than others? Survey evidence on positional concerns in France. Journal of Economic Issues, 42(6), 1145–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, J. (2000). The effect of work absence on wages and wage gaps in Sweden. Journal of Population Economics, 13(1), 45–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heffetz, O. (2011). A test of conspicuous consumption: Visibility and income elasticities. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(6), 1101–1117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hesselius, P. (2007). Does sickness absence increase the risk of unemployment? The Journal of Socio-Economics, 36(2), 288–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hesselius, P., Johansson, P., & Nilsson, J. P. (2009). Sick of your colleagues’ absence? Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2–3), 583–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hesselius, P., Johansson, P., & Vikström, J. (2013). Social behaviour in work absence. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 115(6), 995–1019.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. (1986). Ökonomische Theorie des Arbeitsmarktes. Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ichino, A., & Maggi, G. (2000). Work environment and individual background: Explaining regional shirking differentials in a large Italian firm. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(5), 1057–1090.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, N. J. (1998). Status-seeking, income taxation and efficiency. Journal of Public Economics, 70(1), 99–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson, P., Karimi, A., & Nilsson, J. P. (2019). Worker absenteeism: Peer influences, monitoring, and job flexibility. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society A, 182(Part 2), 605–621.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, P., Kooreman, P., Soetevent, A., & Kypteyn, A. (2011). The effects of lottery prizes on winners and their neighbors: Evidence from the Dutch postcode lottery. American Economic Review, 101(5), 2226–2247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., Palme, M., & Persson, M. (2016). Sickness absence and local benefit cultures. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 118(1), 49–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, W.-F., & Turnovsky, S. J. (2005). Consumption externalities, production externalities and long-run macroeconomic efficiency. Journal of Public Economics, 89(5–6), 1097–1129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist, L., & Uhlig, H. (2000). Tax policy and aggregate demand management under catching up with the Joneses. American Economic Review, 90(5), 356–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markussen, S. (2012). The individual cost of sick leave. Journal of Population Economics, 25(6), 1287–1306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miraglia, M., & Johns, G. (2021). The social and relational dynamics of absenteeism from work: A multilevel review and integration. Academy of Management Annals, 15(1), 37–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MISSOC (Mutual Information System on Social Protection). (2021). Comparative tables database—Sickness cash benefits. Retrieved December 15, 2021.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mujcic, R., & Frijters, P. (2015). Conspicuous consumption, conspicuous health, and optimal taxation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 111, 59–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumark, D., & Postlewaite, A. (1998). Relative income and the rise in married women’s employment. Journal of Public Economics, 70(1), 157–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2010). Sickness, disability, and work: Breaking the barriers—A synthesis of findings across OECD countries, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palme, M., & Persson, M. (2020). Sick pay insurance and sickness absence: Some European cross-country observations and a review of previous research. Journal of Economic Surveys, 34(1), 85–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park, Y. (2010). The second paycheck to keep up with the Joneses: Relative income concerns and labor market decisions of married women. Eastern Economic Journal, 36(2), 255–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pérez-Asenjo, E. (2011). If happiness is relative, against whom do we compare ourselves? Implications for labour supply. Journal of Population Economics, 24(6), 1411–1442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, M. (1995). Why are taxes so high in egalitarian societies? The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97(6), 569–580.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Pichler, S., & Ziebarth, N. R. (2017). The pros and cons of sick pay schemes: Testing for contagious presenteeism and noncontagious absenteeism behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 156, 14–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pingle, M., & Mitchell, M. (2002). What motivates positional concerns for income? Journal of Economic Psychology, 23(1), 127–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schor, J. (1991). The overworked American: The unexpected decline of leisure. Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scoppa, V., & Vuri, D. (2014). Absenteeism, unemployment and employment protection legislation: Evidence from Italy. IZA Journal of Labor Economics, 3, 3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seidman, L. S. (1988). The welfare costs of a relativistic economy. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 11(2), 295–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skåtun, D. R., & Skåtun, J. D. (2004). The impact of turnout on turning up: The complementarity of attendance among co-workers. Journal of Economics, 83(5), 225–242.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Solnick, S. J., & Hemenway, D. (2005). Are positional concerns stronger in some domains than in others? American Economic Review P & P, 95(2), 147–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wendner, R. (2014). Ramsey, Pigou, heterogeneous agents, and nonatmospheric consumption externalities. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16(3), 491–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wouters, S., van Exel, N., Job, A., van de Donk, M., Rohde, K. I. M., & Brouwer, W. B. F. (2015). Do people desire to be healthier than other people? A short note on positional concerns for health. European Journal of Health Economics, 16(1), 47–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Laszlo Goerke .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix

1. Utility Maximum

From an individual’s perspective, the reference levels of consumption and absence, profits, the tax rate and the lump-sum transfer are constant. Therefore, the second-order conditions for a maximum are given by Zhh, Zaa < 0 < ZhhZaa − (Zah)2, where Zh and Za are defined in Eqs. (3a) and (3b) and the net wage equals \(w^{{\text{N}}}\) = w[1 − t].

$$Z_{{{\text{hh}}}} = u_{11} \left[ {w^{{\text{N}}} } \right]^{2} - H^{\prime\prime} < 0$$
(15a)
$$Z_{{{\text{aa}}}} = u_{11} \left[ {s - w^{{\text{N}}} } \right]^{2} + v_{11} < 0$$
(15b)
$$Z_{{{\text{ha}}}} = Z_{{{\text{ah}}}} = u_{11} w^{{\text{N}}} \left[ {s - w^{{\text{N}}} } \right] \ge 0$$
(15c)

Hence, we have

$$Z_{{{\text{hh}}}} Z_{{{\text{aa}}}} - \mathop {Z_{{{\text{ah}}}} }\nolimits^{2} = u_{11} \left[ {v_{11} \left[ {w^{{\text{N}}} } \right]^{2} - H^{\prime\prime}\left[ {s - w^{{\text{N}}} } \right]^{2} } \right] - H^{\prime\prime}v_{11} > 0$$
(16)

2. Stability of Market Equilibrium

In equilibrium, lump-sum payments, T, are determined endogenously in order to balance the budget. Thus, T = wt[h − a]. Moreover, profits as defined in (4) are paid out to individuals and affect their consumption. Hence, the equilibrium level of consumption equals production:

$$\begin{aligned} c^{{\text{m}}} = & w\left[ {1 {-} t} \right]\left[ {h^{{\text{m}}} {-}a^{{\text{m}}} } \right] + sa^{{\text{m}}} + wt\left[ {h^{{\text{m}}} {-}a^{m}} \right] + f\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} {-}a^{{\text{m}}} } \right) - w\left[ {h^{{\text{m}}} {-}a^{{\text{m}}} } \right] - sa^{{\text{m}}} \\ = & \,f\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} {-}a^{{\text{m}}} } \right) \\ \end{aligned}$$
(17)

To ascertain whether the market equilibrium is stable, we calculate the Jacobian determinant \(\left| J \right|\) of the system defined by Eqs. (3a), (3b) and (5), taking into account (17). Moreover, all individuals behave identically. Hence, changes in consumption, c, and the reference level, \(\overline{c}\), are the same. Similarly, the variations in a and \(\overline{a}\) coincide. Thus, the derivatives of (3a), (3b) and (5) with respect to contractual hours, h, absence, a, and wages, w, incorporating (17), are given by πhh = f″ = −πha < 0, πhw = −1 and:

$$Z_{{{\text{hh}}}}^{{\text{e}}} = \left[ {u_{11} + u_{12} } \right]f^{\prime}w^{{\text{N}}} - H^{\prime\prime} < 0$$
(18a)
$$Z_{{{\text{aa}}}}^{{\text{e}}} = - \left[ {u_{11} + u_{12} } \right]f^{\prime}\left[ {s - w^{{\text{N}}} } \right] + v_{11} + \gamma v_{12} < 0$$
(18b)
$$Z_{{{\text{ha}}}}^{{\text{e}}} = - \left[ {u_{11} + u_{12} } \right]w^{{\text{N}}} f^{\prime} > 0$$
(18c)
$$Z_{{{\text{ah}}}}^{{\text{e}}} = \left[ {u_{11} + u_{12} } \right]\left[ {s - w^{{\text{N}}} } \right]f^{\prime} > 0$$
(18d)
$$Z_{{{\text{hw}}}}^{{\text{e}}} = u_{1} \left[ {1 - t} \right] = - Z_{{{\text{aw}}}}^{{\text{e}}} > 0$$
(18e)

In (18a) to (18e), we use the superscript e to indicate that equilibrium repercussions via lump-sum payments T and profits are incorporated. The Jacobian determinant \(\left| J \right|\) of the system defined by the modified Eqs. (3a), (3b) and (5) is negative.

$$\begin{aligned} \left| J \right| = & - \left[ {Z_{{{\text{hh}}}}^\text{e} Z_{{{\text{aa}}}}^\text{e} - Z_{{{\text{ha}}}}^\text{e} Z_{{{\text{ah}}}}^\text{e} } \right] - f^{\prime\prime}Z_{{{\text{hw}}}}^\text{e} \left[ {Z_{{{\text{ha}}}}^\text{e} + Z_{{{\text{aa}}}}^\text{e} + Z_{{{\text{hh}}}}^\text{e} + Z_{{{\text{ah}}}}^\text{e} } \right] \\ = & \, - H^{\prime\prime}\left[ {\left[ {u_{11} + u_{12} } \right]\left[ {s - w^{{\text{N}}} } \right]f^{\prime} - \left[ {v_{11} + \gamma v_{12} } \right]} \right] \\ & + \,f^{\prime\prime}u_{1} \left[ {1 - t} \right]\left[ {H^{\prime\prime} - \left[ {v_{11} + \gamma v_{12} } \right]} \right] < 0 \\ \end{aligned}$$
(19)

3. Pareto-Efficient Allocation

The second-order conditions for a maximum of Γ are

$$\Gamma_{{{\text{hh}}}} = \left[ {u_{11} + 2u_{12} + u_{22} } \right]\left[ {f^{\prime}} \right]^{2} + \left[ {u_{1} + u_{2} } \right]f^{\prime\prime} - H^{\prime\prime} < 0$$
(20a)
$$\Gamma_{{{\text{aa}}}} = \left[ {u_{11} + 2u_{12} + u_{22} } \right]\left[ {f^{\prime}} \right]^{2} + \left[ {u_{1} + u_{2} } \right]f^{\prime\prime} + v_{11} + 2\gamma v_{12} + \gamma^{2} v_{22} < 0$$
(20b)

and \({\text{Det}} = \Gamma_{{{\text{hh}}}} \Gamma_{{{\text{aa}}}} - \mathop {\Gamma_{{{\text{ha}}}} }\nolimits^{2} > 0\). Using

$$\Gamma_{{{\text{ha}}}} = - \underbrace {{\left[ {u_{11} + 2u_{12} + u_{22} } \right]}}_{\left( - \right)}\left[ {f^{\prime}} \right]^{2} - \underbrace {{\left[ {u_{1} + u_{2} } \right]f^{\prime\prime}}}_{\left( - \right)} = - \Gamma_{{{\text{hh}}}} - H^{\prime\prime} > 0,$$
(21)

the determinant of the system of Eqs. (8a) and (8b) is found to be positive.

$$\begin{aligned} {\text{Det}} = & \underbrace {{\left[ {\left[ {u_{11} + 2u_{12} + u_{22} } \right]\left[ {f^{\prime}} \right]^{2} + \left[ {u_{1} + u_{2} } \right]f^{\prime\prime}} \right]}}_{\left( - \right)}\underbrace {{\left[ {v_{11} + 2\gamma v_{12} + \gamma^{2} v_{22} - H^{\prime\prime}} \right]}}_{\left( - \right)} \\ & - \,H^{\prime\prime}\underbrace {{\left[ {v_{11} + 2\gamma v_{12} + \gamma^{2} v_{22} } \right]}}_{\left( - \right)} > 0 \\ \end{aligned}$$
(22)

4. Alternative Specification of Preferences

Suppose preferences are given by

$$\tilde{Z}\left( {h,a} \right) = u\left( {c,\overline{c}} \right) - \tilde{H}\left( {h,a} \right) + v\left( {a,\gamma \overline{a}} \right),$$
(23)

where \(\tilde{H}_{1}\) < 0 < \(\tilde{H}_{2}\). Pareto-efficiency can then be characterised by maximising:

$$\tilde{\Gamma }\left( {h,a} \right) = u\left( {c\left( {h,a} \right),\overline{c}\left( {\overline{h},\overline{a}} \right)} \right) - \tilde{H}\left( {h,a} \right) + v\left( {a,\gamma \overline{a}} \right)$$
(24)

The first-order conditions for individually optimal choices and describing Pareto-efficiency are

$$\tilde{Z}_{h} = u_{1} w\left[ {1 - t} \right] - \tilde{H}_{1} \left( {h,a} \right) = 0$$
(25a)
$$\tilde{Z}_{{\text{a}}} = u_{1} \left[ {s - w^{{\text{N}}}} \right] - \tilde{H}_{2} \left( {h,a} \right) + v_{1} = 0$$
(25b)
$$\tilde{\Gamma }_{{\text{h}}} = \left[ {u_{1} + u_{2} } \right]f^{\prime}\left( {h - a} \right) - \tilde{H}_{1} \left( {h,a} \right) = 0$$
(26a)
$$\tilde{\Gamma }_{{\text{a}}} = - \left[ {u_{1} + u_{2} } \right]f^{\prime}\left( {h - a} \right) - \tilde{H}_{2} \left( {h,a} \right) + v_{1} + \gamma v_{2} = 0$$
(26b)

The properties of the model will be unaffected if (1) \(\tilde{H}_{2}\) is not too large in absolute value such that (25b) and (26b) define interior solutions for absence choices, and (2) v1(a, \(\gamma \overline{a}\)) − \(\tilde{H}_{2} \left( {h,a} \right)\) exhibits the same qualitative features as v1(a, \(\gamma \overline{a}\)) with respect to a.

5. Proof of Proposition 2

Part (a): If income is untaxed, working hours will be excessive, there will be too little absence from work and, hence, effort and consumption will also be excessive.

The combination of (11a), (11b), and (12a), (12b) shows that

$$H^{\prime}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} } \right) = v_{1} \left( {a^{{\text{m}}} } \right)$$
(27a)

and

$$H^{\prime}\left( {h^{*}} \right) = v_{1} \left( {a^{*}} \right).$$
(27b)

Given the assumptions on the derivatives (H′, H″, v1 > 0 > v11), there are three possible combinations of market outcomes relative to the efficient combination:

Case (1): hm = h* and am = a*,

Case (2): hm < h* such that H′(hm) < H′(h*) and v1(am) < v1(a*), which implies am > a*,

Case (3): hm > h* and am < a*, according to the same line of argument as in Case (2).

In Case (1), Eqs. (27a) and (27b) hold, but (11a) and (12a), respectively (11b) and (12b), cannot be satisfied simultaneously. Therefore, hm = h* and am = a* do not guarantee that the conditions which characterise the market equilibrium and the efficient outcome are both fulfilled.

In Case (2), hm − am < h* − a* results, which implies that cm = f(hm − am) < c* = f(h* − a*) holds. This, in turn, indicates that f′(hm − am) > f′(h* − a*) and u1(cm) > u1(c*) due to the strict concavity of f and u. Furthermore, deducting (12a) from (11a) yields

$$\begin{aligned} u_{1} \left( {c^{{\text{m}}} ,\overline{c}} \right)f^{\prime}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} - a^{{\text{m}}} } \right) - & H^{\prime}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} } \right) - \left[ {\left[ {u_{1} \left( {c^{*},c^{*}} \right) + u_{2} \left( {c^{*},c^{*}} \right)} \right]f^{\prime}\left( {h^{*} - a^{*}} \right) - H^{\prime}\left( {h^{*}} \right)} \right] \\ = & \,\underbrace {{u_{1} \left( {c^{{\text{m}}} ,\overline{c}} \right)f^{\prime}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} - a^{{\text{m}}} } \right) - u_{1} \left( {c^{*},c^{*}} \right)f^{\prime}\left( {h^{*} - a^{*}} \right)}}_{{ = {\text{A}}1}} \\ & + \,\underbrace {{H^{\prime}\left( {h^{*}} \right) - H^{\prime}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} } \right)}}_{{ = {\text{A}}2}} - \underbrace {{u_{2} \left( {c^{*},c^{*}} \right)f^{\prime}\left( {h^{*} - a^{*}} \right)}}_{\left( - \right)} = 0 \\ \end{aligned}$$
(28)

In Case (2), the terms A1 and A2 are positive. Therefore, equality (28) cannot hold and hm < h*, am > a* do not describe the market outcome relative to the efficient situation.

In consequence, the only constellation of working hours and absence which simultaneously guarantees the conditions which describe the market equilibrium and the Pareto-efficient allocation is described by Case (3). If hm > h* and am < a*, cm > c* must also hold. ∎

Part (b): The tax rate \(\hat{t}\):  = t(s = γ = 0) which ensures that individuals choose the optimal number of working hours and the optimal duration of absence is given by

$$0 < \hat{t} = - \frac{{u_{2} \left( {c^{*},c^{*}} \right)}}{{u_{1} \left( {c^{*},c^{*}} \right)}} < 1.$$
(29)

This part can be demonstrated by substituting \(\hat{t}\):  = t(s = γ = 0) = −u2(c*, c*)/u1(c*, c*) in Eqs. (11a) and (11b). Given a unique market equilibrium, it can only be characterised by the values of h and a which fulfil Eqs. (12a) and (12b), i.e. the Pareto-efficient combination. As tax receipts are returned to individuals and they obtain all profit income, consumption will be the same as in the Pareto-efficient allocation, given the same levels of working hours and absence. ∎

6. Sick Pay

In market equilibrium, consumption equals production, cm = f(hm − am). Therefore, the derivatives of the first-order conditions (3a), (3b) and (5) with regard to sick pay, s, are \(Z_{{{\text{hs}}}}^{{\text{e}}}\) = πhs = 0 and \(Z_{{{\text{as}}}}^{{\text{e}}} = u_{1}\). Also taking into account (18a) to (18e), the changes in contractual hours, absence and effort due to a rise in sick pay, s, are found to be

$$\frac{{{\text{d}}h^{{\text{m}}} }}{{{\text{d}}s}} = \frac{{u_{1} }}{\left| J \right|}\left[ {f^{\prime\prime}Z_{{{\text{hw}}}}^{{\text{e}}} - Z_{{{\text{ah}}}}^{{\text{e}}} } \right] > 0$$
(30a)
$$\frac{{{\text{d}}a^{{\text{m}}} }}{{{\text{d}}s}} = \frac{{u_{1} }}{\left| J \right|}\left[ {Z_{{{\text{hh}}}}^{{\text{e}}} + f^{\prime\prime}Z_{{{\text{hw}}}}^{{\text{e}}} } \right] > 0$$
(30b)
$$\frac{{{\text{d}}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} - a^{{\text{m}}} } \right)}}{{{\text{d}}s}} = - \frac{{u_{1} \left[ {u_{11} + u_{12} } \right]f^{\prime}s}}{\left| J \right|} < 0$$
(30c)

7. Proof of Proposition 3

Notation: Market outcomes in a world with absence externalities are denoted by hm(am, γ), am(hm, γ) and cm(hm, am) = cm(hm(am, γ), am(hm, γ)), while the Pareto-efficient allocation is characterised by h*(a*, γ), a*(h*, γ), and c*(γ).

Part (a): If the tax rate is zero (t = 0), sick pay is non-negative (s ≥ 0), and higher absence by the reference group does not raise utility from absence (v2 ≤ 0), working hours in market equilibrium will be excessive, while the differences between Pareto-efficient and market outcomes with respect to absence and consumption are indeterminate.

The comparison of the first-order conditions characterising the market equilibrium and the Pareto-efficient outcome or of a combination of them does not provide insights with respect to the relative levels of working hours and absence. However, it can be shown that only a number of combinations of h, a and h − a are feasible. Basically, the differences [hm(am, γ) − am(hm, γ)] − [h*(a*, γ) − a*(h*, γ)], hm(am, γ) − h*(a*, γ) and am(hm, γ) − a*(h*, γ) could be positive, zero or negative. Hence, the theoretically maximal number of outcomes is 27. To simplify the subsequent argument, note that imposing a sign on the term Diff 1: = hm(am, γ) − am(hm, γ) − [h*(a*, γ) − a*(h*, γ)] = hm(am, γ) − h*(a*, γ) − [am(hm, γ) − a*(h*, γ)] implies that the same sign applies to the difference Diff 2: = cm(hm, am) − c*(γ) because c = f(h − a).

Some of the 27 feasible combinations are logically impossible. If Diff 2 > (<) 0 holds, hm(am, γ) − h*(a*, γ) ≤ (≥) 0 and am(hm, γ) − a*(h*, γ) ≥ (≤) 0 cannot occur simultaneously. This argument rules out 4 (and another 4) of the 27 combinations. Additionally, if Diff 2 = 0 holds, hm(am, γ) − h*(a*, γ) and am(hm, γ) − a*(h*, γ) must have the same signs. Hence, another six combinations cannot describe the market outcome relative to the Pareto-efficient allocation (cf. Table 1).

Table 1 Feasible and impossible combinations of working hours, absence and effort

We next consider the case of Diff 2 ≤ 0 again. This implies that u1(cm) ≥ u1(c*), given u11 + u12 < 0 and f′(hm − am) = w ≥ f′(h* − a*). As a result, u1(cm)w > [u1(c*) + u2(c*)]f′(h* − a*), since u2 < 0. The comparison of (3a) and (8a), assuming t = 0, clarifies that H′(hm) > H′(h*) < 0 must hold, because otherwise the equations cannot be fulfilled simultaneously. Given the convexity of H in h, H′(hm) > H′(h*) implies that hm(am, γ) > h*(a*, γ) holds. Accordingly, all theoretically feasible cases for which Diff 2 ≤ 0 is assumed are only compatible with hm(am, γ) > h*(a*, γ), ruling out a further 6 of the remaining 13 (27 − 4 − 4 − 6) combinations as incompatible with hm(am, γ), am(hm, γ) characterising the market equilibrium and h*(a*, γ), a*(h*, γ) the Pareto-efficient allocation (argument A).

Note that thus far the proof has required no restrictions with respect to sick pay and the sign of v2. Suppose, next, that hm(am, γ) ≤ h*(a*, γ) holds. In accordance with the above line of argument, this implies that H′(hm) < H′(h*) is true. Combining (3a), (3b) and (8a), (8b) yields

$$u_{1} \left( {c^{{\text{m}}} } \right)s - H^{\prime}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} } \right) + v_{1} \left( {a^{{\text{m}}} } \right) = 0$$
(31a)
$$\gamma v_{2} - H^{\prime}\left( {h^{*}} \right) + v_{1} \left( {a^{*}} \right) = 0$$
(31b)

For γv2 < 0 and s ≥ 0 or γv2 = 0 and s > 0, Eqs. (31a) and (31b) can only hold at the same time if v1(am) < v1(a*), that is for am(hm, γ) > a*(h*, γ), and given v11 < 0 (argument B). Hence, two further combinations have been ruled out. Because no further incompatibilities of the first-order conditions, or combinations thereof, can be discerned, the above considerations leave 5 of the 27 permutations (see Table 1). All of them are characterised by hm(am, γ) > h*(a*, γ). ∎

The proof that hm(am, γ) > h*(a*, γ) is the only feasible outcome, assumes either a positive level of sick pay (s > 0) and γv2 ≥ 0, or non-negative sick pay (s ≥ 0) and envy with respect to absence (γv2 < 0); cf. argument B. Therefore, it also covers the case of positive sick pay and no absence externality. Hence, the above argument constitutes an alternative to the proof provided in Appendix 6 establishing that working hours in market equilibrium will be excessive if sick pay is positive.

Part (b): If a higher absence level by the reference group increases the level of absence chosen individually (v12 > 0), a greater strength of relative absence concerns, as captured by an increase in the parameter γ, raises the number of working hours and the duration of absence in market equilibrium, while effort declines.

Since \(Z_{{{\text{h}}\gamma }}^{e} = \pi_{{{\text{h}}\gamma }} = 0\) and \(Z_{{{\text{a}}\gamma }}^{e} = v_{12} \overline{a}\), the changes in working hours, absence and effort are

$$\frac{{{\text{d}}h^{{\text{m}}} }}{{{\text{d}}\gamma }} = - Z_{{{\text{a}}\gamma }}^{{\text{e}}} \underbrace {{\frac{{Z_{{{\text{ah}}}}^{{\text{e}}} + f^{\prime\prime}Z_{{{\text{aw}}}}^{{\text{e}}} }}{\left| J \right|}}}_{\left( - \right)}$$
(32a)
$$\frac{{{\text{d}}a^{{\text{m}}} }}{{{\text{d}}\gamma }} = Z_{{{\text{a}}\gamma }}^{{\text{e}}} \underbrace {{\frac{{Z_{{{\text{hh}}}}^{{\text{e}}} + Z_{{{\text{hw}}}}^{{\text{e}}} f^{\prime\prime}}}{\left| J \right|}}}_{\left( + \right)}$$
(32b)
$$\frac{{{\text{d}}\left( {h^{{\text{m}}} - a^{{\text{m}}} } \right)}}{{{\text{d}}\gamma }} = - Z_{{{\text{a}}\gamma }}^{{\text{e}}} \frac{{Z_{{{\text{hh}}}}^{{\text{e}}} + Z_{{{\text{ha}}}}^{{\text{e}}} }}{\left| J \right|} = Z_{{{\text{a}}\gamma }}^{{\text{e}}} \underbrace {{\frac{{H^{\prime\prime}}}{\left| J \right|}}}_{\left( - \right)}$$
(32c)

Part (c): A greater strength of relative absence concerns has ambiguous consequences for the Pareto-efficient allocation.

The partial derivatives of Eqs. (8a) and (8b) with respect to γ are given by Γhγ = 0 and Γaγ = v2 + (v12 + γv22)\(\overline{a}\). Since Γaγ cannot be signed without specifying the utility function v, the changes in working hours, absence and effort in the Pareto-efficient allocation are ambiguous. ∎

Part (d): The tax rate and level of sick pay which induce a Pareto-efficient allocation as market outcomes are given by \(0 < t^{*}\left( {c^{*},\gamma } \right) = - \frac{{u_{2} \left( {c^{*},c^{*},\gamma } \right)}}{{u_{1} \left( {c^{*},c^{*},\gamma } \right)}} < 1\;{\text{and}}\;s^{*}\left( {c^{*},a^{*},\gamma } \right) = \frac{{\gamma v_{2} \left( {a^{*},\gamma } \right)}}{{u_{1} \left( {c^{*},c^{*},\gamma } \right)}}.\)

Replacing t and s in Eqs. (3a) and (3b) by −u2(c*, c*, γ)/u1(c*, c*, γ) and γv2(a*)/u1(c*, c*, γ) and using w = f′(h − a) from (5) shows that Eqs. (3a) and (3b) will hold for those values of working hours and absence which characterise the Pareto-efficient allocation described by Eqs. (8a) and (8b). All tax payments are returned to individuals via lump-sum payments. Moreover, individuals obtain the entire profit income. Consequently, income and consumption will be the same as in the Pareto-efficient allocation, given hm(am, γ) = h*(a*, γ) and am = a*. ∎

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Goerke, L. (2023). Relative Absence Concerns, Positional Consumption Preferences and Working Hours. In: Leroch, M.A., Rupp, F. (eds) Power and Responsibility. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-23015-8_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics