Skip to main content

Price Formation: General Equilibrium

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economics of Markets

Abstract

This chapter extends the theory to multiple markets where, as in classical economics, wealth is explicitly treated as one of the determinants of reservation prices in market realizations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 49.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a recent multiple-market model of double-auction dynamics, see Asparouhova et al. (2020).

  2. 2.

    Since the horizon \(T\) is assumed given, it will be usually omitted. Yet it is important to keep in mind that the economy’s supply and demand apply to a given period \(\{ 0,...,T\} ,\) which includes the case where the limit \(T = \infty\) is considered. In all rigor, we should index the distribution of unit by \(T,\) writing, for example, \(M_{T}\) and \(N_{T} .\)

  3. 3.

    This is a standard property of line integration. See, for example, Apostol (1969, ch. 10).

  4. 4.

    A technical detail is omitted in the differentiation under the integral (or expectation) sign.

  5. 5.

    To wit: “A market…is theoretically perfect only when all have perfect knowledge of the conditions of supply and demand, and the consequent ratio of exchange; and…there can only be one ratio of exchange of one uniform commodity at any moment” (Jevons (1871 [1888], p. iv).

  6. 6.

    For a review of the neoclassical models of price adjustment and stability, see Negishi (1962), Hahn (1982), and Fisher (2013). Hahn, in his review of neoclassical price dynamics, said: “we shall have to conclude that we still lack a satisfactory descriptive theory of the invisible hand” (Hahn, 1982, p. 746).

  7. 7.

    For a review of SMD theorem and related aggregation literature see Shafer and Sonnenschein (1982). See also Kirman (1989) and Rizvi (2006).

  8. 8.

    Hotelling (1932).

  9. 9.

    In the mathematical theory of dynamics, an equilibrium, when it exists, derives from a dynamical representation of a system: it is not decided a priori and rationalized a posteriori.

References

  • Abdelmalek, N. N. (1974). On the discrete linear L1 approximation and L1 solutions of overdetermined linear equations. Journal of Approximation Theory, 11(1), 38–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apostol, T. M. (1969). Calculus, Volume II: Multi-variable calculus and linear algebra, with applications to differential equations and probability. Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asparouhova, E., Bossaerts, P., & Ledyard, J. O. (2020). Price formation in multiple, simultaneous continuous double auctions, with implications for asset pricing (Social Science Working Paper 1450). California Institute of Technology. https://resolver.caltech.edu/CaltechAUTHORS:20200727-111303655

  • Barbashin, E., & Krasovskii, N. (1961). On stability of motion in the large. Dokl. Akad. Nauk. USSR, 86(3), 453–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. (1974). Excess demand functions. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1(1), 15–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, F. M. (2013). The stability of general equilibrium—What do we know and why is it important? In P. Bridel (Ed.), General equilibrium analysis (pp. 34–45). Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutenbrunner, C., & Jurecková, J. (1992). Regression rank scores and regression quantiles. The Annals of Statistics, 20, 305–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, F. (1982). Stability. In K. J. Arrow & M. D. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics (Vol. 2, pp. 745–793). North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. The American Economic Review, 35(4), 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1932). Edgeworth’s taxation paradox and the nature of demand and supply functions. Journal of Political Economy, 40(5), 577–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jevons, W. S. (1871 [1888]). The theory of political economy. Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirman, A. (1989). The intrinsic limits of modern economic theory: The emperor has no clothes. The Economic Journal, 99(395), 126–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R. (2005). Quantile regression. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R., & Bassett, G., Jr. (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46(1), 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R., & Hallock, K. F. (2001). Quantile Regression. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(4), 143–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krasovskii, N. (1959 [1963]). Problems of the theory of stability of motion [Translated from Russian]. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • LaSalle, J. P. (1960). Some extensions of Liapunov’s second method. IRE Transactions on Circuit Theory, 7(4), 520–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyapunov, A. M. (1892). The general problem of the stability of motion (Doctoral Dissertation, in Russian). University of Kharkov, Kharkov Mathematical Society.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mantel, R. (1974). On the characterization of aggregate excess demand. Journal of Economic Theory, 7(3), 348–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohring, H. (1971). Alternative welfare gain and loss measures. Economic Inquiry, 9(4), 349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Negishi, T. (1962). The stability of a competitive economy: A survey article. Econometrica, 30(4), 635–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizvi, S. A. T. (2006). The Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu results after thirty years. History of Political Economy, 38(suppl. 1), 228–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shafer, W., & Sonnenschein, H. (1982). Market demand and excess demand functions. In K. J. Arrow & M. D. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics (Vol. II, pp. 670–693). North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silberberg, E. (1972). Duality and the many consumer’s surpluses. The American Economic Review, 62(5), 942–952.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776 [1904]). The Wealth of Nations (E. Cannan, Ed., Vol. I–II). Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein, H. (1972). Market excess demand functions. Econometrica, 40(3), 549–563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein, H. (1973a). Do Walras’ identity and continuity characterize the class of community excess demand functions? Journal of Economic Theory, 6(4), 345–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein, H. (1973b). The utility hypothesis and market demand theory. Economic Inquiry, 11(4), 404–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, H. M. (1959). Linear programming techniques for regression analysis. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 54(285), 206–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sabiou M. Inoua .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Inoua, S.M., Smith, V.L. (2022). Price Formation: General Equilibrium. In: Economics of Markets. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-08428-7_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-08428-7_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-031-08427-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-031-08428-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics