Skip to main content

Proper Future Economic Policies

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Visions and Strategies for a Sustainable Economy

Part of the book series: Global Institute for Sustainable Prosperity ((GISP))

  • 206 Accesses

Abstract

This contribution focuses on the macroeconomic policies employed during the Global Financial Crisis and Covid-19, but most importantly on the future economic policies to achieve high levels of economic activity and employment, along with equal distribution of income and wealth. The relevant future economic policies proposed are fiscal, monetary and financial stability. Most importantly these policies need to be properly coordinated if successful economic activity is to be achieved. Such coordination should generate a path for resilient and sustainable growth, enhance productivity and reduce inequality. In terms of inequality, a relevant recent development has emerged. This is the strength of trade union membership, which since 1985 and across OECD countries has been reduced significantly. The problem with such reduction is recognized more recently. Governments and Central Banks around the world should move towards coordination of relevant policies to enhance the strength of trade unions. Fiscal and monetary authorities should introduce and employ safely and properly such coordination to achieve all the goals mentioned above.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    It should be noted that the institutional dimension of the Euro Area needs careful re-design so that its federalist structure is completed, and relevant policies are in place, and properly employed (Arestis, 2019a; Acocella et al., 2016).

  2. 2.

    As Acocella et al. (2016) also suggest “Automatic stabilizers can fail either because they are too limited or because they are not powerful enough in oiling the market mechanism during large recessions, especially when restricted by fiscal rules designed to maintain sustainability” (p. 288).

  3. 3.

    Acocella et al. (2016) provide a short review of fiscal multipliers to conclude that they exceed one in the downturn. Thereby, “austerity policies would be counterproductive in recessionary periods, making public deficits and debt worse rather than better” (p. 166).

  4. 4.

    In the UK, however, household wealth has risen during the pandemic period. The Office for National Statistics reported that this increase emerged from a rise in house prices of 8.5% in 2020, and of government support (as reported in the Financial Times, 30 April 2021).

  5. 5.

    In terms of the Brexit, an independent commission has been set up (April 2021) to closely examine, and improve, the UK’s deals with the EU. This commission includes members of Parliament and business leaders (Financial Times, 12 April 2021).

  6. 6.

    Tenreyro (2021) suggests that “ In Europe, employment support schemes such as the UK government’s furlough scheme mean that governments temporarily take over wage bills to avoid mass unemployment” (p. 6).

  7. 7.

    Savers in the UK are assumed to have accumulated £180bn in their bank accounts (10% of UK’s annual GDP). If all this were to be spent, it would increase consumption about 6% in both 2021 and 2022 (Financial Times, 12 April 2021).

  8. 8.

    The Bank of England and the Treasury, and on 17 March 2020, established the Covid Corporate Financing Facility (CCFF), a lending facility. The aim of the CCFF is to provide lending to large non-financial firms. The Treasury decides which firms can take part in the CCFF.

  9. 9.

    The ECB at its meeting on 21 January 2021 decided to leave its stimulus policies unchanged, and to check further whether bank lending rates, corporate credit conditions, and government bond yields “are favourable enough to boost demand and inflation” (reported in the Financial Times, 22 January 2021). However, further clarification and details of how ‘favourable financing conditions’ is defined are necessary. In any case, a further problem for the ECB is the recent sell-off in bond markets, which is spread to the Euro Area from the USA (where the expectation of higher inflation in view of the expected economic recovery has caused it). As a consequence of this sell-off, the ECB has increased its emergency bond-buying programme to avoid it. The Euro Area bond yields actually did fall.

  10. 10.

    A further QE type, suggested by ecologists, is for Central Banks to provide free funds for green projects. Or finance at a zero interest rate, green bonds from firms engaged in ecological projects.

  11. 11.

    More recently, however, middle of April 2021, Treasury bond prices have increased, in view of higher demand for Treasuries, since investors are uncertain about the impact of the $1.9tr impact on the economy; high inflation is expected. The 10-year Treasury bond rate of interest decreased to 1.55%. This, however, may change if the $1.9tr impact on the economy is successful. USA’s consumer-price index (PCI) was 2.0% in March 2021. It increased from the 1.7% in February 2021, the biggest increase since 2009. It is expected to increase to 3.5% by May 2021 (The Economist, 17 April 2021). Whether a similar increase of the Fed’s price index is consistent with the Fed’s change of its monetary policy framework, as in August 2020, is an interesting question, since no clarification by the Fed on this issue, implies further uncertainty. The April 2021 surge in inflation to 4.2% (the highest annual rate since 2008) produced selling of the 10-year government bonds, with the relevant interest rate increasing to 1.68% (Financial Times, 13 May 2021).

    .

  12. 12.

    In the EMU, the independent Central Bank and the lack of EMU fiscal policy does not allow proper coordination of fiscal and monetary policies. Proper fiscal union is required to allow such a proper coordination of fiscal and monetary policies in the EMU (see, also Arestis and Sawyer, 2011; Sawyer, 2013).

  13. 13.

    As reported in the IMF Press Release No. 20/98 (23 March 2020).

  14. 14.

    It should be noted that the Fed’s inflation targeting is different from other central banks’ (Central Banks follow the Taylor Rule, whereby they manipulate their interest rates to achieve their inflation targets, and also they respond to fluctuations to the output gap). The Fed has two objectives: ‘maximum employment’ and ‘stable prices’ (with 2% its inflation target). In terms of the ‘maximum employment’, which is interpreted as low unemployment, there is the question of the extent to which maximum employment is equivalent to ‘low unemployment’ (Tarullo, 2017, p. 3). Another difference is that the Fed has recently promised to tolerate higher inflation than its target (what is called, ‘average inflation target’, as stated in the Financial Times, 10 and 15 May 2021; with a number of the ECB’s governing council members supporting the Fed proposal for the ECB). This implies that the Fed is prepared to see the real rate of interest reduced, thereby increasing investment and aggregate demand. Whether such a policy can be successful depends heavily on expectations of healthy future economic activity, which are around now in view of the President’s $1.9tn economic stimulus. A relevant development is that in March 2021 the Fed upgraded to 6.5% the growth rate of the US economy, higher than the December 2020 relevant rate of 4.5%. It also stated that it expected to achieve its 2% inflation target, which however it should go back to the target. However, the Fed is expected to keep interest rates close to zero until 2024. By contrast, the Governor of the Bank of England told the House of Lords Economics Affair Committee that if inflation moved above the 2% inflation target of the Bank of England, the Monetary Policy Committee would raise interest rates – but there is not much evidence of this at present (reported in the Financial Times, 19 May 2021).

  15. 15.

    The European Investment Bank has been transformed into a ‘climate bank’; a very interesting development.

  16. 16.

    How much capital should financial institutions hold to make them resilient in the case of significant increase in borrower defaults is a relevant question. Mendicino et al. (2021) explore this question to conclude that a capital ratio of around 15% is in fact optimum.

  17. 17.

    The USA Treasury Secretary, Janet Yellen, suggested in her speech to the Chicago Council on Global Affairs on 05 April 2021, the G20 and other countries should join the USA to set a global minimum corporate tax. This in her view would avoid profit shifting across countries to avoid taxes. Companies would pay taxes where their revenues are earned, not where their profits would be shifted—normally to tax heavens. In addition, this is needed to create a “stable tax system that raise sufficient revenue to invest in essential public goods and respond to crises” (as reported in the Financial Times, 06 April 2021). Janet Yellen also suggested on 07 April 2021 (as reported in the Financial Times on 08 April 2021) that the $2tn plan would produce 1.6% increase to GDP by 2024, alongside roughly $2.5tn in corporate tax increase. According to the Treasury Secretary, these are mutually beneficial policies. European countries have welcomed the suggestion of a global corporate tax, but they disagree over details of the proposal, especially over the minimum corporate tax (Financial Times, 15 April 2021); The UK’s Chancellor of the Exchequer is holding back support of the global corporate tax, arguing that it should be part of a broader package of a fairer system (reported in the Financial Times, 17 May 2021). Janet Yellen (on May 2021), urged Congress to accept higher taxes to pay for the President’s plan of spending. Janet Yellen also suggested that if inflation became an issue, tools are available to address it (reported in the Financial Times, 03 May 2021).

  18. 18.

    The USA President has suggested recently (mid-April 2021) to reduce his infrastructure bill by 60bn in an attempt to get his infrastructure bill through the Congress.

  19. 19.

    Canzoneri et al. (2016) examine fiscal multipliers in the case of recessions, employing a model based on Cardia and Woodford (2009, 2010), to show that fiscal multipliers are state dependent, and during recessions their values exceed two, while during booms they are less than one.

  20. 20.

    In the case of the UK’s Financial Conduct Authority (FCA), it has been criticized for failing to regulate properly the sub-prime lending (as reported in the Observer, 04 April 2021).

  21. 21.

    The LTV ratio is a policy tool that relates to the housing market. It is a lending risk assessment that financial institutions and other lenders consider before approving a mortgage. Higher LTV implies higher risk loans.

  22. 22.

    In the UK, a new Infrastructure Bank is planned; the UK Treasury announced it, and confirmed by the Chancellor on his budget day (03 March 2021). This new bank is to be launched in spring 2021 to support private investment projects. The Chancellor on 03 March 2021 declared that the Bank of England should have another objective, namely environmental sustainability.

  23. 23.

    A report published on 24 March 2021 (Network for Greening the Financial System; a group of 89 Central Banks and financial supervisors formed in relation to the Paris climate goals), advises central banks how to avoid climate change risks, and support their national governments, without influencing their monetary policies. The main proposal is for Central Banks to offer a lower rate when financing banks, which meet climate-related lending criteria (Financial Times, 25 March 2021). ‘Green Quantitative Easing’, and ‘Green Targeted Lending Operations’, are additional policies to enable energy transition. Clearly, Central Banks should not ignore climate changes, which affect economies profoundly. Indeed, central banks should be involved with climate change. They can, and should, accelerate reductions in carbon emissions, change the cost of capital, use stress tests, to address climate risks in the financial sector, and apply relevant macroeconomic policies to avoid financial instability. It should also be noted that the virtual climate summit meeting (with 40 world leaders) organized by the USA President on the 22nd and 23rd of April 2021, and dealt with carbon emissions, pledged, “to cut emissions by at least 50 percent by the end of this decade” (Financial Times, 24 April 2021). The UK pledged to catch its emissions by 78% and by 2035. The summit, though, ended with very few funding promises for the poor countries. However, the Bank of England, and other Central Banks, are examining how they can orderly contribute to the emergence of a carbon–neutral economy (Ramsden, 2021).

  24. 24.

    As reported in The Economist (08 May 2021), in the USA the Fed is already considering the possibility of a CBDC. Also reported is that the CBDC is hoped to be introduced by 2025 by the ECB. Moreover, such conducive economic policies can significantly support progressive social, environmental, and economic development strategies and policies.

References

  • Acocella, N., Di Bartolomeo, G. and Hughes Hallet, A. (2016), Macroeconomic Paradigms and Economic Policy: From the Great Depression to the Great Recession, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Angeriz, A. and Arestis, P. (2008), “Assessing Inflation Targeting Through Intervention Analysis”, Oxford Economic Papers, 60(2), pp. 293–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P. (2016), “Main and Contributory Causes of the Recent Financial Crisis and Economic Policy Implications”, in P. Arestis and M. C. Sawyer (eds.), Emerging Economies During and After the Great Recession, Annual Edition of International Papers in Political Economy, (Palgrave Macmillan, 2016)

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P. (2019a), “The Past and Future of the Euro”, Revista de Economia Critica, Vol. 27, No. 2, pp. 6–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P. (2019b), “Critique of the New Consensus Macroeconomics and Propose a More Keynesian Macroeconomic Model”, in P. Arestis and M. C. Sawyer (eds.), Frontiers of Heterodox Macroeconomics, Annual Edition of International Papers in Political Economy, London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P. (2020), “Financial Stability: Still Unsettled for the Future”, in P. Arestis and M.C. Sawyer (eds.), Economic Policies for a Post Neo-Liberal World , Annual Edition of International Papers in Political Economy, London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (2011), “The Design Faults of the Economic and Monetary Union”, Journal of Contemporary European Studies, 19(1), pp. 19–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P. and Sawyer, M. (2019), “Critique of the New Consensus Macroeconomics and Propose a More Keynesian Macroeconomic Model”, in P. Arestis and M. Sawyer (eds.), Frontiers of Heterodox Macroeconomics, Annual Edition of International Papers in Political Economy, London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P. and González Martinez, A.R. (2015), “The Absence of Environmental Issues in the New Consensus Macroeconomics is only One of Numerous Criticisms”. In P. Arestis and M. Sawyer (eds.), Finance and the Macroeconomics of Environmental Policies, Annual Edition of International Papers in Political Economy, London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, A. (2021), “Getting over Covid”, Speech given at the Resolution Foundation, 8 March 2021. Available at: www.bankofengland.co.uk/news/speeches

  • Bailey, A., Bridges, J., Harrison, R., Jones, J. and Mankodi, A. (2020), “The Central Bank Balance Sheet as a Policy Tool: Past, Present and Future”, Bank of England Staff Working Paper No 899, Bank of England, December 2020. Available at: www.bankofengland.co.uk/working-paper/staff-working-papers

  • Balima, H.W., Kilama, E.G. and Tapsoba, R. (2017), “Settling the Inflation Targeting Debate: Lights from a Meta-Regression Analysis”, IMF Working Paper WP/17/213, September 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bank of England (2015), “On Bank Research Agenda”, Discussion Paper, Bank of England.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barwell, R. (2020), “Bank of England Should Switch Strategy on QE”, Financial Times, 10 December 2020.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becard, Y. and Gauthier, D. (2021), “Banks, Shadow Banks, and Business Cycles”, Bank of England Staff Working Paper No. 907, February 2021

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. (2018), “On the Future of Macroeconomic Models”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 34(1–2), pp. 43–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A., Ehrmann, M. de Haan, J. and Jansen, D.-J. (2017), “What Will Monetary Policy Look Like After the Crisis”, European Central Bank Research Bulletin, No. 39, 18 October 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordo, M.D. (2017), “An Historical Perspective on Financial Stability and Monetary Policy Regimes: A Case for Caution in Central Banks Current Obsession with Financial Stability”, Norges Bank Working Paper 5/2018, November 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri, M., Collard, F., Dellas, H. and Diba, B. 2016), Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions”, The Economic Journal, 126(590), pp. 75–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carney, M. (2020), Building a Better World for All, London: William Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carutti, E., Claessens, S. and Laeven, L. (2015), “The Use and Effectiveness of Macroprudential Policies: New Evidence”, IMF Working Paper WP/15/61, International Monetary Fund, March 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colciago, A., Samarina, A. and de Haan, J. (2018), “Central Bank Policies and Income and Wealth Inequality: A Survey”, DNB Working Paper No. 594, May 2018, De Nederlandsche Bank, Amsterdam, The Netherlands.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curdia, V. and Woodford, M. (2009), “Credit Functions and Optimal Monetary Policy”, Working Paper No. 278, Board of International Settlements.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curdia, V. and Woodford, M. (2010), “Credit Spreads and Monetary Policy”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(S1), pp. 3–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. and Lambertini, L. (2001), “Monetary-Fiscal Policy Interactions and Commitment versus Discretion in a Monetary Union”, European Economic Review, 45, pp. 977–997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. and Lambertini, L. (2003), “Symbiosis of Monetary and Fiscal Policies in a Monetary Union”, Journal of International Economics, 60, pp. 235–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Draqui, M. (2015), “The ECB and its Watchers XVI Conference”, Speech Delivered at Frankfurt Main, 11 March 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • Driffill, J. (2015), “Unconventional Monetary Policy in the Euro Zone”, Working Paper ISSN 2183–1815, Lisbon School of Economics & Management, Department of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson, G. B. (2006), “Fiscal Multipliers and Policy Coordination”, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, No. 241, F New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehnts, D. and Paetz, M.(2021), “COVID-19 and its economic consequences for the Euro Area”, Eurasian Economic Review. Available at: https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1007/s40822-020-00159-w

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elbourne, A., Ji, K. and Duijndam, S. (2018), “The Effects of Unconventional Monetary Policy in the Euro Area”, CPB Discussion Paper 371, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, B.M. (2015), “Has the Financial Crisis Permanently Changed the Practice of Monetary Policy? Has it Changed the Theory of Monetary Policy?”, The Manchester School, 5(11), Supplement 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C. (2012), “Monetary Policy and Public Debt”, Banque de France Financial Stability Review, 16, pp. 123–130, April 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart, C. and Ashworth, J. (2012), “QE: A Successful Start May Be Running Into Diminishing Returns”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 28(4), pp. 640–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haldane, A. (2021), “Inflation: A Tiger by the Tail?”, Speech Given Online, 26 February 2021. Available at: https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/news/speeches

  • Haldane, A., Roberts-Sklar, M., Wieladok, T. and Young, C. (2016), “QE: The Story so Far”, Bank of England Working Paper 624, Bank of England, October 2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2015), “Negative Interest Rates in Europe: A Glance at Their Causes and Implications”, in Global Economic Prospects, Chapter 1, June 2015.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2017), “Negative Interest Rate Policies – Initial Experiences and Assessments”, Staff Report, 13 March 2017. Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/pp/ppindex.aspx

  • Jarociński, M. and Maćkowiak, B. (2017), “Monetary Fiscal Interactions and the Euro Area Malaise”, NBER Working Paper 23746, August 2017. Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w23746

  • King, M. (2016), The End of Alchemy: Money, Banking and the Future of the Global Economy. London: Little Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, T. B. (2019), “Expectation and Duration at the Effective Lower Bound”, Journal of Financial Economics, 134, pp. 736–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumhof, M., Ranciere, R. and Winant, P. (2013), “Inequality, Leverage and Crises: The Case of Endogenous Default”, IMF Working Paper, 13/249, International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeper, E. (1993), “The Policy Tango; Towards a Holistic View of Monetary and Fiscal Effects”, Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 78(4), pp. 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCausland, W.D. and Theodossiou, I. (2016), “The Consequences of Fiscal Stimulus on Public Debt: A Historical Perspective”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 40(4), pp. 1103–1116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendicino, C., Nikolov, K., Rubio-Remirez, J. Suarez, J. and Supera, D. (2021), “How Much Capital Should Banks Hold?”, Research Bulletin No. 80, European Central Bank, 27 January 2021. Available at: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/economic-research/resbull/2021

  • Muellbauer, J. (2020), “Implications of Household-level Evidence for Policy Models: The Case of Macro-Financial Linkages’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 36(3), pp. 510–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides, A. (2017), “The Fiscal-Monetary Policy Mix in the Euro Area: Challenges at the Zero Lower Bound”, MIT Sloan School Working Paper 5197–17, 8 May 2017. Available at: http://creativecomments.org/licenses/by-nc/

  • Rajan, R. (2010), Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy, Princeton University Press, Princeton, USA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsden, D. (2021), “QE as an Economic Policy Tool—What does it do and how should we Use it?”. Speech given at the Peter Sinclair Town Hall, University of Birmingham, 17th February 2021.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutledge, A. and Litan, R.E. (2014), “A Real Fix for Credit Ratings”, Economic Studies at Brookings, June 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ryan-Collins, J. and van Lerven, F. (2018), “Bringing the Helicopter to Ground: A Historical Review of Fiscal-Monetary Coordination to Support Economic Growth in the 20th Century”, UCL Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose (IIPP) Working Paper Series 2018–08. Available at: https://www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/public-purpose/wp2018-08

  • Sawyer, M, (2013), “Alternative Economic Policies for the Economic and Monetary Union”, Contributions to Political Economy, 32(1), pp. 11–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair, P. and Allen, W.A. (2017), “Monetary Policy Normals, Future and Past”, National Institute Economic Review, No. 241, pp. R5–R12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skidelsky, R. (2017), “How Would Keynes have Analysed the Great Recession of 2008 and 2009?”, ch. 9 in T. Congdon, Money in the Great Recession: Did a Crash in Money Growth Cause the Global Slump?, Edward Elgar Publishers, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J. (2021), “The Macroeconomic Policy Outlook”, Macroeconomic Policy Unit, Quarterly Briefing Q1 2021. London: Resolution Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. (2010), Economics of the Public Sector, New York: The New Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. (2012), “Macroeconomics, Monetary Policy, and the Crisis”, in O.J. Blanchard, D. Romer, M. Spence and J.E. Stiglitz (eds.), In the Wake of the Crisis: Leading Economists Reassess Economic Policy. Cambridge (MA): MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. (2015), “New Theoretical Perspectives on the Distribution of Income and Wealth Among Individuals: Part IV: Land and Credit”, NBER Working Paper 21192, Cambridge (MA): National Bureau for Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarullo, D.K. (2017), “Monetary Policy without a Working Theory of Inflation”, Hutchins Center Working Paper 33, October 2017.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tenreyro, S. (2021), “Response to the Covid-19 Pandemic: UK and US Experiences”. Speech Given at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Macroeconomics and Monetary Policy, Spring Conference, 26 March 2021.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobias, A. (2020), “What to do When Low-for-Long Interest Rates are Lower and for Longer”, IMF Blog, 14 December 2020.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tressel, T. and Zhang, Y.S. (2016), “Effectiveness and Channels of Macroprudential Policies: Lessons from the Euro Area”, IMF Working Paper WP/16/4, Strategy, Policy, and Review Department, IMF, January 2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verselli, A. (2017), Crisis and Sustainability: The Delusion of Free Markets, London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vines, D. and Wills, S. (2020), “The Rebuilding Macroeconomic Theory Project Part II: Multiple Equilibria, Toy Models, and Policy Models in a New Macroeconomic Paradigm”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 36(2), pp. 427–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wren-Lewis, S. (2020), “Mapping Types of Macromodel to Types of Macro User”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 36(3), pp. 498–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yellen, J.L. (2014), “Monetary Policy and Financial Stability”, The 2014 Michel Camdessus Central Banking Lecture, International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C., 2 July 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watt, A. (2015), “Quantitative Easing with Bite: A Proposal for Conditional Overt Monetary Financing of Public Investment”, IMK Working Paper No. 148, March 2015, IMK Macroeconomic Institute. Available at: http://www.boeckler.de/cmk5016.htm

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Philip Arestis .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Arestis, P., Karagiannis, N. (2022). Proper Future Economic Policies. In: Karagiannis, N., King, J.E. (eds) Visions and Strategies for a Sustainable Economy. Global Institute for Sustainable Prosperity. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-06493-7_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-06493-7_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-031-06492-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-031-06493-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics