Skip to main content

Markets and Institutions: Economics and the Rough Understanding of Organizations

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Confronting Mainstream Economics for Overcoming Capitalism

Part of the book series: Marx, Engels, and Marxisms ((MAENMA))

  • 165 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter, we examine the theme of institutions (or the organization of markets), and more specifically the way in which the neoclassical mainstream has tried over the last decades to “endogenize” them, in order to integrate them into its general theoretical corpus. We show that most of the so-called neo-institutionalist works, very often non-mathematized and supposedly distinct from the neoclassical current, actually seek to refer to the standard general market equilibrium model to sound more scientific and be accepted academically. We will see how these analyzes represent a defense of private property rights, a justification of the established social order, and a certain vision, extremely restrictive and oriented, of democracy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    One of the bases used to write this chapter was a long survey elaborated for the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) in 1996, a few months before I joined the CNRS as a full-time researcher: Herrera (1996). The discreetly critical aspect of its initial content meant that this draft, although self-censored and commissioned as an OECD working paper, did not obtain the internal visa authorizing its publication. It thus remained a mimeo. The present, liberated text of this chapter has little to do with the original one, which was too polite—because it was excessively polished.

  2. 2.

    Veblen (1899a, 1899b, 1900).

  3. 3.

    For example, Mitchell (1913), Commons (1931), Ayres (1944), and Clark (1957).

  4. 4.

    Menger (1996 [1833]).

  5. 5.

    Arrow and Debreu (1954).

  6. 6.

    This was the pioneering position of Coase (1987 [1937]). And also that of Hicks (1969).

  7. 7.

    Among others: Williamson (1975).

  8. 8.

    Williamson (1985). Also see authors as different as: Alchian (1977), Hirschman (1986), and Coase (1988).

  9. 9.

    De Janvry et al. (1993).

  10. 10.

    Williamson (1995).

  11. 11.

    Coase (1987).

  12. 12.

    Lin and Nugent (1995).

  13. 13.

    Bertrand (2003).

  14. 14.

    For an example of typology: Matthews (1986).

  15. 15.

    Coase (1960).

  16. 16.

    Stiglitz (1988, 1995, 2001).

  17. 17.

    Boland (1979).

  18. 18.

    Cf. Ménard (1990).

  19. 19.

    See, for example, North (1984).

  20. 20.

    North (1990a). Earlier: North (1987).

  21. 21.

    Williamson (1975).

  22. 22.

    Akerlof (1984).

  23. 23.

    North (1984).

  24. 24.

    Hayami and Ruttan (1984).

  25. 25.

    Menger (1996 [1833]).

  26. 26.

    Hayek (1953).

  27. 27.

    North and Thomas (1973). See also the concentrated and early version: North and Thomas (1970).

  28. 28.

    North (1991).

  29. 29.

    Nabli and Nugent (1989).

  30. 30.

    Cf. the articles relating to institutions published in the volumes of Handbooks of Development Economics successively coordinated by H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan (1988), J. Behrman and the same Srinivasan (1995), T.P. Schultz and J.A. Strauss (2008), then D. Rodrik and M. Rosenzweig (2010).

  31. 31.

    North (1981).

  32. 32.

    North (1990a).

  33. 33.

    See: Shleifer (1995); and, in the same document: Blanchard (1995).

  34. 34.

    Banque mondiale (1996).

  35. 35.

    Clark (1924).

  36. 36.

    Banque mondiale (1997).

  37. 37.

    Fogel and Engerman (1974a, p. 233). Also see: Fogel and Engerman (1974b).

  38. 38.

    See: Fields (1981), and: Rutherford (1989).

  39. 39.

    Alchian and Demsetz (1972) and Favereau (1989).

  40. 40.

    Mahieu (1989).

  41. 41.

    On the issue, for example, of communautary ownership of land (and the very powerful attacks on it) in Papua New Guinea, read: Herrera and Tetoe (2011, 2012, 2015).

  42. 42.

    For an analysis of the Japanese firm, complementary to that of O.E. Williamson: Aoki (1986).

  43. 43.

    Schneider and Libercier (1995).

  44. 44.

    Lévi-Strauss (1962, p. 44).

  45. 45.

    Here: Schultz (1968).

  46. 46.

    For example, Barnum and Squire (1979) and Singh et al. (1986).

  47. 47.

    De Janvry et al. (1991).

  48. 48.

    Matoussi and Nugent (1989).

  49. 49.

    See: http://www.universalis.fr/encyclopedie/jean-jacques-laffont/.

  50. 50.

    Laffont and Matoussi (1995).

  51. 51.

    Here: Marshall (1920 [1890]). Also: Johnson (1950).

  52. 52.

    Cheung (1968, 1969a, b).

  53. 53.

    Stiglitz (1974).

  54. 54.

    Ziegler (2005).

  55. 55.

    Squire and Van der Tak (1975).

  56. 56.

    Akerlof (1976, 1984).

  57. 57.

    See: Arrow (1972a, b).

  58. 58.

    Herrera (2010a).

  59. 59.

    See: Laffont (1982) and Tirole (1988).

  60. 60.

    The World Bank (1997, p. 53).

  61. 61.

    North (1987). On the crucial role of the State in maintaining the stability of property rights: D Long (1989).

  62. 62.

    The World Bank (1997, pp. 35–38).

  63. 63.

    North (1990a).

  64. 64.

    Cf De Soto (1986).

  65. 65.

    Buchanan (1975). A little before, in parallel: Niskanen (1971, 1975).

  66. 66.

    North (1987).

  67. 67.

    Findlay and Wilson (1987).

  68. 68.

    Coase (1989 [1937]).

  69. 69.

    North (1979).

  70. 70.

    Idem. Also: North (1981).

  71. 71.

    North (1981, p. 21).

  72. 72.

    North (1990a).

  73. 73.

    North (1990b).

  74. 74.

    North (1987).

  75. 75.

    Friedman (1962).

  76. 76.

    See: Lipset (1959).

  77. 77.

    Read: Helliwell (1994).

  78. 78.

    Helliwell, et al. (2013).

  79. 79.

    In particular: Schwarz (1992).

  80. 80.

    Barro (1996).

  81. 81.

    See: Gastil (various years).

  82. 82.

    Here: http://fr.wikipedia.org/wiki/Freedom_House.

  83. 83.

    Consult the website  www.freedomhouse.org, and immediately afterward, consult a doctor in case of prolonged exposure to this ideological irradiation.

  84. 84.

    Cf. Kojm (2012). Available on: http://fr.scribd.com/doc/115962650/Global-Trends-2030-Alternative-Worlds.

  85. 85.

    See: Krueger (1974, 1990, 1993).

  86. 86.

    Among other examples: Bhagwati (1982), Wellisz and Findlay (1986), Scully and Slottje (1991), and Scully (2002).

  87. 87.

    Central Intelligence Agency(various years).

  88. 88.

    Gillis et al. (1990, p. 267). For a very different perspective: Herrera (2010b, 2017a).

References

  • Akerlof G.A. (1976), “The Economics of Caste and of the Rat Race and other Woeful Tales,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 90, n° 4, p. 599–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1984), An Economic Theorist’s Book of Tale—Essays That Entertain the Consequences of New Assumptions in Economic Theory, New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian A.A. (1977), Economic Forces at Work, Minneapolis: Liberty Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian A.A. and H. Demsetz (1972), “Production, Information Costs and Economic Costs, and Economic Organization,” American Economic Review, vol. 62, n° 2, p. 92–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M. (1986), “Horizontal vs. Vertical Information Structure of the Firm,” American Economic Review, vol. 76, n° 5, p. 971–983.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K.J. (1972a), “Models of Job Discrimination,” in A.H. Pascal (ed.), Racial Discrimination in Economic Life, p. 83–102, Lexington MA: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1972b), “Some Mathematical Models of Race in the Labor Market,” in A.H. Pascal (ed.), Racial Discrimination in Economic Life, p. 187–204, Lexington MA.: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K.J. and G. Debreu (1954), “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy,” Econometrica, vol. 22, n° 3, p. 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayres C.E. (1944), The Theory of Economic Progress, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banque mondiale (1996), “De l’Économie planifiée à l’économie de marché,” Rapport sur le développement dans le monde de la Banque mondiale, Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1997), “L’État dans un monde en mutation,” Rapport sur le développement dans le monde de la Banque mondiale, Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnum H.N. and L. Squire (1979), “An Econometric Application of the Theory of the Farm Household,” Journal of Development Economics, n° 6, p. 79–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R.J. (1996), “Democracy and Growth,” Journal of Economic Growth, vol. 1, n° 1, p. 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand É. (2003), “Les ‘Théorèmes de Coase:’ énoncés et critiques microéconomiques,” Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati J.N. (1982), “Directly Unproductive Profit Seeking Activities,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 90, n° 5, p. 988–1002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O.J. (1995), “Comment on ‘Establishing Property Rights’ by Shleifer,” Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994, p. 118–121, Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boland L. (1979), “Knowledge and the Role of Institutions in Economic Theory,” Journal of Economic Issues, vol. 13, n° 4, p. 957–972.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan J.M. (1975), The Limits of Liberty—Between Anarchy and Leviathan, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Intelligence Agency (various years), The World Factbook, Public Affairs, Washington DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery H.B. and T.N. Srinivasan (eds.) (1988), Handbooks of Development Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung S.N.-S. (1968), “Private Property Rights and Sharecropping,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 76, n° 6, p. 1107–1122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1969a), Theory of Share Tenancy, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1969b), “Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements,” Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 13, p. 49–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark J.M. (1924), “The Socializing of Theoretical Economics,” in R.G. Tugwell (ed.), The Trend of Economics, p. 73–105, New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1957), Economic Institutions and Human Welfare, New York: A.A. Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase R. (1960), “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, n° 3, p. 1–44, October.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase R.H. (1988), The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1989 [1937]), “La Nature de la firme,” Revue française d’Économie, vol. 2, n° 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commons J.R. (1931), “Institutional Economics,” American Economic Review, vol. 21, n° 4, p. 648–657.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Janvry A., M. Fafchamps and E. Sadoulet (1991), “Peasant Household Behavior with Missing Markets: Some Paradoxes Explained,” Economic Journal, vol. 101, n° 409, p. 1400–1417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Janvry A., E. Sadoulet and E. Thorbecke (1993), “Introduction,” World Development, vol. 21, n° 4, p. 565–575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Long J.B. (1989), “The Protestant Ethic Revisited: A Twentieth Century Look,” Fletcher Forum of World Affairs, n° 13, p. 229–242.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Soto H. (1986), El Otro Sendero, El Barranco, Lima: Institute for Liberty and Democraty.

    Google Scholar 

  • Favereau O. (1989), “Marchés internes, marchés externes,” Revue économique, vol. 40, n° 2, p. 273–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fields A. (1981), “The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics: A Critique with Special Reference to the North/Thomas Model of pre-1500 Europe,” Explorations in Economic History, n° 18, p. 174–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay R. and J.D. Wilson (1987), “The Political Economy of the Leviathan,” in A. Razin and E. Sadka (eds.), Economic Policy in Theory and Practice, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogel R.W. and S.L. Engerman (eds.) (1974a), Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery, New York: W.W. Norton and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1974b), Time on the Cross: Evidence and Methods—A Supplement, Boston: Little, Brown and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M. (1962), Capitalism and Freedom, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gastil R.D. (various years), Freedom in the World: Political Rights and Civil Liberties, Westport (CT): Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gillis M., D.H. Perkins, M. Roemer and D.R. Snodgrass (1990), Économie du développement, Brussels: De Boeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayami Y. and V.W. Ruttan (1984), “Toward a Theory of Induced Institutional Innovation,” Journal of Development Studies, vol. 20, n° 4, p. 203–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F.A. (1953), Scientisme et sciences sociales: essai sur le mauvais usage de la raison, Paris: Plon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell J.F. (1994), “Empirical Linkages Between Democracy and Economic Growth,” British Journal of Political Science, n° 24, p. 225–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell J.F., P.R. Layard and J.D. Sachs (2013), World Happiness Report 2013, New York: Sustainable Development Solutions Network.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera R. (1996), “Institutions et croissance: une étude appliquée aux pays en développement,” mimeo, Paris: OECD Development Centre.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2010a), Dépenses publiques et croissance économique - Pour sortir de la science(-fiction) néoclassique, Paris: L’Harmattan.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2010b), Un Autre Capitalisme n’est pas possible, Paris: Syllepse.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2017), “La Colombie telle que l’a vécue Marulanda,” in R. Herrera, Figures révolutionnaires de l’Amérique latine, p. 65–72, Paris: Éditions Delga.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera R. and P. Tetoe (2011), “Le Capital étranger dans le secteur des mines en Papouasie Nouvelle-Guinée,” Économies et Sociétés, série F, tome XLV, n° 2, p. 321–336, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2012), “Le Paradoxe Papua Niugini: archaïsme de la propriété de la terre, modernité des résistances paysannes?,” Revue française de Socio-économie, n° 9, 2012/1, p. 133–152, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2015), “The Papua Niugini Paradox,” in R. Herrera and K.-C. Lau (eds.) The Struggle for Food Sovereignty—Alternative Development and the Renewal of Peasant Societies Today, p. 119–135, London: Pluto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks J.R. (1969). A Theory of Economic History, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman A.O. (1986). Vers une Économie politique élargie, Paris: Éditions de Minuit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson D.G. (1950), “Resource Allocation Under Share Contracts,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 58, n° 1, p. 111–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kojm C. (2012), Global Trends 2030: Alternative Worlds, Washington DC: National Intelligence Council.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger A.O. (1974), “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society,” American Economic Review, vol. 64, n° 3, p. 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1990), “Government Failures in Development,” National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper, n° 3340, Cambridge (MA).

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1993), Political Economy of Policy Reform in Developing Countries, Cambridge MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J.-J. (1982), Cours d’analyse microéconomique - Tome 1: Fondements de l’économie publique, Paris: Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont J.-J. and M.S. Matoussi (1995), “Moral Hazard, Financial Constraints and Sharecropping in El Oulja,” Review of Economic Studies, vol. 62, n° 3, p. 381–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lévi-Strauss C. (1962), La Pensée sauvage, Paris: Plon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin J.Y. and J.B. Nugent (1995), “Institutions and Economic Development,” in J. Behrman and T.N. Srinivasan (eds.), Handbook of Development Economics, vol. III, Chapter 38, p. 2302–2369, Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipset S.M. (1959), “Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy,” American Political Science Review, vol. 53, n° 1, p. 69–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahieu F.R. (1989), “Transferts et communauté africaine,” Stateco, nos 58–59, p. 107–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A. (1920 [1890]), Principles of Economics, 8th ed., London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matoussi M.S. and J.B. Nugent (1989), “The Switch to Sharecropping in Medjez-el-Bab,” in M. Nabli and J.B. Nugent (eds.), The New Institutional Economics and Development, p. 140–157, Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matthews R.C.O. (1986), “The Economics of Institutions and the Sources of Growth,” The Economic Journal, vol. 96, n° 384, p. 903–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ménard C. (1990), L’Économie des organisations, collection «Repères», n° 86, Paris: La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menger C. (1996 [1833]), Investigations into the Method of the Social Sciences, Grove City: Libertarian Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell W.C. (1913), Business Cycles, Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nabli M.K. and J.B. Nugent (eds.) (1989), The New Institutional Economics and Development, Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen W.A. (1971), Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1975), “Bureaucrats and Politicians,” Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 18, n° 3, p. 617–643.

    Google Scholar 

  • North D.C. (1979), “A Framework for Analyzing the State in Economic History,” Explorations in Economic History, vol. 16, n° 3, p. 249–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1984), “Government and the Cost of Exchange in History,” Journal of Economic History, vol. XLIV, n° 2, p. 255–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1987), “Institutions, Transaction Cost and Economic Growth,” Economic Inquiry, vol. 25, n° 3, p. 419–428.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1990a), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions, Cambridge (UK): Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1990b), “Institutions and a Transaction-Cost Theory of Exchange,” in J.E. Alt and K.A. Shepsle (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1991), “Institutions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 5, n° 1, p. 97–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • North D.C. and R.P. Thomas (1970), “An Economic Theory of the Growth in the Western World,” Economic History Review, vol. 23, n° 1, p. 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1973), The Rise of the Western World—A New Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D. and M. Rosenzweig (2010), Handbooks of Development Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier - North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford M. (1989), “What Is Wrong with the New Institutional Economics (and What Is Still Wrong with the Old)?,” Review of Political Economy, vol. 1, n° 3, p. 299–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider H. and M.H. Libercier (1995), Mettre en œuvre le développement participatif, Centre de Développement de l’OCDE, Séminaires du Centre de Développement, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz T.P. and J. Strauss (2008), Handbooks of Development Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier - North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz T.W. (1968), “Institutions and the Rising Economic Value of Man,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 50, n° 5, p. 1113–1122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarz G. (1992), “Democracy and Market-Oriented Reform: A Love-Hate Relationship?,” Economic Education Bulletin, vol. 32, n° 5, p. 13–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully G.W. (2002), “Economic Freedom, Government Policy and the Trade-Off Between Equity and Economic Growth,” Public Choice, vol. 113, nos 1–2, p. 77–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scully G.W. and D.J. Slottje (1991), “Ranking Economic Liberty Across Countries,” Public Choice, vol. 69, n° 2, p. 121–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer A. (1995), “Establishing Property Rights,” Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994, p. 93–107, Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh I.J., L.Squire et J. Strauss (dir.) (1986), Agricultural Household Models: Extension, Application and Policy, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Squire L. and H.B. Van der Tak (1975), Economic Analvsis of Projects, Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press (for The World Bank).

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J.E. (1974), “Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping,” Review of Economic Studies, vol. 41, n° 2, p. 219–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1988), Economics of the Public Sector, New York: W.W. Norton & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1995), “Economic Organization, Information, and Development,” in H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan (eds.), Handbook of Development Economics, vol. I, Chapter 5, p. 94–160, Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2001), “Information and the Change in the Paradigm in Economics,” Prize Lecture at Columbia Business School, Columbia University, December 8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tirole (J. (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen T.B. (1899a), “Preconceptions of Economic Science (I),” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 13, p. 121–150, January.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1899b), “Preconceptions of Economic Science (II),” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 13, p. 396–426, July.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1900), “Preconceptions of Economic Science (III),” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 14, p. 240–269, February.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wellisz S. and R. Findlay (1986), “Central Planning and the Second Economy in Soviet-Type Systems,” Economic Journal, vol. 96, n° 383, p. 646–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson O.E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, London and New York: Free Press - Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1995), “The Institutions and Governance of Economic Development and Reform,” Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics 1994, p. 171–205, Washington DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (The) (1997), World Development Report, The World Bank: Washington DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziegler J. (2005), L’Empire de la honte, Paris: Fayard.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rémy Herrera .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Herrera, R. (2022). Markets and Institutions: Economics and the Rough Understanding of Organizations. In: Confronting Mainstream Economics for Overcoming Capitalism. Marx, Engels, and Marxisms. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-05851-6_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics