Skip to main content

Development: Theoretical Rebirth… Or Smiling Recolonization?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Confronting Mainstream Economics for Overcoming Capitalism

Part of the book series: Marx, Engels, and Marxisms ((MAENMA))

  • 165 Accesses

Abstract

Development economics, as an autonomized branch of general economics striving to study how a poor country can “develop,” has its modern origins in the 1940s and 1950s. It arose from a double differentiation, by rejecting both standard neoclassical economics and Keynesian economics (dominant over the period 1945–1975 approximately). This chapter intends to show how neoclassicism has absorbed development economics as one of its own components, but also how the current mainstream is now prisoner of a very deep theoretical crisis. We shall also see in what sense its domination in the element of theory must be understood as inseparable from that of neoliberalism over the practice of development.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This chapter has been written from the following two articles: Herrera (2004a, 2006a).

  2. 2.

    Krugman (1993). A “leftist” neoclassical, Krugman, is here complimenting and paying homage to three “right-wing” neoclassicals, authors—“progressive” authors to the point of defining corruption as a “sister activity of taxes”—Murphy et al. (1989).

  3. 3.

    Rosenstein-Rodan (1943). Also see: Dessus and Herrera (1999, 2000).

  4. 4.

    Krugman (1993, 1995).

  5. 5.

    Hirschman (1958).

  6. 6.

    Krugman (1989, 1990).

  7. 7.

    For an introduction to the capitalist world system theories: Herrera (2001).

  8. 8.

    Read, for example, Kalecki (1986, 1993) and Lange (1967).

  9. 9.

    See, in particular, Prebisch (1973), Furtado (2003), Marini (1969), Mahalanobis (1955), and Amin (1993).

  10. 10.

    Massé (1965).

  11. 11.

    Even a reactionary economist like Guillaumont (1985) admitted this.

  12. 12.

    Read here: Nakatani and Herrera (2007).

  13. 13.

    See, for example, Krueger et al. (1981).

  14. 14.

    International Monetary Fund (2003). Read also the IMF “anti-corruption guide,” available on: http://www.imf.org/external/np/gov/guide/eng/index.htm.

  15. 15.

    Regarding the IMF’s mandate to combat money laundering and the financing of terrorism (known as “AML/CFT”), see here: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/2008/POL073108A.htm.

  16. 16.

    World Bank (1994). See the Worldwild Governance Indicators on: http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/worldwide-governance-indicators.

  17. 17.

    Respectively: http://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/ourwork/democraticgovernance/overview.html; http://www.adb.org/themes/governance/; http://idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getdocument.aspx?docnum=1555501; http://www.oecd.org/governance/; and http://www.ebrd.com/pages/about/policies/governance.html.

  18. 18.

    Gazier and Herrera (2002).

  19. 19.

    Tullock (1993). Before that, from the same: Tullock (1967). And even before, of course: Buchanan and Tullock (1961). Also: Stigler (1971, 2003). Without forgetting: Krueger (1974).

  20. 20.

    Read on this subject the speech given in Davos in 1999 by the Seventh Secretary-General of the United Nations, Kofi Atta Annan. As well as: http://www.unglobalcompact.org/.

  21. 21.

    Richter (2003).

  22. 22.

    Sachs (2005). See: Herrera (2006b).

  23. 23.

    UNICEF (2001) See: http://www.unicef-irc.org/publications/pdf/monee8/eng/5.pdf.

  24. 24.

    Herrera (2004b, c).

  25. 25.

    Arrow and Debreu (1954). Also: Debreu (1959).

  26. 26.

    See: Guerrien (1996a).

  27. 27.

    For instance, if a nation establishes a minimum wage for workers, will this lead to an increase in unemployment?

  28. 28.

    Adelman and Robinson (1978), Devarajan and Rodrik (1991), and Bourguignon et al. (1983). Later: Bourguignon et al. (2008).

  29. 29.

    Read: Lewis (1955), Kuznets (1966), and Myrdal (1968).

  30. 30.

    Todaro (1982).

  31. 31.

    Schultz (1968). Also: Becker (1964).

  32. 32.

    Herrera (2010).

  33. 33.

    Azariadis and Drazen (1990).

  34. 34.

    Kaldor (1961, 1982).

  35. 35.

    Goodwin (1967).

  36. 36.

    Goodwin (1983).

  37. 37.

    Aghion and Howitt (1992, 1998, 2005).

  38. 38.

    Bukharin (1972 [1914]).

  39. 39.

    Read here: Sonnenschein (1972, 1973).

  40. 40.

    Mantel (1974).

  41. 41.

    Debreu (1974). See, before that, by the same: Debreu (1959, 1962).

  42. 42.

    Lucas (1981), Kydland and Prescott (1982), and Long and Plosser (1983).

  43. 43.

    For an internal criticism, but clearly insufficient: Summers (1986).

  44. 44.

    An example: Naoussi and Tripier (2012).

  45. 45.

    Hayek (1953, p. 34).

  46. 46.

    North and Thomas (1973).

  47. 47.

    Such analyses are at the antipodes of the Marxist ones. For example, Soboul (2014). Also: Nicolas (2002).

  48. 48.

    Fogel (1964). Or: Fogel and Engerman (1971).

  49. 49.

    Read instead: Bénot (2006 [1992]). And: Dorigny and Zins (2009).

  50. 50.

    Nietzsche (1899, p. 390).

  51. 51.

    Stiglitz (1974).

  52. 52.

    Williamson (1975).

  53. 53.

    See the preface to the French edition of: Von Mises (1938).

  54. 54.

    Source: extract from the personal page of X. Sala-i-Martín (available at: http://www.columbia.edu/%~23).

  55. 55.

    For a demonstration radically opposed to the neoclassical position, see: Herrera and Long (2019).

  56. 56.

    On this issue, see: Barro and Sala-i-Martín (1992, 1995, 1997).

  57. 57.

    Abramovitz (1986). More recently, Acemoğlu, Johnson and Robinson (2005).

  58. 58.

    Keefer and Knack (1995) and Knack (1996).

  59. 59.

    This is what suggested, for example, Baumol et al. (1989).

  60. 60.

    Delong (1989).

References

  • Abramowitz M. (1986), “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind,” Journal of Economic History, vol. 46, n° 2, p. 385–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoğlu K.D., S. Johnson and J.A. Robinson (2005), “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth,” in P. Aghion and S. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1, part A, p. 385–472, Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adelman I. and S. Robinson (1978), Income Distribution Policy in Developing Countries: A Case Study of Korea, A World Bank Research Publication, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P.M. and P.W. Howitt (1992), “A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction,” Econometrica, vol. 60, n° 2, p. 323–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1998), Endogenous Growth Theory, Cambridge MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2005), “Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth,” in P. Aghion and S. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1, p. 67–110. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amin S. (1993), Itinéraire intellectuel, Paris: L’Harmattan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K.J. and G. Debreu (1954), “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy,” Econometrica, vol. 22, n° 3, p. 265–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis C. and A. Drazen (1990), “Threshold Externalities in Economic Development,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 105, n° 2, p. 501–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R.J. and X. Sala-i-Martín (1992), “Convergence,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 100, n° 2, p. 223–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1995), Economic Growth, New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1997), “Technological Diffusion, Convergence, and Growth,” Journal of Economic Growth, vol. 2, n° 1, p. 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol W.J., S. Blackman and E. Wolff (1989), Productivity and American Leadership: The Long View, Cambridge MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G.S. (1964), Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education, New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bénot Y. (2006 [1992]), La Démence coloniale sous Napoléon, Paris: La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F., M. Bussolo and L.A. Pereira da Silva (2008), The Impact of Macroeconomic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution, Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F., G. Michel and D. Miqueu (1983), “Short-Run Rigidities and Long-Run Adjustments in a Computable General Equilibrium Model of Income Distribution and Development,” Journal of Development Economics, vol. 13, n° 1, p. 21–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan J.M. and G. Tullock (1961), The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bukharin N.I. (1972 [1914]), L’Économie politique du rentier - critique de l’économie marginaliste, Paris: Études et Documentations Internationales.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G. (1959), Theory of Value, New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1962), “New Concepts and Techniques for Equilibrium Analysis,” International Economic Review, vol. 3, n° 2, p. 257–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1974), “Excess Demand Functions,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, vol. 1, n° 1, p. 15–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delong J.B. (1989), “The Protestant Ethic Revisited: A Twentieth Century Look,” Fletcher Forum of World Affairs, n° 13, p. 229–242.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dessus S. and R. Herrera (1999), “Capital public et croissance: une étude en économétrie de panel,” Revue économique, vol. 50, n° 1, p. 113–126, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2000), “Public Capital and Growth: A Panel Data Assessment,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. 48, n° 2, p. 407–418, Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devarajan S. and D. Rodrik (1991), “Pro-competitive Effects of Trade Reform: Results from a CGE Model of Cameroon,” European Economic Review, n° 35, p. 1157–1184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorigny M. and M.-J. Zins (eds.) (2009), Les traités négrières coloniales: Histoire d’un crime, Paris: Cercle d’Art.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogel R.W. (1964), Without Consent or Contract: The Rise and Fall of American Slavery, New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fogel R.W. and S.L. Engerman (eds.) (1971), The Reinterpretation of American Economic History, New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furtado C. (2003), Raízes do subdesenvolvimento, Rio de Janeiro: Civilização Brasileira.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gazier B. and R. Herrera (2002), “Escaping from the Crisis: Structural Adjustment and Social Security in the Republic of Korea,” in K. Marshall and O. Butzbach (eds.), New Social Policy Agendas for Europe and Asia—Challenges, Experience, and Lessons, p. 405–417, Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin R.M. (1967), “A Growth Cycle,” in C.H. Feinstein (ed.), Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth, p. 54–58, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1983), Essays in Linear Economic Systems, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrien B. (1996a), Dictionnaire d’analyse économique - Microéconomie, macroéconomie, théorie des jeux, etc., «Dictionnaires repères», Paris: La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guillaumont P. (1985), Économie du développement, tome 2, Thémis, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F.A. (1953), Scientisme et sciences sociales: essai sur le mauvais usage de la raison, Paris: Plon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera R. (2001b), “Les Théories du système mondial capitaliste,” in J. Bidet and E. Kouvélakis, Dictionnaire Marx contemporain, p. 201–221, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2004a), “Un Renouveau de l’économie du développement?,” Recherches internationales (Paris), n° 72, p. 51–68, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2004b), “Good Governance against Good Government?,” Joint Written Statement of the Centre Europe Tiers-Monde and the American Association of Jurists for the Human Rights Commission of the United Nations, 60th Session, Point 17, E/CN.4/2004/NGO/124, July, Geneva.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2004c), “IMF: A Bad Governance Model?,” Third World Economics, n° 324, p. 15–21, Penang.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2006a), “The Hidden Face of Endogenous Growth Theory,” Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 38, n° 2, p. 243–257, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2006b), “Objectifs du Millénaire pour le Développement: lutte contre la pauvreté ou guerre contre les pauvres ?,” Alternatives Sud, vol. 13, n° 1, p. 185–199, Louvain-la-Neuve.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2010). Dépenses publiques et croissance économique - Pour sortir de la science(-fiction) néoclassique, Paris: L’Harmattan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera R. and Z. Long (2019). La Chine est-elle capitaliste?, Paris: Éditions Critiques.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman A.O. (1958), The Strategy of Economic Development, New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (2003), Good Governance: The IMF Role, Washington DC: IMF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor N. (1961). “Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth,” in F.A. Lutz and D.C. Hague (eds.), The Theory of Capital, p. 177–222, New York: St.Martin Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1982), The Scourge of Monetarism, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki M. (1986), Selected Essays on Economic Planning, Cambridge (UK): The University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1993). Introduction to the Theory of Growth in a Socialist Economy (1963). in J. Osiatyński and B. Jung (eds.), Collected Works of Michal Kalecki, vol. IV, New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer P. and S. Knack (1995), “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures,” Economics & Politics, vol. 7, n° 3, p. 207–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack S. (1996), “Institutions and the Convergence Hypothesis: The Cross-national Evidence,” Public Choice, n° 87, p. 207–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger A.O. (1974), “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society,” American Economic Review, vol. 64, n° 3, p. 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger A.O. et al. (1981), Trade and Employment in Developing Countries, National Bureau of Economic Research, London: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P.R. (1989), Rethinking International Trade, Cambridge (MA): The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1990), “Increasing Returns and Economic Geography,” National Bureau of Economics Research Working Papers, n° 3275, Cambridge MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1993), “The Fall and Rise of Development Economics,” available on: http://www.wws.princeton.edu/pkrugman/dishpan.html.

  • ——— (1995), Development, Geography, and Economic Theory, Cambridge (MA): The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets S.S. (1966). Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure, and Spread, New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1982), “Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica, vol. 50, n° 6, p. 1345–1370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange O.R. (1967), Essays on Economic Planning, London: Asia Publishing House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis W.A. (1955), Theory of Economic Growth, London: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Long J.B. and C.I. Plosser (1983), “Real Business Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 91, n° 1, p. 39–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R.E. (1981), Studies in Business Cycle Theory, Cambridge MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahalanobis P.C. (1955). “The Approach of Operational Research to Planning in India,” Sankhya—The Indian Journal of Statistics, vol. 16, nos 1–2, p. 3–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mantel R.R. (1974), “On the Characterization of Aggregate Excess Demand,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 7, n° 3, p. 348–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marini R.M. (1969), Subdesarrollo y revolución, México: Siglo XXI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Massé P. (1965), Le Plan ou l’anti-hasard, Collection Idées, Paris: Gallimard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy K.M., A. Shleifer and R.W. Vishny (1989), “Industrialization and the Big Push,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 106, n° 2, p. 503–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal G. (1968), Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations, New York: Twentieth Century Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakatani P. and R. Herrera (2007), “What Rich Countries Owe Poor Ones,” Monthly Review, vol. 59, n° 2, p. 31–36, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Naoussi C.F. and F. Tripier (2012), “La Modélisation en équilibre général dynamique et stochastique des cycles économiques en Afrique sub-saharienne,” Revue d’économie politique, n° 5, p. 657–683.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicolas J. (2002), La Rébellion française - Mouvements populaires et conscience sociale: 1661–1789, Paris: Le Seuil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nietzsche F.W. (1899), Humain, trop humain, Paris: Mercure de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • North D.C. and R.P. Thomas (1973). The Rise of the Western World—A New Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R. (1973), Problemas teóricos y prácticos del crecimiento económico, New York: Naciones Unidas, Comisión Económica para América Latina.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richter J. (2003), Building on Quicksand: The Global Compact, Democratic Governance and Nestlé, Geneva: Éditions CETIM / IBFAN-GIFA / Déclaration de Berne.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstein-Rodan P.N. (1943), “Industrialization of Eastern and South Eastern Europe,” Economic Journal, vol. 53, n° 210, p. 202–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs J. (2005), The End of Poverty, London: Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz T.W. (1968), “Institutions and the Rising Economic Value of Man,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 50, n° 5, p. 1113–1122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soboul A. (2014), “Du Féodalisme au capitalisme: la Révolution française et la problématique des voies de passage,” in A. Casanova et R. Herrera (eds.), Penser les crises, p. 34–58, Paris: Le Temps des Cerises.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein H. (1972), “Market Excess Demand Functions,” Econometrica, vol. 40, n° 3, p. 549–563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1973), “Do Walras’ Identity and Continuity Characterize the Class of Excess Demand Functions?,” Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 6, n° 4, p. 345–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler G.J. (1971), “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics, vol. 2, n° 1, p. 3–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (2003), Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J.E. (1974), “Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping,” Review of Economic Studies, vol. 41, n° 2, p. 219–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Summers L.H. (1986), “Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle Theory,” Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, vol. 10, n° 4, p. 23–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Todaro M.P. (1982), Economics for a Developing World, Essex: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock G. (1967), “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft,” Western Economic Journal, n° 5, p. 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • ——— (1993), Rent Seeking, Brookfield: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNICEF (2001), A Decade of Transition, Regional Monitoring Report (MONEE), n° 8, Florence.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Mises L. (1938), Le Socialisme - Étude économique et sociologique, Paris: Éditions M.-Th. Génin - Librairie de Médicis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson O.E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, London and New York: Free Press - Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (The) (1994), Governance: The World Bank’s Experience, Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rémy Herrera .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Herrera, R. (2022). Development: Theoretical Rebirth… Or Smiling Recolonization?. In: Confronting Mainstream Economics for Overcoming Capitalism. Marx, Engels, and Marxisms. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-05851-6_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics