Skip to main content

Are Workers in the Developing World Winners or Losers in the Current Era of Globalization?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Global Labour in Distress, Volume I

Part of the book series: Palgrave Readers in Economics ((PRE))

Abstract

This chapter investigates whether workers in less-developed countries (LDC) are winners or losers in the expanding global economy. This study is distinctive in that it looks beyond the impact of globalization on direct economic benefits to labor (employment and surplus labor) and assesses if workers simultaneously improve their bargaining power in the marketplace. I use a time-series cross-sectional panel data set for 59 developing countries from 1972 to 1997 to demonstrate that the overall impact of globalization on labor has been different in countries at various levels of economic development. These results challenge conventional wisdom by revealing that under conditions of globalization, labor in low-income countries is not necessarily in a better bargaining position despite certain economic gains. In contrast, labor in high-income countries enjoys both greater economic benefits and an improved bargaining position. The absolute “winners” in globalization ultimately comprise a small percentage of the larger labor force in the developing world.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Silver (2003) identifies labor’s marketplace bargaining power based on Erik O. Wright’s (2000) analysis. It refers specifically to the structural power gamed by workers based on their location in the economic system and is a direct result of tight labor markets. Silver emphasizes three forms of marketplace bargaining power: (1) the possession of scarce skills, (2) low unemployment, and (3) “the ability of workers to pull out of the labor market entirely and survive on nonwage sources of income.” She also discusses associational power, which refers to “the various forms of power that result from the formation of collective organization of workers” and another form of structural power or workplace bargaining power that results “from the strategic location of a particular group of workers within a key industrial sector.” Associational and structural bargaining powers are often positively correlated in the long run (e.g., teachers, European automobile workers).

  2. 2.

    The edited volume by Candland and Sil (2001) is a notable exception. The case studies are limited to the experiences of five developing countries: Mexico, Brazil, India, Pakistan, and China. Silver (2003) also discusses the effects of globalization on labor, but focuses on identifying waves of labor unrest and uses the world system rather than nation states as the level of analysis.

  3. 3.

    PLP is an index I developed to make inferences about the extent of labor’s bargaining power. I place emphasis on potential labor power since, as Silver (2003) also acknowledges, workers’ bargaining power does not automatically mean that workers will apply that power to demand greater political and economic benefits.

  4. 4.

    Categories of low-, lower-middle, upper-middle, and high-income LDC are based on World Development Indicators 2002. Even though Greece and Mexico are also OECD countries, I included them in my LDC dataset because neither country was categorized as “high-income” for most of the time period of this study. Korea is included because it was not an OECD country until the 1990s.

  5. 5.

    This literature emphasizes that wages and income will increase with openness as long as the LDCs are fairly rapid globalizers, have strong institutions, and good governance.

  6. 6.

    Silver (2003) also analyzes labor and globalization, but with a different focus. Her approach centers on the interaction between global patterns of labor unrest and world political dynamics. Furthermore, globalization is considered mainly in terms of the increasing mobility of capital.

  7. 7.

    Silver(2003) makes a good case for why Galton’s problem precludes the necessity of observing cross-national variations. Nonetheless, this argument is not supported with empirical evidence.

  8. 8.

    Silver (2003) suggests that improvements (recessions) in marketplace bargaining power do not always translate to greater (weaker) “associational power” in the short run (see fn.l). for example, British, Chinese, and Indian textile workers in the nineteenth century. However, she concludes that “these were the exceptional cases; most commonly, associational power was not sufficiently strong to compensate for the weak structural power of workers.”

  9. 9.

    Conversely, capitalists and skilled workers will be better able to influence government policies in more developed countries.

  10. 10.

    Nontradable informal activities include services such as haircutting, domestic help, street vending, etc.

  11. 11.

    Surplus labor is called “casual labor” in India.

  12. 12.

    See, ILO (2002) for more details on growing levels of surplus labor.

  13. 13.

    See, for example, Posusney’s (1997) analysis on labor in Egypt.

  14. 14.

    For more details, see Baer and Herve (1966).

  15. 15.

    The logic holds that in overpopulated countries more people are employed than needed to produce output. As long as hidden unemployment prevails, its supply to industry is unlimited in the sense that industries can expand or be created without affecting the prevailing wage (See Wellisz, 1968).

  16. 16.

    The United Nations Economic and Social Council Commission reports that fertility has declined in many nations since the 1970s, particularly in middle-income countries.

  17. 17.

    The labor force, which includes the employed and unemployed, is part of the formula for surplus labor.

  18. 18.

    This can be compared to an average of 7 percent of surplus labor in OECD countries and 13 percent in the HICs.

  19. 19.

    See for example, Valenzuela, 1989; Banuri & Amadeo, 1991. McGuire, 1997 adds that unreliability of union data can result in huge discrepancies in existing cross-country compilations of union-density estimates.

  20. 20.

    For more detailed hypotheses on why low-skilled labor groups in LDCs are difficult to organize, see Deyo (1989); Gereffi (1995); Ingerson (1984).

    LSI covers mostly mid-1990s data.

  21. 21.

    The decade dummies were dropped from the model if they were insignificant across models.

  22. 22.

    Estimating a measure of first-order correlation (p) has the effect of making the time-series data stationary. This measure is used to transform all variables in the model according to the formula: yt = yt − (ρyt − 1). This partial differencing reduces suspicions about spurious results, particularly the concern that the effects of potentially high degree of institutional inertia exhibited by the dependent variable are not captured.

  23. 23.

    As a robustness check, I ran the model using total exports of goods, services, and income in place of manufactured exports. The primary results were unaffected.

  24. 24.

    HIC interactions are excluded to avoid linear dependency.

  25. 25.

    With globalization, both can simultaneously occur if incentives to work in the informal sector is greater than the incentive to enroll in school, and the increase in low-skill employment is drawn from the existing labor force.

  26. 26.

    The per capita human spending is an instrumental variable (using the Lewbel procedure) in this model because of endogeneity—LDCs with large skilled labor populations are apt to invest in human capital. This variable is not included as a control for surplus labor since higher government spending on education and health in LDCs does not necessarily benefit the poor and tends to be disproportionately allocated to the middle and upper classes. See World Development 2000–2001.

  27. 27.

    Portfolio flows in HICs are almost twice as high as flows in MICs, and almost four times the level of flows in LICs (averaged from 1972–1997).

  28. 28.

    For a recent review of the literature that supports the hypothesis that private capital flows are more efficient in higher-income countries, see Eichengreen (2001).

  29. 29.

    The number of ILO ratifications is arguably the weakest component of LSI, since ratification does not necessarily ensure enforcement. A detailed evaluation of the strengths and weaknesses of LSI is a subject for a future study.

  30. 30.

    LSI closely resembles Silver’s (2003, p. 13) reference to “associational power,” or “the various forms of power that result from the formation of collective organization of workers” (most important, trade unions and political parties). The comparisons in Table 15 and Chart 1 suggest that marketplace bargaining power and associational power are closely related.

  31. 31.

    LSI and PLP also differ in some of the African cases where LSI tends to be higher than PLP (Ghana and Mali). The reason is because data availability for all four components of LSI is apt to be scarce in these countries, biasing these scores upward. See McGuire (1999, p. 12).

  32. 32.

    Yap (2003) for instance, discusses “credible apologies” that East Asian governments make to labor. They may dismiss, demote, or replace certain government officials deemed responsible for the policies that “hurt” labor, downsize or eliminate the relevant agency, or offer reparations. Representatives from academia, labor, or business also may be invited in to review, evaluate, or oversee changes to government.

  33. 33.

    For example. Yap (2003) draws from Bates (1981) and argues that labor can withdraw economic resources (e.g., alter their production mix, engage in the black market) to protest the government’s economic policies. In reference to workers in Thailand, Brown (2004) discusses the importance of taking account of industrial workers and their organization as potential political actors. He argues that “even when labor is invisible, in the sense of not being a public, organized actor overtly engaged in formal political processes, the politics of the working class is nonetheless there and is significant. For, behind the scenes, there has been a continual jockeying to channel and control workers and their struggles. This is to ensure that they either do not emerge as a public, organized force, or if they do, they are organized in a manner that is in keeping with the broader economic, ideological, and political interests of those dominating contests for state power” (Brown, 2004, p. 133).

References

  • Achen, C. (2000). Why Lagged Dependent Variables Can Suppress the Explanatory Power of Other Independent Variables. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Political Methodology Section of the American Political Science Association, UCLA, 20–22 July.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baer, W., & Herve, M. E. A. (1966). Employment and Industrialization in Developing Countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80(1), 88–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bangasser, P. (2000). The ILO and the Informal Sector: An Institutional History. ILO Employment Paper 2000/9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banuri, T., & Amadeo, E. (1991). Worlds within the Third World: Labour Market Institutions in Asia and Latin America. In T. Banuri (Ed.), Economic Liberalization: No Panacea. Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bates, R. (1981). Markets and States in Tropical Africa. University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., & Katz, J. (1995). What to Do and Not to Do with Time-Series Cross-Section Data. American Political Science Review, 89(3), 634–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beeson, M., & Hadiz, V. (1998). Labor and the Politics of Structural Adjustment in Australia and Indonesia. Journal of Contemporary Asia, 28(3), 291–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berman, E., & Machin, S. (2000). Skill-biased Technology Transfer around the World. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 16(3), 12–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, A. (2004). Labour. Politics, and the State in Industrializing Thailand. Routledge, Curzon Taylor and Francis Group.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brunner, A. (2003). The Long-Run Effects of Trade on Income and Income Growth. IMF Institute Series Working Paper No. 03 37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Candland, C., & Sil, R. (2001). The Politics of Labor in a Global Age. Continuity and Change in Late-Industrializing and Post-Socialist Economies. Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, A., & Senser, R. (1997). China’s Troubled Workers. Foreign Affairs, 76(2), 104–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dean, J. M. (1995). From Protectionism to Free Trade Fever? Recent Reforms in Developing Countries. Open Economies Review, 6(4), 369–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deshpande, S., & Deshpande, L. (1998, May). Impact of Liberalization on Labour Market in India. Economic and Political Weekly, 30, L31–L39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devarajan, S., Ghanem, H., & Thierfelder, K. (1997). Economic Reform and Labor Unions: A General Equilibrium Analysis Applied to Bangladesh and Indonesia. World Bank Economic Review, 11(1), 145–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deyo, F. (1989). Beneath the Miracle: Labor Subordination in the New Asian Industrialism. University of California Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B. (2001). Capital Account Liberalization: What Do Cross-Country Studies Tell Us? World Bank Economic Review, 15(3), 341–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Encarnation, D. (1989). Dislodging Multinationals: India s Strategy in Comparative Perspective. Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, S. (1993). Organized Labor in the Asia-Pacific Region. 1LR Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, S., & Peetz, D. (1998). Globalization and Industrial Relations in East Asia: A Three-Country Comparison. Industrial Relations, 37(3), 282–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frundt, H. (2002). Central American Unions in the Era of Globalization. Latin American Research Review, 37(3), 7–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galenson, W. (1962). Labor in Developing Economies. University of California Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Galenson, W. (1994). Trade Union Growth and Decline. Praeger Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallin, D. (2001). Propositions on Trade Unions and Informal Employment in Times of Globalisation. Antipode, 33(3), 531–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi, G. (1995). Global Production Systems and Third World Development. In B. Stallings (Ed.), Global Change, Regional Response (pp. 100–142). Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ghose, A. (2000). Trade Liberalization and Manufacturing Employment. ILO Working Employment Paper 2000/3, Geneva.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golden, M., Wallerstein, M., & Lange, P. (1999). Postwar Trade-Union Organization and Industrial Relations in Twelve Countries. In H. Kitschelt, P. Lange, G. Marks, & J. Stephens (Eds.), Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harriss-White, B. (1999). State, Market, Collective, and Household Action in India’s Social Sector. In B. Harriss-White & S. Subramanian (Eds.), Illfare in India: Essays on India’s Social Sector in Honour of S. Guhan. Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingerson, A. (1984). The Textile Industry and Working Class Culture in Labor. In C. Bergquist (Ed.), The Capitalist World Economy (Vol. 7) in Political Economy of World Systems Annuals. Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Labor Organization. (1997). World Employment Report, 1996–1997. ILO.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Labor Organization. (1999). World Employment Report, 1998–1999. ILO.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Labour Office. (2002). Key Indicators of the Labour Market, 2001–2002. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P., & Venables, A. (1995). Globalization and the Inequality of Nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(4), 857–880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuchta-Helbling, C. (2000). Barriers to Participation: The Informal Sector in Emerging Democracies. The Center for International Private Enterprise. http://www.cipe.org/topics/informalsector/papers/, http://www.cipe.org/topics/mformalsector/papers/

  • Lall, S. (1998). Exports of Manufactures by Developing Countries: Emerging Patterns of Trade and Location. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 14(2), 54–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Learner, E. (1996). Wage Inequality from International Competition and Technological Change: Theory and Country Experience. The American Economic Review, 86(2), 309–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel, A. (1997). Constructing Instruments for Regressions with Measurement Error When No Additional Data Are Available, with an Application to Patents and R&D. Econometrica, 65(5), 1201–1213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loayza, N. (1997). The Economics of the Informal Sector: A Simple Model and Some Empirical Evidence from Latin America. World Bank Working Paper no. 1727.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lok, H. P. (1993). Labour in the Garment Industry: An Employer’s Perspective. In C. Manning & J. Hardjono (Eds.), Indonesia Assessment 1993. Australian National University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning, C. (1998). Does Globalization Undermine Labour Standards? Lessons from East Asia. Australian Journal of International Affairs, 52(2), 133–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazumdar, J., & Quispe-Magnoli, M. (2002). Trade and the Skill Premium in Developing Countries: The Role of Intermediate Goods and Some Evidence from Peru. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper, 2002–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, J. (1997). Peronism without Peron. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, J. (1999). Labor Union Strength and Human Development m East Asia and Latin America. Studies in Comparative International Development, 33(4), 2–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montiel, P. (1994). Capital Mobility m Developing Countries: Some Measurement Issues and Empirical Estimates. World Bank Economic Review, 8(3), 311–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munck, R. (2002). Globalization and Labour. Zed Books.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Offe, C., & Wiesenthal, H. (1985). Two Logics of Collective Action. In J. Keane (Ed.), Disorganized Capitalism (p. 216). MIT University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1971). Logic of Collective Action. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Papola, T. S. (1994). Employment Growth and Social Protection of Labor in India. Indian Journal of Industrial Relations, 30(2), 117–141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Portes, A. (1990). When More Can Be Less: Labor Standards, Development, and the Informal Economy. In Labor Standards and Development in the Global Economy, Symposium on Labor Standards and Development U S. Department of Labor: Bureau of International Labor Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posusney, M. P. (1997). Labor and the State in Egypt. Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prasad, S. (1998). Economic Globalization and Labour: Market Transformations in Fiji. Economic and Industrial Democracy, 19(2), 227–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, D., & Gindling, T. (1997). Educational Expansion, Trade Liberalization, and Distribution in Costa Rica. In A. Berry (Ed.), Poverty, Economic Reform, and Income Distribution in Latin America. Lynne Rienner Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogowski, R. (1989). Commerce and Coalitions. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scruggs, L., & Lange, P. (2002). Where Have All the Members Gone? Globalization, Institutions, and Union Density. The Journal of Politics, 64(1), 126–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1966). Peasants and Dualism with or without Surplus Labor. The Journal of Political Economy, 74(5), 425–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silver, B. (2003). Forces of Labor. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, A., Levy, B., & Paredes, R. (1996). Public Institutions and Private Transactions: A Comparative Analysis of the Legal and Regulatory Environment for Business Transactions in Brazil and Chile. In L. Alston (Ed.), Empirical Studies in Institutional Change. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (1993). UN Industry and Development Report. 1992/1993. United Nations Industrial Development Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valenzuela, S. (1989). Labor Movements in Transitions to Democracy. Comparative Politics, 21(4), 445–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webster, E., & Lipsig-Mumme, C. (2002). Recasting Labour Studies in the New Millennium. Society in Transition, 33(2), 258–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wellisz, S. (1968). Dual Economies, Disguised Unemployment and the Unlimited Supply of Labour. Economica, 137, 22–51, New Series 35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Western, B. (1997). Between Class and Market. Postwar Unionization in the Capitalist Democracies. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A. (1997). Openness and Wage Inequality in Developing Countries: The Latin American Challenge to the East Asian Conventional Wisdom. World Bank Economic Review, 11(1), 33–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A., & Ridao-Cano, C. (1999). Skill, Trade, and International Inequality. Oxford Economic Papers, 51, 89–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (1995). World Development Report 1994–1995. World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2000). World Development Report 1999–2000. World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2001). World Development Report 2000–2001. World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2002). World Development Report, 2002. World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, E. (2000, January). Working-Class Power, Capitalist-Class Interests, and Class. American Journal of Sociology, 105, 957–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yap, O. F. (2003). Non-Electoral Responsiveness Mechanisms: Lessons from the Asian Less-Democratic Newly Industrializing Countries. The British Journal of Political Science, 33, 491–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, K. (2004). Review of Labour, Politics, and the State in Industrializing Thailand. Journal of Contemporary Asia, 34(4), 551–552.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yusuf, S. (1999). The Changing Development Landscape. Finance and Development, 36(4), 15–18.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Additional information

The author is grateful to Hayward Alker for valuable advice and input on this research project and James McGuire for generously providing access to his data. The SC1D editors and anonymous reviewers also provided extremely helpful feedback and comments.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Table 11 Data sources and definitions
Table 12 Data sources, calculations, and estimations
Table 13 Manufactured exports (NM)
Table 14 Translated to manufactured production

Appendix 2

Assessing PLP

Few efforts have been made to measure and compare labor power across developing countries over time. Union density is the most commonly used cross-national indicator of labor power. As noted earlier, union density is more appropriately applied in the developed world than in the LDCs. Most LDCs are still far from attaining strong and independent unions. Even in LDCs with relatively high union density, labor is rife with collective action problems and often subject to a broad range of government controls.

Given the unreliability of direct organizational measures, as Encarnation’s analysis suggests, alternative assessments of labor’s bargaining power tend to be tautological (Encarnation, 1989). According to Encarnation, bargaining power is generally defined by the outcome, making it difficult to tell which party had more bargaining power if negotiations are “won by those who win.” It is virtually impossible to differentiate between power and negotiated outcomes using this approach. Encarnation (1989, p. 20) concludes that bargaining power must refer to the ability of laborers to “improve the range of plausible outcomes available to each [negotiator], and to improve the probability of securing the outcome that each prefers.”

The measure of PLP used in this analysis attempts to avoid the tautology problem. It does so by acquiring some sense of labor’s propensity for collection action rather than collective action per se. After all, since labor discontent can be costly for political leaders (and workers), governments often respond to labor demands before strikes or other militant actions occur. Offe and Wiesenthal (1985) argue that in such circumstances “the organization then has become strong enough to derive some power (i.e., control over its environment) from its recognized potential of power. In other words, concessions are likely to be made not because members have struck, but in order to avoid a strike.”

To assess whether PLP serves as an indirect measure of labor’s political power, additional steps must be taken. Comparing PLP to other nontautological assessments of labor’s bargaining power is the most precise way to accomplish this. McGuire’s (1999) labor strength index (LSI) represents the only other effort to assess the “real” magnitude of labor’s bargaining power in LDCs and compare it across countries. Because of data limitations, it represents only one period of time (the 1990s). LSI is based on four dimensions: (1) union membership as a percent of the nonagricultural labor force; (2) proportion of formal-sector workers covered by collective contracts; (3) level of collective bargaining power—national/sectoral, enterprise, or both; (4) number of major International Labour Organization conventions ratified.Footnote 29 This is a multifaceted attempt to capture several important dimensions of labor strength that are not directly measured by PLP.

The comparison of PLP and LSI in Table 15 significantly increases confidence in the PLP’s reliability as an indicator of labor’s bargaining power. The correlation coefficient, excluding the outliers, is 0.61 (see Chart 1). The correlation is actually higher than expected since LSI includes unionization data (and its inherent weaknesses), and because PLP captures some important nontraditional sources of labor’s bargaining power.Footnote 30

Table 15 Comparing PLP and LSIa
Chart 1
A dual axis line graph plots L S I and P L P scores for various countries. The graph depicts significant fluctuations for various countries.

PLP and LSI. (*Note that some of the countries were dropped from the graph to reduce clustering)

For most cases, the PLP rankings are similar to LSI, and it is primarily the East Asian cases, for example, Singapore, Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand that show the most contrast. Their PLP score is “high,” which contradicts conventional wisdom on labor in these nations.Footnote 31 Yet the PLP scores are consistent with more recent analyses by Yap (2003) and Brown (2004), which bring important new insights on labor in the East Asian countries and explain why labor’s political influence in these authoritarian nations has been commonly misinterpreted.

According to both Yap and Brown, workers in these nations have been in a relatively unique position in the developing world because of the central economic role they have played in the nations’ development. Repressive labor strategies have been part of the East Asian nations’ export-oriented industrialization strategy for economic development. Yet paradoxically, precisely because of this dependence on labor, the state has had to accommodate labor in different ways.Footnote 32 Labor’s collective political consciousness has thereby evolved differently in these countries while the more familiar signs of political power (e.g., strikes, unionization, centralization of bargaining power) have been conspicuously absent.Footnote 33 As Young (2004) argues, “in studies … where the forms of consciousness and organization are found not to conform to these [familiar] expectations, labor is deemed to be ‘weak’ or ‘immature,’ and seen to be peripheral to the development of state, society and the economy…. The outcome may not conform to very generalized theoretical expectations, but that calls for re-evaluation and refinement of theory, rather than a dismissal of the significance of working class struggles.” One important advancement of the PLP indicator is that it can approximate labor movements that do not develop the familiar institutional forms.

The indicator applied in this study, PLP, offers three broad advantages: (1) it corresponds to conditions specific to the bargaining power of labor in developing countries; (2) it is comparable across LDCs; and (3) it has a time-series component that can capture the dynamic aspects of bargaining power. The first advantage is important because the logic of PLP is based on the particular circumstances faced by labor in LDCs. Desirability of the second two characteristics is more obvious. A standardized measure available over time and across countries greatly reduces the biases that can affect empirical analyses of labor in the developing world.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Rudra, N. (2022). Are Workers in the Developing World Winners or Losers in the Current Era of Globalization?. In: Goulart, P., Ramos, R., Ferrittu, G. (eds) Global Labour in Distress, Volume I. Palgrave Readers in Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-89258-6_13

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-89258-6_13

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-89257-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-89258-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics