Keywords

1 Introduction

Recent research has reported a disappointing performance in labor productivity growth among European Union (EU) and euro area (EA) countries since the start of the crisis from 2008 to 2015 (Van Ark & Jäger, 2017). According to this literature, this performance stems largely from a slower diffusion of technology and innovation due to low growth rates of information and communication technology (ICT) and complementary intangible capital investment (Van Ark & Jäger, 2017, p. 15; Van Ark, 2016, pp. 37–41; Van Ark & O’Mahony, 2016, pp. 132–138).

Indeed, a recent growth-accounting study at the macro-level over the period 2000–2013 identifies the deepening of intangible capital as a main driver of labor productivity growth (Corrado et al., 2018, p. 11). Such findings are in line with existing growth-accounting studies for the US (Corrado et al., 2009), the UK (Marrano et al., 2009), Japan (Fukao et al., 2009), Sweden (Edquist, 2011), and the EU-15 (Corrado et al., 2013).

Within this substantial body of growth-accounting evidence, however, there exists only scarce econometric evidence at the macro-level of the impact of intangible capital investment on labor productivity growth. The only existing econometric study analyses an EU-13 country sample for pre-crisis times from 1998 to 2005 (Roth & Thum, 2013). This scarcity of growth econometric studies is remarkable in light of their general advantages in comparison to growth-accounting studies (Temple, 1999, pp. 120–121). To help close this gap in the research, this study conducts an econometric analysis using a cross-country growth-accounting approach covering 16 EU countries over the period 2000–2015. This approach goes beyond earlier work in two ways. First, it enables us to corroborate earlier econometric findings (Roth & Thum, 2013) with the help of a greatly extended dataset containing more than two and half times the number of overall observations (256 versus 98). Second, by covering a period until 2015, we are able to generate novel econometric findings on the impact of intangible capital deepening on labor productivity growth by accounting for times of crisis (2008–2013) and times of economic recovery (2014–2015).

By matching the most recent release of the INTAN-Invest (NACE2)Footnote 1 dataset (Corrado et al., 2018) with the latest figures from the EU KLEMSFootnote 2 dataset (Jäger, 2017), in combination with a wide range of growth-relevant policy variables from Eurostat, the OECD and the World Bank, this contribution provides the largest up-to-date intangible capital panel dataset at the macro-level containing an overall number of 256 country observations. Estimating a slightly modified model specification as developed within the existing literature (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 495), with the help of a cross-country growth-accounting econometric approach, this contribution reaches three major findings. First, in line with the previous growth econometric literature (Roth & Thum, 2013), it confirms that once intangibles are accounted for, they become the dominant source of labor productivity growth in the EU, explaining up to 66% of this growth. Second, when accounting for times of crisis (2008–2013), it finds that even when the relationship between tangible capital and labor productivity turned negative, the impact of intangibles on growth remained solidly positive. Third, when accounting for the economic recovery (2014–2015), it reports a highly significant and remarkably strong relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity growth.

2 Theoretical Linkages between Intangible Capital and Labor Productivity Growth

The earliest work highlighting the importance of intangible capital for labor productivity dates back to the 1960s (Haskel & Westlake, 2018, p. 38). Based on research by Brynjolfsson et al. (2002) and Nakamura (2001), among others, Corrado et al. (2005) developed a methodological framework for the US of how to account for business intangibles in the “new economy”. The authors used an intertemporal framework for investment and grouped the various business intangibles into three broad dimensions: 1) computerized information, namely software, 2) innovative property, namely research & development (R&D) and 3) economic competencies, namely brand names, firm-specific human capital and organizational capital. Conducting a growth-accounting analysis alongside their methodological framework, Corrado et al. (2009) showed that business intangibles were able to explain a significant share of labor productivity growth. Using growth-accounting studies, similar results were found for the UK (Marrano et al., 2009), Japan (Fukao et al., 2009), Sweden (Edquist, 2011) and the EU (Corrado et al., 2013, 2018). Econometric cross-country growth-accounting studies for the EU (Roth & Thum, 2013) find an even stronger impact of intangibles on labor productivity growth. In addition, the positive relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity was prominently discussed and established in the work of Bounfour (Bounfour & Miyagawa, 2015; Delbecque et al., 2015); Piekkola (2016, 2018) and Miyagawa (Miyagawa & Hisa, 2013; Bounfour & Miyagawa, 2015).

The positive relationship between computerized information and labor productivity growth—particularly the interaction between software and organizational capital (Brynjolfsson et al., 2002)—and R&D and labor productivity growth (Guellec & van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, 2001) has already been well established in the literature. Consequently, the intangible assets—software, R&D and entertainment, artistic and literary originals, and mineral exploration—were already included in the asset boundary of the national accounts. Given that economic competencies, in particular, were not yet included in the national accounts, it seems necessary to once more elaborate their positive role in labor productivity growth. Concerning brand names, Cañibano et al. (2000) argue that the ownership of an attractive brand permits a seller to retain a higher margin for goods or services compared to his competitors. Since the consumer is driven by his perceptions in choosing among the products of competing firms, the development of an appealing image or brand is crucial in producing future benefits. Concerning training or firm-specific human capital, the same authors stress that a firm with higher-skilled employees is likely to attain higher profits than competitors whose workers are less competent. This observation is in line with Abowd et al. (2005), who argue that the value of a firm will increase if the quality of its firm-specific human capital resources improves. Concerning organizational capital, Lev and Radhakrishnan (2005, p. 75) define organizational capital as “an agglomeration of technologies (…) business practices, processes and designs and incentive and compensation systems—that together enable some firms to consistently and efficiently extract from a given level of physical and human resources a higher value of product than other firms find possible to attain.” The authors classify this as the only competitive asset truly possessed by a firm, whereas the others are exchangeable and thus can be obtained by any company prepared to make the necessary investment.

3 Estimates on Intangible Capital

A methodological framework originally developed by Corrado et al. (2005) for measuring business intangibles in the US has become widely used internationally. The framework was adopted in individual country-case studies for the UK (Marrano et al., 2009), Japan (Fukao et al., 2009), and Sweden (Edquist, 2011). Adapting this methodological framework to the EU, the FP7 INNODRIVE projectFootnote 3 constructed the first harmonized dataset for an EU-27 country sample (plus Norway), alongside the three dimensions mentioned above. It contained two “old” national account intangibles and eight “new” intangibles over the time period 1980–2005 (INNODRIVE, 2011; Jona-Lasinio et al., 2011; Gros & Roth, 2012; Roth & Thum, 2013). The INNODRIVE macro database was used as the base for the EU-27 countries within the first version of the INTAN-Invest (NACE1) datasetFootnote 4—a harmonized and updated intangible dataset covering the EU and the US over the time period 1980–2010 (Corrado et al., 2013). In developing the second version of the INTAN-Invest (NACE2) dataset, Corrado et al. (2016, 2018) significantly altered their methodology to provide information on intangible capital on single-digit NACE2 economic sectors and updated their dataset in the latest January 2019 release until the year 2015.

The INTAN-Invest (NACE2) covers 19 EU countries plus the US over the period 1995–2015. The dataset measures three “old” national account intangibles and five “new” intangibles. The dataset groups business intangibles under three dimensions: 1) computerized information, 2) innovative property and 3) economic competencies. The first dimension, i.e. computerized information, contains computer software and databases. The second dimension, i.e. innovative property, contains 1) entertainment, artistic and literary originals, and mineral exploration, 2) R&D, 3) design and 4) new product development in the financial industry. The third dimension, i.e. economic competencies, contains 1) brand, 2) firm-specific human capital and 3) organizational capital. A detailed explanation of the altered methodology of the INTAN-Invest (NACE2) dataset is provided in Corrado et al. (2016), pp. 42–47.

4 Previous Empirical Results

Table 2.1 gives an overview of the existing empirical results of the growth-accounting and cross-country growth econometric literature analyzing the relationship between business intangible capital and labor productivity growth by businesses at the macro-level. The table displays three distinct effects once intangible capital has been incorporated into the asset boundary of the national accounts.

Table 2.1 Overview of existing empirical studies, 2009–2018

In the first instance, the table clarifies that investments in intangible capital reach significant levels, once they are fully accounted for. Analyzing the business investment level for the US in pre-crisis times, Corrado et al. (2009) find a business investment level of 13% of non-farm business output, whereas Nakamura (2010) finds equal shares of intangible and tangible capital investments. Similar investment rates for precrisis times are found for Japan (Fukao et al., 2009) and the UK (Marrano et al., 2009) with 11.1% of GDP and 13% of adjusted MGVA (market sector gross value added), respectively. With a value of 16% of GVA(gross value added), higher business investment rates are found in Sweden (Edquist, 2011). Utilizing INNODRIVE data, Roth and Thum (2013) find an average business investment rate for precrisis times (1998–2005) for 13 EU countries of 9.9% of GVA. Utilizing the first version (NACE1) of the INTAN-Invest dataset, Corrado et al. (2013) find an average business investment rate of 6.6% of GDP for an EU-15 country sample from 1995 to 2009. Utilizing the second version of the INTAN-Invest (NACE Rev.2) dataset, Corrado et al. (2018) find an average investment rate for business intangibles for the EU-14 and NMS-4 of 7.2% and 6.4% of GDP, respectively, from 2000 to 2013.

Second, the contribution from intangible capital services to labor productivity growth is significant. Once business intangible capital is accounted for, 27% and 20% of labor productivity growth were explained in the US and the UK, respectively. The same and higher values of up to 41% hold for Japan and Sweden (Fukao et al., 2009; Edquist, 2011). Utilizing INNODRIVE data and analyzing 13 EU countries with the help of an econometric cross-country growth-accounting methodological approach, Roth and Thum (2013) find that 50% of labor productivity can be explained. Using INTAN-Invest (NACE1) data for an EU-15 country sample over the time period 1995–2009, Corrado et al. (2013) find a value of 24%. In their most recent study, using INTAN-Invest data (NACE2), Corrado et al. (2018) differentiate between a precrisis and a crisis period. They find that intangible capital contributes 30% over the time period 2000–2013, and 19% and 43% in times of precrisis and crisis respectively, for an EU-14 country sample.

Third, the capitalization of intangibles accelerates productivity growth.

5 Model Specification, Research Design and Data

5.1 Model Specification

We estimate a slightly revised model specification as developed in the existing econometric literature (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 495). Following this literature, the slightly revised model specification takes the following form:

$$ \left(\ln {q}_{i,t}-\ln {q}_{i,t-1}\right)=c+g{H}_{i,t}+m{H}_{i,t}\frac{\left({q}_{\max, t}-{q}_{i,t}\right)}{q_{i,t}}+n\left(1-{ur}_{i,t}\right)+p\sum \limits_{j=1}^k{X}_{j,i,t}+{yd}_{i,t}+\alpha \left(\ln {k}_{i,t}-\ln {k}_{i,t-1}\right)+\beta \left(\ln {r}_{i,t}-\ln {r}_{i,t-1}\right)+{u}_{i,t} $$
(2.1)

where (lnqi,t −  ln qi,t−1) is labor productivity growth (GVA expanded by intangibles and divided by total hours worked) for the non-farm business sectors b − n + r − s excluding real estate activities expanded by the investment flows of business intangible capital in country i and period t. The constant term c represents exogenous technological progress; the level of human capital (Hi,t) reflects the capacity of a country to innovate domestically; and the term Hi,t(qmax,t − qi,t)/qi,t proxies a catch-up process, with qmax,t using a purchasing power parity-weighted GVA measure divided by total hours worked and representing the country with the highest level of labor productivity at period t. The term (1 − uri,t) takes into account the business cycle effect proxied by 1 minus the unemployment rate (ur); the term \( \sum \limits_{j=1}^k{X}_{j,i,t} \) is the sum of k extra policy variables, which could possibly explain TFP (total factor productivity) growth and ydi,t are year dummies to control among others for the economic downturn in 2001, in the wake of the bursting of the information technology bubble in the previous year and the 9/11 attack in 2001, as well as the pronounced economic downturn since 2008. (lnki,t −  ln ki,t−1) and (lnri,t −  ln ri,t−1) represent the growth of tangible and intangible capital services, and ui,t represents the error term.

5.2 Research Design

The econometric analysis covers 16 out of 27 EU countries from 2000 to 2015. The countries included are Austria, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Slovakia, Slovenia, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.Footnote 5 With 16 EU countries and 16 time periods from 2000 to 2015, this leaves the econometric analysis with an overall number of 256 observations. Following the approach by Roth and Thum (2013, p. 496), annual growth rates from 2000 to 2015 were estimated. The econometric analysis was restricted to a period of 2000–2015, due to the valid calculation of capital stock data. Equation (2.1) is estimated with the help of an econometric cross-country growth accounting approach. This approach differs from traditional single-growth accounting in two ways. First, the output elasticities are estimated rather than imposed. And second, the model can be designed to explain the international variance in TFP (total factor productivity) growth. The whole research design applies to non-farm business sectors b − n + r − s excluding real estate activities. For Greece, Ireland, and Portugal, measures for the total economy were adjusted to the non-farm business sectors. For Greece, disproportionately high levels of organizational capital investment were adjusted to an average EU-16 level. Measurement errors and missing values in the latest releases of the EU KLEMS (Jäger, 2017) and the INTAN-Invest (NACE2) dataset (Corrado et al., 2018) were dealt with when necessary.Footnote 6

5.3 Data Sources

The data were retrieved from the sources specified below:

  1. 1.

    Data on the single components of intangible capital were taken from the INTAN-Invest (NACE2) dataset (Corrado et al., 2018), which provides information on gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) and intangibles adjusted GVA. The data cover 19 EU countries + the US over the period 1995–2015, for 21 NACE2 economic sectors. The INTAN-Invest (NACE2) dataset does not provide intangible capital stocks.

  2. 2.

    Data on the single components of tangible capital were taken from the EU KLEMS database (Jäger, 2017). The database provides data on GFCF, tangible capital stocks, GVA, labor compensation, capital compensation, and number of hours worked per employee. The data cover the EU-28 countries and the US, over the period 1995–2015, for 21 NACE2 economic sectors.

  3. 3.

    Human capital is measured as the percentage of the population aged 15+ that has attained at least upper-secondary education, which is taken as a proxy for the stock of human capital. The data were obtained from Eurostat.

  4. 4.

    Data on unemployment, power purchasing parity (PPP), inflation (HICP), government expenditures on education (percent of GDP), total government expenditures (percent of GDP), social expenditure (percent of GDP), and stock of foreign direct investment (FDI) (percent of GDP) were obtained from Eurostat.

  5. 5.

    Data on income tax (as a percent of GDP) were obtained from the OECD. The variables rule of law (Kaufmann et al., 2010), data on market capitalization (percent of GDP), and openness to trade were retrieved from the World Bank.

5.4 A Note on the Construction of Intangible Capital Stocks

In line with the literature (Niebel et al., 2017, p. 55; Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 497; Timmer et al., 2007, pp. 32 and 39), intangible capital stocks for the selected 16 EU-27 countries for the time period 2000–2015 were constructed by applying the perpetual inventory method (PIM) to a series of intangible capital investment going back to 1995 and using the depreciation rates (δR) as suggested by Corrado et al. (2009): 20% for R&D, design, and new product development in the financial services industry; 35% for software; 40% for organizational capital and firm-specific human capital; 60% for brand names; and 13.75% for entertainment, artistic and literary originals, and mineral exploration. For the calculation of the intangible capital stock Rt, the PIM takes the following form:

$$ {R}_t={N}_t+\left(1-{\delta}_R\right){R}_{t-1} $$
(2.2)

which assumes that (1) geometric depreciation, (2) constant depreciation rates over time, and (3) depreciation rates for each type of asset are the same for all countries. The real investment series for (Nt) uses a GVA price deflator which is the same for all intangibles.

5.5 A Note on the Construction of Intangible and Tangible Capital Services

Data on intangible capital service services were generated according to the work by Oulton and Srinivasan (2003) and Marrano et al. (2009) and are consistent with the EU KLEMS approach (Timmer et al., 2007). This work contends that rather than using a wealth measure (such as the capital stock), it is vital to ascertain the flow of services a capital stock can provide to production. The technical steps of the construction of intangible and tangible capital services are in line with Roth and Thum (2013) and are explained in detail in Appendix 1.

6 Descriptive Analysis

Table 2.A1 in Appendix 2 shows the descriptive statistics of the analyzed dataset. Labor productivity growth increased by 0.1% points (from 1.5 to 1.6), or by 6.7%, a slightly higher value than the value of 4.4% detected in previous work (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 498). Figure 2.1 shows the business intangible capital investment over GVA for the eight intangible capital indicators for the 16 EU countries over the 16-year average time period 2000–2015. The figure shows that overall business intangible capital investments vary considerably across the 16 EU countries. Sweden ranks first with an investment of 17.1%. This is similar to the findings by Edquist (2011), who reports an investment rate of 16, but higher than the findings by Roth and Thum (2013), who report an investment rate of 13.6% over business GVA. Sweden is followed by Finland, France, Denmark, and Ireland with investment rates of 15.6%, 14.5%, 13.4%, and 13.4% over GVA, respectively. Such values are again higher than those found by Roth and Thum (2013). In particular, the Irish case seems noteworthy, given its low values in the literature (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 498). Most countries’ investment rates are positioned between 9% and 12%, and therefore fall near the EU-16 average investment rate of 11%. This is in the range of the value of 9.9%, as reported in earlier econometric work (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 498). The lowest investment levels can be detected in Spain, Slovakia, and Greece, with values of 7.0, 6.8, and 4.5, respectively. Overall, it is noteworthy that the equal investment levels for Germany and Italy—with values of 9.3% and 9.2%—as well as the pronounced difference between Germany and France by 5.2% points, were not detected in the earlier literature using INNODRIVE data (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 498).Footnote 7

Fig. 2.1
A bar graph features business intangible investments for 16 European countries from Greece to Sweden and for the entire E U 16. It features 17 bars with 8 segments each for: soft d b, min-art, N F P, design, R and D, brand, org cap, F S H C.

Business intangible investment (as a percentage of GVA) in 16 EU countries, 2000–2015 Notes: Investments are compared to GVA (non-farm business sector b-n + r-s excluding real estate activity). Softdb = software and databases; Minart = entertainment, artistic and literary originals, and mineral exploration; NFP = new product development costs in the financial industry; Design = design; R&D = research and development; Brand = brand names; Org.Cap. = organizational capital; FSHC = firm-specific human capital.

Sources: INTAN-Invest (NACE2) data (Corrado et al., 2018).

In order to analyze the distribution of the three intangible dimensions, Fig. 2.2 displays a scatterplot between the innovative property and economic competencies. The five countries located in the upper-right corner—Sweden, Ireland, Finland, Denmark, and France—can be classified as highly innovative and strong investors in economic competencies. In addition, four out of these five countries score high on computerized information. There are some economies, however, that are highly innovative, but which invest less in economic competencies and computerized information, such as Germany.Footnote 8 The third category includes countries that score low on innovative property but high on economic competencies, namely the UK, the Netherlands, and Portugal, of which only the Netherlands scores high on promoting computerized information. The fourth category contains countries that score low on both dimensions: Italy, Spain, Slovakia, and Greece. Three out of these four countries also score low on computerized information.

Fig. 2.2
A scatter plot of economic competencies versus innovative property plots high and low computerized information as 17 datapoints.

Scatterplot between innovative property and economic competencies (as a percentage of GVA), 2000–2015

Notes: The dashed lines indicate the EU16 average values. AT = Austria; CZ = Czech Republic; DE = Germany; DK = Denmark; EL = Greece; ES = Spain; FI = Finland; FR = France; IE = Ireland; IT = Italy; NL = the Netherlands; PT = Portugal; SE = Sweden; SI= Slovenia; SK = Slovakia; UK = United Kingdom.

Sources: INTAN-Invest (NACE2) data (Corrado et al., 2018).

Figure 2.3 compares business investments in intangible and tangible capital as used in the econometric estimation. Once intangibles are included in the asset boundary of the national accounts, the average level of investment of the 16 EU countries is 25.1%. This value is significantly higher than the value produced if one only considers tangible capital investment, which would be at 14.1%. Among the 16 EU countries, seven countries (Finland, France, Sweden, the Netherlands, the United Kingdom, Ireland, and Denmark) invest more in intangibles than in tangibles—their share of intangible/tangible investment is already greater than 1%. This is in line with the finding by Nakamura (2010), who detected this pattern for the US as early as the year 2000, but contrasts with an earlier analysis for the time period 1998–2005 (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 500), which did not find such a pronounced pattern.Footnote 9

Fig. 2.3
A bar graph features business tangible and intangible capital investments for 16 European countries from Greece to Czech Republic and for the entire E U 16. It features 17 bars with 7 segments each for: C T, I T, O-con, O-mac, Tra-Eq, Cult, and I C.

Business tangible and intangible capital investments (as a percentage of GVA), EU16, 2000–2015

Notes: CT = communications technology; IT = information technology; OCon = total non-residential capital investment; OMach = other machinery and equipment; TraEq = transport equipment; Cult = cultivated assets; IC = intangible capital. Residential Structure has been excluded. Values on top of the bars depict the intangible/tangible capital investment ratio.

Sources: INTAN-Invest (NACE2) data (Corrado et al., 2018) and EUKLEMS data (Jäger, 2017).

Figure 2.4 shows the time series pattern for intangible and tangible capital investment and labor productivity growth for the 16 individual EU countries and the average EU-16 pattern. Three findings are especially noteworthy. First, in line with earlier literature (Corrado et al., 2018), when analyzing an average EU-16 time series pattern, the crisis has led to a slight decline in intangible capital investment but a more pronounced decline in tangible capital. Whereas intangible capital investments have swiftly recovered, tangible capital investments have not yet recovered to pre-crisis levels. Second, the decline in investment in tangible capital has been pronounced in EA countries due to the sovereign debt crisis, particularly in Greece, Spain, Italy, Portugal, and Slovenia. Conversely, with the exception of Greece, intangible capital investment has even increased in these countries in times of crisis and economic recovery. Third, the Irish case is exceptional. In times of economic recovery, Ireland has managed to more than double its intangible capital investments—largely due to significant investments in R&D.

Fig. 2.4
Seventeen line-graphs feature tangible and intangible investments and labor productivity between 2000 to 2015 for 16 European countries and for the entire E U 16.

Investments in intangibles and tangibles and labor productivity in the 16 EU countries (2000–2015)

Notes: Investment in intangibles, tangibles, and labor productivity are given in millions of national currencies and are standardized to 1 in the year 2008. The continuous line indicates the start of the financial crisis in September 2008. The dashed line indicates the start of the economic recovery at the end of 2013. Adapted y-scales are applied to Greece, Ireland, and Slovakia. EU-16 average is based on PPP-adjusted values.

Sources: INTAN-Invest (NACE2) data (Corrado et al., 2018).

7 Econometric Estimation

We estimate eq. (2.1) with the help of a pooled panel (PP) estimation approach.Footnote 10 To control for panel heteroscedasticity, a panel-corrected standard error estimation procedure (PCSE) was used.Footnote 11 It should be noted that the PP-PCSE estimation yields the same coefficients as a random-effects estimator (see row 27 in Table 2.3). This property permits us to compare our results directly with the econometric findings of the existing literature (Roth & Thum, 2013, pp. 501–505). Regression 2.1 in Table 2.2 shows the results when estimating a traditional production function without the inclusion of intangibles (excluding software, R&D, and entertainment, artistic and literary originals, and mineral exploration from the tangible capital investment). Growth in tangible capital services is positively associated with labor productivity growth and has a coefficient of 0.31, which explains a 64% share of labor productivity growth.Footnote 12 Regression 2.2 includes intangibles. Growth in intangible capital services positively relates to labor productivity growth with a coefficient of a magnitude of 0.38, explaining 66% of labor productivity growth. As can be inferred from Table 2.1, this value is higher than the figure of 50% reported in earlier work (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 502). Once intangibles are included, the impact of tangible capital diminishes to 34%, which is a slightly lower value than previously reported in the literature (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 503).Footnote 13 This finding clarifies that intangible capital investments have become the dominant source of growth in EU countries.

Table 2.2 Intangibles and labor productivity growth, 2000–2015, PP-PCSE estimation

Regression 3 in Table 2.2 analyzes the relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity during times of crisis by adding a crisis (2008–2013) interaction effect to the specification of regression 2. Regression 3 clarifies that while the relationship between tangible capital services growth and labor productivity growth actually turns negative in times of crisis, with a coefficient of 0.04 (0.28–0.32), the relationship between intangible capital services growth and labor productivity growth remains positive with a coefficient of 0.20 (0.48–0.28). To analyze this novel finding in more detail, regression 4 adds a recovery interaction effect (2014–2015) to a crisis-recovery sub-sample (2008–2015). Regression 4 clarifies that in times of economic recovery, intangible capital services growth has a strong positive relationship to labor productivity growth. This finding is particularly evident in Ireland in 2015, where a large intangible service growth (20%) is related to a large labor productivity growth of (25.8%) (see rows 2 and 3 in Table 2.3 and Fig. 2.4).

Table 2.3 Sensitivity analysis for the baseline PP-PCSE estimator

Regression 5 assesses which dimensions of intangible capital services are the key drivers for the positive relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity growth. It includes 1) computerized information, 2) innovative property, and 3) economic competencies. In contrast to earlier work (Roth & Thum, 2013, p. 503), which finds economic competencies to be the main driver, we now find innovative property to be a strong driver (0.37) of labor productivity growth. This relationship describes the evidence in the Irish case in 2015, in which a large share of innovative property services growth is related to a large labor productivity growth. Excluding Ireland in rows 23–25 in Table 2.3 renders innovative property insignificant and re-establishes economic competencies with a coefficient of 0.17 as the main driver. In order to control for potential endogeneity, regression 6 estimates eq. (2.1) with the help of a 2SLS estimation approach and 208 overall observations. Following earlier econometric work by Roth and Thum (2013, p. 503), lagged levels of intangible and tangible capital as instruments were chosen.Footnote 14 The results clarify that while the relationship between tangible capital and labor productivity growth is rendered insignificant after controlling for endogeneity, the coefficient for intangible capital services growth remains highly significant, yielding a further increase in magnitude (0.50). The sensitivity analysis in Table 2.3 further explores the robustness of the coefficient of intangible capital on labor productivity growth, from regression 2, permitting us to conduct an analysis with a maximum of 256 observations.

Table 2.3 displays a sensitivity analysis of regression 2 in Table 2.2. The first row shows the coefficient for the Baseline regression, regression 2 in Table 2.2. Rows 2–6 analyze the sensitivity due to influential cases.Footnote 15 When controlling for Ireland in 2015, as expected, the intangible capital coefficient declines (0.26), explaining a 46% share of labor productivity growth. A similar decline in magnitude (0.24 and 0.28) is found when excluding Ireland or Ireland and Greece from the country sample in rows 3 and 5. Excluding Greece in row 4 yields a higher coefficient (0.44). Excluding the three new member states in row 6 yields a slight reduction of the coefficient (0.37). Rows 7–12 restructure the country sample and analyze five distinct European regime dummies. When analyzing the 13 EU countries from 2000 to 2015 from earlier work (Roth & Thum, 2013), the relationship remains highly significant and reveals an increase in magnitude (0.52). Neither controlling for the five European regime dummies in rows 8–12, nor altering the model specifications in rows 13–22, nor using alternative estimation approaches in rows 26–27 alters the significance of the relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity in any appreciable manner, although the magnitude of the relationship varies slightly.

8 Conclusions

This contribution analyzes the relationship between intangible capital investment by businesses and labor productivity growth by analyzing an EU-16 country sample over the time period 2000–2015, with the help of a cross-country growth-accounting estimation approach. By matching the most recent release of the INTAN-Invest (NACE2) dataset (Corrado et al., 2018) with the latest data available from the EU KLEMS dataset (Jäger, 2017) alongside a wide range of growth-relevant policy variables from Eurostat, the OECD, and the World Bank, this contribution generates the largest and most up-to-date panel dataset developed on intangible capital at the macro-level, based on a total of 256 country observations.

This contribution reaches three major findings. First, in line with previous growth econometric literature (Roth & Thum, 2013), this contribution confirms that once intangibles are factored into the calculations, they become the dominant source—up to 66%—of labor productivity growth in the EU. Second, when focussing on times of crisis (2008–2013), this contribution finds that whereas the relationship between tangible capital and labor productivity turned negative, the impact of intangibles on growth remained solidly positive throughout this period. Thirdly, when accounting for the economic recovery (2014–2015), this contribution establishes a highly significant and remarkably strong relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity growth.

In light of these novel empirical results, four main policy conclusions can be drawn from our analysis of European economies. First, given the paucity of econometric findings in the literature analyzing the relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity growth at the macro-level, additional research should be devoted in the future to further econometrically corroborate the positive relationship between intangible capital and labor productivity. This future research should examine in more detail the evolutionary changes in existing cross-country intangible capital datasets, by country and by asset type. Second, as developed economies transition into knowledge societies, it is essential to incorporate a complete set of intangibles—including branding, firm-specific human capital, and organizational capital—into today’s national accounting framework in order to acknowledge the pronounced shift in investment patterns from tangible to intangible investment in contemporary national accounting frameworks. The current frameworks are inadequate, as they under-represent actual levels of capital investment in European economies. Their reported levels of capital investment would undoubtedly be greater once the full range of investment in intangible capital is incorporated into the accounting framework.

Third, the incorporation of a broader dimension of innovation investment seems to be an important first step in revising today’s national accounting framework, particularly when focusing on the business sector. Moreover, a follow-up step consists of broadly adapting the national accounting framework to reflect environmental, health, and public intangible capital investment. Fourth, government policies that actively support the accumulation of business intangibles should be designed and implemented as soon as possible. This will foremost require government investment in public intangibles, such as enhancing the quantity and quality of a highly skilled labor force, well-functioning formal and informal institutions, and a well-designed policy framework that includes credible financial conditions and an effective scheme offering intangible tax incentives at the member state and EU level.Footnote 16