Abstract
A recent literature explores how domestic institutions affect politicians’ incentives to enter into international agreements (IAs). We contribute to this field by systematically testing the impact of a broad set of domestic institutional design features. This allows us to compare new and established political economy explanations of IA entry. For this purpose, 99 democracies are analyzed over the period 1975 to 2010. We find that domestic institutions determine countries’ disposition to enter into IAs, as predicted by political economic theory. For example, democracies with majoritarian electoral institutions are less likely to conclude IAs than other democracies. Countries also conclude more IAs when their democratic institutions are long-lived and they lack an independent judiciary. However, programmatic parties and the number of domestic veto players are not associated with IA-making. The key take-away of this study is that specific domestic institutions matter for how frequently states make formal deals with each other.
Published as:
Kiesow Cortez, F. and J. Gutmann (2017). Domestic Institutions and the Ratification of International Agreements in a Panel of Democracies. Constitutional Political Economy 28(2): 142–66.
Access this chapter
Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout
Purchases are for personal use only
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
- 1.
As of this writing 114 states have ratified the Vienna Convention and 15 more have signed but not yet ratified the convention. Many non-signatory states recognize that the convention or parts of it reflect customary international law.
- 2.
The dilemma of the strong state is discussed, for example, in Dreher and Voigt (2011). The dilemma involves a commitment problem of the state vis-à-vis its citizens. On the one hand, the state should be strong enough to enforce private property rights. On the other, if a state is powerful enough to enforce property rights, it can misuse its strength to violate those rights. See also Weingast (1995), who argues federalism could be one way of solving the dilemma.
- 3.
This issue is discussed in Cox and McCubbins (2001).
- 4.
According to Vreeland (2007) these costs include (1) being denied access to the IMF loan; (2) increased difficulty in rescheduling debt, since informal creditor organizations (such as the Paris Club) require good standing under an IMF agreement; and (3) fear of decreased FDI because of the negative signal from a failed IMF agreement.
- 5.
This is the case when the executive has an informational advantage and enhanced authority over veto players regarding the conclusion of IAs, which appears to be a plausible assumption. However, research by Mansfield and Milner (2012) on PTAs assumes that domestic veto players have enough political weight to prevent the executive from entering into PTAs. If this applies, governments will be hindered from strategically using IAs to overcome veto player opposition.
- 6.
For simplicity, we do not show the joint probability or log likelihood function. The interested reader is referred to Cameron and Trivedi (2005: 804) for a comprehensive discussion.
- 7.
To further rule out problems caused by collinearity in our data, we have checked bivariate correlations between our independent variables as well as variance inflation factors (VIFs) from a model estimated with OLS. All bivariate correlations are below 0.8. Unsurprisingly, the highest positive correlations are between income per capita, democracy, and judicial independence. The highest negative correlations are between income and aid dependence, and between population size and trade openness. The VIFs also suggest no reason for concern about collinearity. Judicial independence and income per capita show the highest VIFs with 5.5 and 4.6 respectively.
References
Acemoglu, D. (2005). Constitutions, politics, and economics: A review essay on Persson and Tabellini’s the economic effects of constitutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(4), 1025–1048.
Alcañiz, I. (2012). Democratization and multilateral security. World Politics, 64(2), 306–340.
Baccini, L., & Urpelainen, J. (2014). International institutions and domestic politics: Can preferential trading agreements help leaders promote economic reform? Journal of Politics, 76(1), 195–214.
Barrett, S. (1999). International cooperation and the international commons. Duke Environmental Law & Policy Forum, 10(1), 131–145.
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176.
Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V., & Spilker, G. (2010). A comparison of international and domestic sources of global governance dynamics. British Journal of Political Science, 40(3), 509–538.
Blume, L., Müller, J., Voigt, S., & Wolf, C. (2009). The economic effects of constitutions: Replicating–and extending–Persson and Tabellini. Public Choice, 139(1), 197–225.
Bormann, N.-C., & Golder, M. (2013). Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946–2011. Electoral Studies, 32(2), 360–369.
Brambor, T., Clark, W. R., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.
Brennan, G., & Kliemt, H. (1994). Finite lives and social institutions. Kyklos, 47(4), 551–571.
Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2005). Microeconometrics: Methods and applications. Cambridge University Press.
Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67–101.
Congleton, R. D. (1992). Political institutions and pollution control. Review of Economics and Statistics, 74(3), 412–421.
Copelovitch, M. S., & Ohls, D. (2012). Trade, institutions, and the timing of GATT/WTO accession in post-colonial states. Review of International Organizations, 7(1), 81–107.
Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (2001). The institutional determinants of economic policy outcomes. In S. Haggard & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.), Presidents, parliaments, and policy (pp. 21–63). Cambridge University Press.
Cruz, C., & Keefer, P. (2015). Political parties, clientelism, and bureaucratic reform. Comparative Political Studies, 48(14), 1942–1973.
Dreher, A., & Lang, V. F. (2019). The political economy of international organizations. In R. Congleton, B. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of public choice (Vol. 2, pp. 607–652). Oxford University Press.
Dreher, A., & Voigt, S. (2011). Does membership in international organizations increase governments’ credibility? Testing the effects of delegating powers. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39(3), 326–348.
Dreher, A., Gaston, N., & Matens, P. (2008). Measuring globalization – Gauging its consequences. Springer.
Drezner, D. W. (2003). Introduction. In D. W. Drezner (Ed.), Locating the proper authorities: The interaction of domestic and international institutions (pp. 1–22). University of Michigan Press.
Elkins, Z., Ginsburg, T., & Melton, J. (2009). The endurance of national constitutions. Cambridge University Press.
Fang, S., & Owen, E. (2011). International institutions and credible commitment of non-democracies. Review of International Organizations, 6(2), 141–162.
Feld, L. P., & Voigt, S. (2003). Economic growth and judicial independence: Cross-country evidence using a new set of indicators. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 497–527.
Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (2000). Ratification of the 1992 climate change convention: What determines legislative delay? Public Choice, 104(3), 345–368.
Funk, P., & Gathmann, C. (2013). How do electoral systems affect fiscal policy? Evidence from cantonal parliaments, 1890–2000. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(5), 1178–1203.
Gagliarducci, S., Nannicini, T., & Naticchioni, P. (2011). Electoral rules and politicians’ behavior: A micro test. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 3(3), 144–174.
Ginsburg, T. (2009). International delegation and state disaggregation. Constitutional Political Economy, 20(3–4), 323–340.
Gourevitch, P. A. (1999). The governance problem in international relations. In D. Lake & R. Powell (Eds.), Strategic choice and international relations (pp. 137–164). Princeton University Press.
Grossman, G. M. (2016). The purpose of trade agreements. In K. Bagwell & R. W. Staiger (Eds.), Handbook of commercial policy (Vol. 1A, pp. 379–434). Elsevier.
Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.
Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1995). The politics of free-trade agreements. American Economic Review, 85(4), 667–690.
Guzman, A. (2008). How international law works: A rational choice approach. Oxford University Press.
Hausman, J., Hall, B. H., & Griliches, Z. (1984). Econometric models for count data with an application to the patents-R & D relationship. Econometrica, 52(4), 909–938.
Helfer, L. R. (2005). Exiting treaties. Virginia Law Review, 91(7), 1579–1648.
Henisz, W. J. (2000). The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics and Politics, 12(1), 1–31.
Henisz, W. J. (2002). The institutional environment for infrastructure investment. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(2), 355–389.
Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2012). Penn world table version 7.1. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania.
Hollis, D. B. (2012). Introduction. In D. B. Hollis (Ed.), The Oxford guide to treaties (pp. 1–8). Oxford University Press.
Imhof, S., Gutmann, J., & Voigt, S. (2016). The economics of green constitutions. Asian Journal of Law and Economics, 7(3), 305–322.
Johns, L., & Rosendorff, B. P. (2009). Dispute settlement, compliance and domestic politics. In J. C. Hartigan (Ed.), Trade disputes and the dispute settlement understanding of the WTO: An interdisciplinary assessment (pp. 139–163). Emerald Group.
Keefer, P. (2011). Collective action, political parties, and pro-development public policy. Asian Development Review, 28(1), 94–118.
Keefer, P. (2018). Organizing for prosperity: Collective action, political parties, and the political economy of development. In C. Lancaster & N. van de Walle (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of the politics of development (pp. 431–457). Oxford University Press.
Keohane, R. O. (1984). After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton University Press.
Kosfeld, M., Okada, A., & Riedl, A. (2009). Institution formation in public goods games. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1335–1355.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1999). The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 15(1), 222–279.
Linzer, D. A., & Staton, J. K. (2015). A global measure of judicial independence, 1948–2012. Journal of Law and Courts, 3(2), 223–256.
Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91(1), 225–239.
Maggi, G., & Rodriguez-Clare, A. (1998). The value of trade agreements in the presence of political pressures. Journal of Political Economy, 106(3), 574–601.
Mansfield, E. D., & Milner, H. V. (2012). Votes, vetoes, and the political economy of international trade agreements. Princeton University Press.
Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V., & Rosendorff, B. P. (2002). Why democracies cooperate more: Electoral control and international trade agreements. International Organization, 56(3), 477–513.
Marshall, M. G., Gurr, T. R., & Jaggers, K. (2014). Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2013.
Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., Perotti, R., & Rostagno, M. (2002). Electoral systems and public spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2), 609–657.
Milewicz, K. M., & Elsig, M. (2014). The hidden world of multilateralism: Treaty commitments of newly democratized states in Europe. International Studies Quarterly, 58(2), 322–335.
Milner, H. V. (1997). Interests, institutions, and information: Domestic politics and international relations. Princeton University Press.
Milner, H. V., Rosendorff, B. P., & Mansfield, E. D. (2004). International trade and domestic politics: The domestic sources of international agreements and institutions. In E. Benvenisti & M. Hirsch (Eds.), The impact of international law on international cooperation (pp. 216–243). Cambridge University Press.
Moe, T. M. (1990). Political institutions: The neglected side of the story. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 6, 213–253.
Moravcsik, A. (2000). The origins of human rights regimes: Democratic delegation in postwar Europe. International Organization, 54(2), 217–252.
Mulligan, C. B., & Shleifer, A. (2005). The extent of the market and the supply of regulation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1445–1473.
Murdoch, J. C., & Sandler, T. (1997). The voluntary provision of a pure public good: The case of reduced CFC emissions and the Montreal protocol. Journal of Public Economics, 63(3), 331–349.
Murdoch, J. C., Sandler, T., & Sargent, K. (1997). A tale of two collectives: Sulphur versus nitrogen oxides emission reduction in Europe. Economica, 64(254), 281–301.
Neumayer, E. (2002). Does trade openness promote multilateral environmental cooperation? The World Economy, 25(6), 815–832.
North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutional governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.
Nzelibe, J. (2011). Strategic globalization: International law as an extension of domestic political conflict. Northwestern University Law Review, 105(2), 635–688.
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.
Padovano, F., Sgarra, G., & Fiorino, N. (2003). Judicial branch, checks and balances and political accountability. Constitutional Political Economy, 14(1), 47–70.
Parisi, F., & Pi, D. (2016). The economic analysis of international treaty law. In E. Kontorovich & F. Parisi (Eds.), Economic analysis of international law (pp. 101–122). Edward Elgar.
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. E. (2000). Political economics: Explaining economic policy. MIT.
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. E. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. MIT.
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. E. (2004). Constitutional rules and fiscal policy outcomes. American Economic Review, 94(1), 25–45.
Phelan, W. (2011). Open international markets without exclusion: Encompassing domestic political institutions, international organization, and self-contained regimes. International Theory, 3(2), 286–306.
Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427–460.
Rickard, S. J. (2010). Democratic differences: Electoral institutions and compliance with GATT/WTO agreements. European Journal of International Relations, 16(4), 711–729.
Sandler, T. (2008). Treaties: Strategic considerations. University of Illinois Law Review, 1, 155–180.
Setear, J. K. (1996). An iterative perspective on treaties: A synthesis of international relations theory and international law. Harvard International Law Journal, 37(1), 139–229.
Snidal, D., & Thompson, A. (2003). International commitments and domestic politics: Institutions and actors at two levels. In D. W. Drezner (Ed.), Locating the proper authorities: The interaction of domestic and international institutions (pp. 197–230). University of Michigan Press.
Spilker, G., & Koubi, V. (2016). The effects of treaty legality and domestic institutional hurdles on environmental treaty ratification. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 16(2), 223–238.
Sykes, A. O. (2007). International law. In A. M. Polinsky & S. Shavell (Eds.), Handbook of law and economics (Vol. 1, pp. 757–826). Elsevier.
Vaubel, R. (1986). A public choice approach to international organization. Public Choice, 51(1), 39–57.
Voigt, S. (2012). The economics of informal international law: An empirical assessment. In J. Pauwelyn, R. A. Wessel, & J. Wouters (Eds.), Informal international lawmaking (pp. 79–105). Oxford University Press.
Voigt, S., & Gutmann, J. (2013). Turning cheap talk into economic growth: On the relationship between property rights and judicial independence. Journal of Comparative Economics, 41(1), 66–73.
Voigt, S., & Salzberger, E. M. (2002). Choosing not to choose: When politicians choose to delegate powers. Kyklos, 55(2), 289–310.
Voigt, S., Gutmann, J., & Feld, L. P. (2015). Economic growth and judicial independence, a dozen years on: Cross-country evidence using an updated set of indicators. European Journal of Political Economy, 38, 197–211.
Vreeland, J. R. (2003). The IMF and economic development. Cambridge University Press.
Vreeland, J. R. (2007). The international monetary fund: Politics of conditional lending. Routledge.
Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 11(1), 1–31.
World Bank. (2014). World Development Indicators. Available at: data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Editor information
Editors and Affiliations
Appendices
Appendix 1: Description of Variables and Data Sources
Variable | Description and source |
---|---|
New treaties | Number of New Treaties in t. Source: Dreher et al. (2008) |
No. of treaties in t-1 | Number of Existing Treaties (in thousands) in t – 1. Source: Dreher et al. (2008) |
Log income per capita | Logarithm of PPP-adj. GDP per capita (Laspeyres) at 2005 constant prices. Source: Heston et al. (2012) |
Log population | Logarithm of population (in thousands). Source: Heston et al. (2012) |
Log openness | Openness at 2005 constant prices (in %). Source: Heston et al. (2012) |
Level of democracy | Polity2, ranges from +10 (strongly democratic) to −10 (strongly autocratic). Source: Marshall et al. (2014) |
Log age of democracy | Logarithm of number of years since country was nondemocratic. Source: Cheibub et al. (2010) and own calculations |
Presidential system | Country classified as presidential democracy. Source: Cheibub et al. (2010), updated based on Bormann and Golder (2013) |
Common law | Common-law legal system. Source: La Porta et al. (1999) |
Aid dependence | Net ODA received (% of GNI). Source: World Bank (2014) |
Majoritarian system | Country classified as majoritarian electoral system. Source: Bormann and Golder (2013) |
Programmatic parties | Own calculation: Share of PPs among gov. parties and largest opposition party. Source: Beck et al. (2001) |
CCP-approve | Own calculation: Number of actors needed to approve international agreements (treatap). Source: Elkins et al. (2009) |
CCP-initiate | Own calculation: Number of actors with competence to initiate international agreements (treatini). Source: Elkins et al. (2009) |
CCP-revoke | Own calculation: Number of actors with competence to revoke international agreements (treatrvk). Source: Elkins et al. (2009) |
Judicial independence | Level of judicial independence. Source: Linzer and Staton (2015) |
Checks (DPI) | Checks and balances. Source: Beck et al. (2001) |
Checks (DPI), dummy | Own calculation: 1 if checks (DPI) > 3, else 0. Source: Beck et al. (2001) |
PolCon III (Henisz) | Political constraints. Source: Henisz (2002) |
PolCon V (Henisz) | Political constraints, includes two additional veto points (the judiciary and sub-federal entities). Source: Henisz (2000) |
Appendix 2: List of Countries
Albania | Germany | Nicaragua |
Argentina | Ghana | Niger |
Armenia | Greece | Nigeria |
Australia | Guatemala | Norway |
Austria | Guinea-Bissau | Pakistan |
Bangladesh | Honduras | Panama |
Belgium | Hungary | Papua New Guinea |
Benin | India | Paraguay |
Bhutan | Indonesia | Peru |
Bolivia | Ireland | Philippines |
Brazil | Israel | Poland |
Bulgaria | Italy | Portugal |
Burundi | Jamaica | Romania |
Canada | Japan | Senegal |
Cape Verde | Kenya | Sierra Leone |
Central African Republic | Korea, South | Slovakia |
Chile | Kyrgyzstan | Slovenia |
Colombia | Latvia | Solomon Islands |
Comoros | Liberia | Spain |
Congo | Lithuania | Sri Lanka |
Costa Rica | Luxembourg | Sudan |
Croatia | Macedonia | Suriname |
Cyprus | Madagascar | Sweden |
Czech Republic | Malawi | Switzerland |
Denmark | Mali | Thailand |
Dominican Republic | Mauritania | Trinidad and Tobago |
Ecuador | Mauritius | Turkey |
El Salvador | Mexico | Uganda |
Estonia | Moldova | Ukraine |
Fiji | Mongolia | United Kingdom |
Finland | Nepal | United States |
France | Netherlands | Uruguay |
Georgia | New Zealand | Venezuela |
Appendix 3: Correlation Matrix
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) Majoritarian system | 1 | ||||||
(2) Programmatic parties | −0.16 [0.15] | 1 | |||||
(3) CCP-approve | −0.35 [0.00] | −0.09 [0.41] | 1 | ||||
(4) CCP-initiate | −0.26 [0.02] | −0.10 [0.35] | 0.25 [0.02] | 1 | |||
(5) CCP-revoke | −0.32 [0.00] | −0.09 [0.43] | 0.23 [0.04] | 0.25 [0.02] | 1 | ||
(6) Judicial independence | −0.06 [0.58] | 0.51 [0.00] | −0.09 [0.39] | −0.05 [0.66] | 0.05 [0.62] | 1 | |
(7) Checks (DPI) | 0.01 [0.91] | 0.33 [0.00] | −0.05 [0.64] | 0.02 [0.85] | −0.07 [0.51] | 0.26 [0.02] | 1 |
Appendix 4: Additional Regression Results
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
No. of treaties (in t – 1) | 1.129* | 1.105(*) | 1.114(*) | 1.098 | 1.139* |
(0.065) | (0.064) | (0.067) | (0.064) | (0.069) | |
Log income per capita | 0.876(*) | 0.877(*) | 0.864* | 0.898 | 0.883 |
(0.062) | (0.063) | (0.062) | (0.069) | (0.067) | |
Log population | 1.086* | 1.070(*) | 1.075(*) | 1.075(*) | 1.091* |
(0.044) | (0.043) | (0.043) | (0.044) | (0.044) | |
Log openness | 1.151(*) | 1.141(*) | 1.167* | 1.180* | 1.195* |
(0.086) | (0.086) | (0.088) | (0.090) | (0.091) | |
Level of democracy | 1.032** | 1.034** | 1.033** | 1.055*** | 1.053*** |
(0.012) | (0.012) | (0.012) | (0.016) | (0.016) | |
Log age of democracy | 1.165*** | 1.154*** | 1.148*** | 1.173*** | 1.171*** |
(0.043) | (0.042) | (0.043) | (0.044) | (0.045) | |
Presidential system | 1.172 | 1.237 | 1.221 | 1.254 | 1.133 |
(0.170) | (0.180) | (0.175) | (0.182) | (0.163) | |
Common law | 0.883 | 0.758* | 0.733* | 0.767* | 0.875 |
(0.124) | (0.098) | (0.100) | (0.101) | (0.129) | |
Aid dependence | 0.985* | 0.985** | 0.985** | 0.984** | 0.984** |
(0.006) | (0.006) | (0.006) | (0.006) | (0.006) | |
Majoritarian system | 0.741** | 0.741** | |||
(0.080) | (0.080) | ||||
Programmatic parties | 0.938 | 0.948 | |||
(0.090) | (0.091) | ||||
CCP-approve | 0.948 | 0.951 | |||
(0.051) | (0.052) | ||||
CCP-initiate | 1.070 | 1.079 | |||
(0.067) | (0.068) | ||||
CCP-revoke | 0.900(*) | 0.896(*) | |||
(0.056) | (0.057) | ||||
Judicial independence | 0.105* | 0.107* | |||
(0.116) | (0.116) | ||||
Judicial independence2 | 3.768(*) | 4.028(*) | |||
(2.951) | (3.133) | ||||
Observations | 2158 | 2158 | 2158 | 2158 | 2158 |
Countries | 99 | 99 | 99 | 99 | 99 |
Region fixed effects | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Decade fixed effects | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Time trend | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Log-likelihood | −5314 | −5318 | −5316 | −5315 | −5309 |
Rights and permissions
Copyright information
© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG
About this chapter
Cite this chapter
Kiesow Cortez, F., Gutmann, J. (2021). Domestic Institutions and the Ratification of International Agreements in a Panel of Democracies. In: Kiesow Cortez, F. (eds) The Political Economy of International Agreements. International Law and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-85194-1_3
Download citation
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-85194-1_3
Published:
Publisher Name: Springer, Cham
Print ISBN: 978-3-030-85193-4
Online ISBN: 978-3-030-85194-1
eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)