Skip to main content

The Value of Industry Studies: Impact of Luigi Orsenigo’s Legacy on the Field of Innovation and Industry Evolution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Innovation, Catch-up and Sustainable Development

Part of the book series: Economic Complexity and Evolution ((ECAE))

  • 485 Accesses

Abstract

New solutions in artificial intelligence and machine learning require researchers to study, in greater depth, the nature, and dynamics of emerging industries like biotechnology or pharmaceuticals. With his pioneering work, Luigi Orsenigo has demonstrated, in great detail, how new technologies create technological opportunities, change appropriability conditions, and cumulativeness in these emerging industries. Rooted in the evolutionary economics tradition, this approach is better suited in explaining the patterns of innovation, technological change, and the growth in very dynamic industries. In this context, our article reviews the evidence of Luigi Orsenigo’s contribution to the economics of innovation, to the tradition of history-friendly models, and to the discussion on the sectoral system of innovation. It concludes by pointing at some unresolved questions in these traditions and new fruitful alleys for future researchers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In Luigi Orsenigo’s lifelong academic research, he developed theory and methodologies with his co-authors. We use the term legacy to discuss his contribution to the academy through the joint works.

  2. 2.

    System of innovation is oriented toward the macro level, and the Mode 2 argument is concerned almost exclusively with the conditions for the organization and production of knowledge.

References

  • Barbanti, P., Gambardella, A., & Orsenigo, L. (1999). The evolution of collaborative relationships among firms in biotechnology. International Journal of Biotechnology, 1(1), 10–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi, G., Dosi, G., & Rocchetti, G. (2001). Modes of knowledge accumulation, entry regimes and patterns of industrial evolution. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(3), 609–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brenner, T., & Murmann, J. P. (2003). The use of simulations in developing robust knowledge about causal processes: Methodological considerations and an application to industrial evolution. In Computing in economics and Finance. Society for Computational Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breschi, S., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2000). Technological regimes and Schumpeterian patterns of innovation. The Economic Journal, 110(463), 388–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, G. S., & Orsenigo, L. (2003). Variables influencing industrial funding of academic research in Italy: An empirical analysis. International Journal of Technology Management, 26(2–4), 277–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buvailo, A. (2018). How big pharma adopts AI to boost drug discovery. BiopharmaTrend.com 8 October 2018.

  • Capone, G., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2013). Are switching costs always effective in creating first-mover advantage? The moderating role of demand and technological regimes. Long Range Planning, 46(4–5), 348–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castellacci, F. (2008). Technological paradigms, regimes and trajectories: Manufacturing and service industries in a new taxonomy of sectoral patterns of innovation. Research Policy, 37(6–7), 978–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cefis, E., & Orsenigo, L. (2001). The persistence of innovative activities: A cross-countries and cross-sectors comparative analysis. Research Policy, 30(7), 1139–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. (1982). Technological paradigms and technological trajectories: A suggested interpretation of the determinants and directions of technical change. Research Policy, 11(3), 147–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., & Roventini, A. (2006). An evolutionary model of endogenous business cycles. Computational Economics, 27(1), 3–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., & Malerba, F. (2018). In memory of a friend and distinguished scholar: Luigi Orsenigo (1954–2018). Economia e Politica Industriale, 45(2), 109–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Malerba, F., Marsili, O., & Orsenigo, L. (1997). Industrial structures and dynamics: Evidence, interpretations and puzzles. Industrial and Corporate Change, 6(1), 3–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1994). Evolutionary regimes and industrial dynamics. In Evolutionary and neo-Schumpeterian approaches to economics (pp. 203–229). Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Marsili, O., Orsenigo, L., & Salvatore, R. (1995). Learning, market selection and the evolution of industrial structures. Small Business Economics, 7(6), 411–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagiolo, G., & Dosi, G. (2003). Exploitation, exploration and innovation in a model of endogenous growth with locally interacting agents. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 14(3), 237–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontana, R., Guerzoni, M., & Nuvolari, A. (2008). Habakkuk revisited: A history friendly model of American and British technology in the nineteenth century (No. 2008, 064). Jena economic research papers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fontana, R., & Zirulia, L. (2015). “… then came Cisco, and the rest is history”: A ‘history friendly’ model of the Local Area Networking industry. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 25(5), 875–899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garavaglia, C. (2010). Modelling industrial dynamics with “history-friendly” simulations. Structural Change & Economic Dynamics, 21(4), 258–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garavaglia, C., Malerba, F., Orsenigo, L., & Pezzoni, M. (2012). Technological regimes and demand structure in the evolution of the pharmaceutical industry. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 22(4), 677–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giachetti, C., & Marchi, G. (2017). Successive changes in leadership in the worldwide mobile phone industry: The role of windows of opportunity and firms’ competitive action. Research Policy, 46(2), 352–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo, L., Zhang, M. Y., Dodson, M., & Gann, D. (2019). Huawei’s catch-up in the global telecommunication industry: Innovation capability and transition to leadership. Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, 31(12), 1395–1411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hung, S. C., Liu, J. S., Lu, L. Y., & Tseng, Y. C. (2014). Technological change in lithium iron phosphate battery: The key-route main path analysis. Scientometrics, 100(1), 97–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacob, M., & Orsenigo, L. (2007). Leveraging Science for innovation: Swedish policy for university-industry collaboration 1990–2005, SNS Förlag Report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, C. W., & Lee, K. (2003). Innovation, technological regimes and organizational selection in industry evolution: A ‘history friendly model’ of the DRAM industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 12(6), 1195–1221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landini, F., Lee, K., & Malerba, F. (2017). A history-friendly model of the successive changes in industrial leadership and the catch-up by latecomers. Research Policy, 46(2), 431–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landini, F., & Malerba, F. (2017). Public policy and catching up by developing countries in global industries: A simulation model. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 41(3), 927–960.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, K. R. (1996). The role of user firms in the innovation of machine tools: The Japanese case. Research Policy, 25, 491–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, K., & Lim, C. (2001). Technological regimes, catching-up and leapfrogging: Findings from the Korean industries. Research Policy, 30(3), 459–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, K., & Malerba, F. (2017). Catch-up cycles and changes in industrial leadership: Windows of opportunity and responses of firms and countries in the evolution of sectoral systems. Research Policy, 46(2), 338–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, D., Capone, G., & Malerba, F. (2019). The long march to catch-up: A history-friendly model of China’s mobile communications industry. Research Policy, 48(3), 649–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mäkinen, S. J., & Vilkko, M. K. (2014). Product portfolio decision-making and absorptive capacity: A simulation study. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management, 32, 60–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F. (2005). Sectoral systems of innovation: A framework for linking innovation to the knowledge base, structure and dynamics of sectors. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 14(1–2), 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F. (2007). Innovation and the dynamics and evolution of industries: Progress and challenges. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 25(4), 675–699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F. (2011). Modelling innovation and the evolution of industries: History-friendly models. Presentation in GLOBELICS ACADEMY.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Mani, S. (2009). Sectoral systems of innovation and production in developing countries: Actors, structure and evolution. Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., Nelson, R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. (1999). ‘History-friendly’ models of industry evolution: The computer industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 8(1), 3–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., Nelson, R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. (2008). Public policies and changing boundaries of firms in a “history-friendly” model of the co-evolution of the computer and semiconductor industries. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67(2), 355–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., Nelson, R., Orsenigo, L., & Winter, S. (2016). Innovation and the evolution of industries-history-friendly models. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1993). Technological regime and firm behaviour. Industrial and Corporate Change, 2, 45–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1995). Schumpeterian patterns of innovation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(1), 47–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1996). Schumpeterian patterns of innovation are technology-specific. Research Policy, 25(3), 451–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1997). Technological regimes and sectoral patterns of innovative activities. Industrial and Corporate Change, 6(1), 83–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (1999). Technological entry, exit and survival: An empirical analysis of patent data. Research Policy, 28(6), 643–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2000). Knowledge, innovative activities and industrial evolution. Industrial and Corporate Change, 9(2), 289–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2002). Innovation and market structure in the dynamics of the pharmaceutical industry and biotechnology: Towards a history-friendly model. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(4), 667–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2008). User-producer relationships, innovation and the evolution of two related industries, paper presented at the DIME Conference on Innovation and Industrial Dynamics, Bocconi University, Milan, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., & Orsenigo, L. (2010). User–producer relations, innovation and the evolution of market structures under alternative contractual regimes. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 21(1), 26–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba, F., Orsenigo, L., & Peretto, P. (1997). Persistence of innovative activities, sectoral patterns of innovation and international technological specialization. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 15(6), 801–826.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, M., & Orsenigo, L. (2006). The economics of biotechnology (Vol. 198). Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1982). The role of knowledge in R&D efficiency. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93, 453–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD Publishing. (2009). The bioeconomy to 2030: Designing a policy agenda. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Orsenigo, L. (1989a). Institutions and markets in the dynamics of industrial innovation: The theory and the case of biotechnology. Thesis, .

    Google Scholar 

  • Orsenigo, L. (1989b). The emergence of biotechnology: Institutions and markets in industrial innovation. Pinter Publishers Ltd..

    Google Scholar 

  • Orsenigo, L. (2007). History-friendly models of industrial evolution. In H. Hanusch & A. Pyka (Eds.), Elgar companion to neo-schumpeterian economics. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orsenigo, L., Pammolli, F., & Riccaboni, M. (2001). Technological change and network dynamics: Lessons from the pharmaceutical industry. Research Policy, 30(3), 485–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orsenigo, L., Pammolli, F., Riccaboni, M., Bonaccorsi, A., & Turchetti, G. (1998). The evolution of knowledge and the dynamics of an industry network. Journal of Management & Governance, 1(2), 147–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosiello, A., & Orsenigo, L. (2008). A critical assessment of regional innovation policy in pharmaceutical biotechnology. European Planning Studies, 16(3), 337–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg, G., Dosi, G., & Orsenigo, L. (1988). Innovation, diversity and diffusion: A self-organisation model. The Economic Journal, 98(393), 1032–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tesfatsion, L. (2001). Introduction to the special issue on agent-based computational economics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 25(3–4), 281–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen, B. (2007). Mapping technological trajectories as patent citation networks: A study on the history of fuel cell research. Advances in Complex Systems, 10(01), 93–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter, S. G., Kaniovski, Y. M., & Dosi, G. (2000). Modeling industrial dynamics with innovative entrants. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 11(3), 255–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoon, M. (2009). A History-friendly model on the relationship between NISs and performances in frontier industries of Korea and Taiwan. In: 2009 Convention of the Korean Association of Technology Economics and Management.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoon, M., & Lee, K. (2009). Agent-based and “history-friendly” models for explaining industrial evolution. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 6(1), 45–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, P., Shi, J., Sadowsk, B., & Nomaler, Ö. (2020). Catching up in the face of technological discontinuity: Exploring the role of demand structure and technological regimes in the transition from 2G to 3G in China. Journal of Evolutionary Economics. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-020-00673-9

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Junguo Shi .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Shi, J., Sadowski, B.M. (2021). The Value of Industry Studies: Impact of Luigi Orsenigo’s Legacy on the Field of Innovation and Industry Evolution. In: Pyka, A., Lee, K. (eds) Innovation, Catch-up and Sustainable Development. Economic Complexity and Evolution. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-84931-3_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics