Skip to main content

Futures Markets (2): Contracts on Interest Rates

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Capital Market Finance

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 1316 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter provides an in-depth analysis of the two principal types of futures contracts on interest rates. The notional contracts on short-, medium-, or long-term securities presented in Sect. 15.1 are defined relative to an “abstract” reference (a “notional” security ) without physical existence and lead, at the seller’s will, to the delivery of one among different eligible physical securities similar to the notional security. The Short-Term Interest Rate contracts (STIRS), examined in Sect. 15.2, are referenced on a short-term underlying rate (3 months or less) although the contract maturity may be much longer, they are cash settled exclusively, and are based either on a forward-looking interest rate, usually a 3-month LIBOR, or on a backward-looking average of overnight rates.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This reference may be loose or even misleading: In the US, the maturities of the DS of the 30-year CME futures contract were restricted for some time to a range of 15–25 years! This contract is now called the classical T-bond, while the Ultra T-bond or new 30-year contract is settled with delivery of T-bonds whose maturity is longer than 25 years.

  2. 2.

    The value of the face rate k can be adjusted occasionally, but remains fixed for a given contract and this during its entire life. Remark, for example, that CME and EUREX has kept the face rate for notional bonds at 6% for several years, although the rates on the bond market are currently (2022) much below that figure.

  3. 3.

    A conversion factor is particular to each DS and also depends on the maturity of the contract. The notation fi is therefore short for the more precise notation fi,T .

  4. 4.

    If the seller were to select a different DS than m (which she obviously would never do) the gain would be even larger.

  5. 5.

    The multiplier 100 comes from the fact that the price Ci is quoted for a nominal amount of $100 while the conversion factor is calculated for an amount of 1.

  6. 6.

    Some futures on bonds (such as the Chicago T-bond contract) give sellers a delay for choosing the exact moment of delivery. This is called a timing option. The quality option and the timing option together make up the wild card option.

  7. 7.

    Recall that φθ = 100km for the coupon payments on dates (Tj = T + j\( {\tau}_m\Big){}_{j=1,\dots, {N}_m-1} \) and 100(1 + km) on the final date Tm = T + Nmτm.

  8. 8.

    The gap between the two rates may be due to differences in maturities, coupon rates, liquidity or credit risk.

  9. 9.

    See Chap. 9, Sect. 9.4.

  10. 10.

    The zero-coupon rates, or equivalently the conversion factors, are read from the rate curve constructed by ICE, computed daily using a standard algorithm (see Chap. 7) and displayed on Reuters.

  11. 11.

    A notable exception is Japanese contracts whose nominal is JPY100,000,000.

  12. 12.

    We do not distinguish in the following analysis the closing date T of transactions from the reference date for the final settlement price (often T+2 days). However, we make the distinction in the numerical example (7, item b).

  13. 13.

    See Chap. 2, Sect. 2.2.4 for the definition of a bank (or simple) discount rate, which is paid in advance, and its difference with a money market rate which is paid in arrears, even if set in advance.

  14. 14.

    This approximation is legitimate only for very low levels of short-term interest rates, as they currently (early 2021) are.

  15. 15.

    Between t and T+3 for a STIR on a backward-looking rate (overnight rate average), as explained in Sect. 15.2.2 below.

  16. 16.

    Or Monday.

  17. 17.

    The dates are fixed by the Monetary Policy Committee and announced by the Bank of England.

  18. 18.

    Alternatively, and more in line with standard definitions of sensitivity/duration, one can define the STIR sensitivity using the price Ψ (and not the nominal value): –d Ψ / Ψ dr = K/(1 – Kr), where Ψ is the fictitious quotation Ψ =100 – KR = 100 – 100Kr introduced above in Sect. 15.2.1.2. This entails a small difference with the simpler definition (which leads to – dF/100dr = K), but an appropriate use of each risk measure yields identical results.

  19. 19.

    This is because exp(KfT,K) = exp((T+K)rT+K)/exp(TrT) which implies KfT,K = (T+K) rT+KTrT.

  20. 20.

    We must use this fictitious price since the quoted “price” \( {F}_0^T \) is not a meaningful price, as argued in the text.

Suggestions for Further Reading

Books

  • Duffie, D. (1989). Futures markets. Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hull, J. (2018). Options, futures and other derivatives (10th ed.). Prentice Hall Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • * Lioui, A., & Poncet, P. (2005). Dynamic asset allocation with forwards and futures. Springer

    Google Scholar 

Articles

  • Adler, M., & Detemple, J. (1988). On the optimal hedge of a non-traded cash position. Journal of Finance, 43, 143–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, R., & Danthine, J. P. (1983). The time pattern of hedging and the volatility of futures prices. Review of Economic Studies, 50, 249–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breeden, D. (1984). Futures markets and commodity options hedging and optimality in incomplete markets. Journal of Economic Theory, 32, 275–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J., Ingersoll, J. E., & Ross, S. A. (1981). The relation between forward and futures prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 9, 321–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D., & Stanton, R. (1992). Pricing continuously resettled contingent claims. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16, 561–573.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. S. Y., & Lee, S. B. (1986). Term structure movements and pricing interest rate contingent claims. Journal of Finance, 41(5), 1011–1029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kane, A., & Marcus, A. (1986). Valuation and optimal exercise of the wild card option in the treasury bond futures market. Journal of Finance, 41(1), 195–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lioui, A., & Poncet, P. (1996). Optimal hedging in a dynamic futures market with a non-negativity constraint on wealth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 20, 1101–1113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lioui, A., & Poncet, P. (2000). The minimum variance hedge ratio under stochastic interest rates. Management Science, 46, 658–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schroder, M. (1999). Changes of numeraire for pricing futures, forwards, and options. Review of Financial Studies, 12, 1143–1163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siddique, A. (2003). Common asset pricing factors in volatilities and returns in futures markets. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27, 2347–2368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Internet Sites

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Patrice Poncet .

Appendices

Appendices

These appendices provide two improvements in the techniques for valuing futures contracts. The first concerns the option to change the delivered DS held by the seller of a notional contract. The second allows taking into account the margin call system.

1 Valuation of the Delivery Option

To obtain a closed formula for the delivery option included in a contract on a notional security, we make the following simplifying assumption which is justified by the uniformity of the basket of DS :

Assumption

The forward yield curve is flat for all DS . We denote by \( {R}_T^f(t) \) the unique forward rate prevailing on date t ≥ 0 for the maturity T.

Applying the result from Sect. 15.1.4.2, the two candidates for CTD on the expiration date T are the bond with the longest duration using the clean price (indexed by the letter l) and the bond with the shortest duration (indexed by the letter s). The choice of one or the other will depend on the actual bond yield on date T, denoted by R(T).

We showed in Sect. 15.1.4.1, that the futures price on date T is

$$ {F}_T=\min \left(\frac{C_l(T)}{f_l},\frac{C_s(T)}{f_s}\right). $$

Consider, for example, the case where the most probable CTD is the DS with longest duration l (i.e. \( {R}_T^f(t)>k \)). The value at the expiry of the futures contract can be decomposed into two parts, involving an option of exchange between the two bonds s and l:

$$ {F}_T=\frac{C_l(T)}{f_l}-\max \left(\frac{C_l(T)}{f_l}-\frac{C_s(T)}{f_s};0\right). $$
(15.33)

Written this way, it is clear that the exchange option, with payoff \( \max \left(\frac{C_l(T)}{f_l}-\frac{C_s(T)}{f_s};0\right) \), reduces the expiry price of the futures contract as computed in Sect. 15.1.4.1. This exchange option can be valued using Margrabe’s formula (see Chap. 11, Sect. 11.2.7).

Suppose, for example, that the annual standard deviation of the bond rate is 1%. If the option is in the money (\( {R}_T^f(t)=k \)), applying the formula gives a futures price of 99.80%, which can be seen as the theoretical price of the futures without the delivery option (100% of the nominal amount) reduced by the time value of the in-the-money option: 0.20%. This effect is mitigated (the delivery option value is low) when the market yield goes noticeably above or below k since then the likelihood of a change in CTD is very low.

2 Relationship Between Forward and Futures Prices

We examine here the impact of the margin call system on the futures price which, in particular, makes it different from the forward price.

  1. 1.

    We first recall two important results (see Appendix 1 to Chap. 9):

    1. (a)

      The futures price, in contrast to the forward price, is a martingale under the risk-neutral probability Q associated with the standard (riskless asset) numeraire \( {\beta}_t=\exp \left({\int}_0^tr(s) ds\right) \).

    2. (b)

      The price \( {F}_0^T \) on date 0 of the futures contract with underlying S equals the forward price \( {\varPhi}_0^T \) corrected by a covariance term (see Eq. (9.A-3) in Appendix 1 to Chap. 9):

$$ {F}_0^T={\varPhi}_0^T\exp \left[\operatorname{cov}\left({\int}_0^Tr(t) dt,\ln {S}_T\right)\right]. $$
(15.34)

The role of covariance is explained as follows: if there is a negative covariance between the short-term rate and the return on the underlying, then an increase in St (thus in \( {F}_t^T \)) goes along with a decrease in the short-term rate. For the buyer of the futures, the positive margin received is invested at a low interest rate. If, on the contrary, St (thus \( {F}_t^T \)) falls, the buyer must finance the negative margin at a higher interest rate. Therefore, the system of margin calls works against the buyer’s interests, implying a price of the futures smaller than that of the forward. Symmetrically, a positive covariance would play in favor of the buyer, implying a futures price higher than that of the forward. Since rates and prices are negatively correlated, the futures prices of financial assets are usually smaller than the corresponding forward prices (while futures rates are higher). Relation (15.34) is general and applies to contracts on both short-term and long-term securities.

  1. 2.

    Let us apply Eq. (15.34) to contracts on interest rates beginning with a contract on a short-term rate.

We start with the approximate result in Proposition 10 according to which the price of a short-term futures is equal to the forward price with expiration date T of a zero-coupon with maturity T + K (usually K = 0.25). This result does not take into account the impact of margin calls that affects futures. Noticing that the zero-coupon BT + K(t) of maturity T + K (duration K on date T) plays the role of St in result (b) above, we deduce the short-term (fictitious) futures price defined by Eq. (15.27) with K instead of 0.25Footnote 20:

The short-term (fictitious) futures price \( {\Psi}_0^T \) is linked to the short-term forward price \( {\Phi}_0^T \)by:

$$ {\Psi}_0^T={\Phi}_0^T\exp \left[-\operatorname{cov}\left({\int}_0^Tr(t) dt,K.{z}_K(T)\right)\right], $$
(15.35)

where zK(T) is the continuous zero-coupon spot rate of duration K prevailing on expiration date T.

Proof

Applying Eq. (15.34) in the case where ST = BT + K(T) gives

$$ {\Psi}_0^T=\kern1em {\varPhi}_0^T\exp \left(\operatorname{cov}\left({\int}_0^Tr(t) dt;\;\ln \Big({B}_{T+K}(T)\right)\right). $$

We obtain the desired result by using the fact that, by definition

$$ {B}_{T+K}(T)={e}^{-K.{Z}_K(T)}. $$

Again, note that the covariance in Eq. (15.35) is that of two processes strongly positively correlated. Indeed, the two terms depend on the evolution of short-term rates between 0 and T\( {\int}_0^Tr(s) ds \) depends on the evolution of the instantaneous rate over the period [0, T], and zK(T) is the rate of duration K that will prevail at T. Since this covariance is multiplied by (–1), the futures price is smaller than the corresponding forward price.

  1. 3.

    An analogous result holds for a contract on a long-term, notional rate and for a contract on a bond price.

Let \( {F}_0^{i,T} \) be the price on date 0 of a fictitious futures contract written on DS i and of maturity T. By applying Eq. (15.34), the futures and forward clean prices are related by

$$ {F}_0^{i,T}={\Phi}_0^{i,T}\exp \left(\operatorname{cov}\left({\int}_0^Tr(s) ds;\ln {C}_i(T)\right)\right), $$

where Ci is the clean spot price of DS i.

The relationship between the futures price of a notional contract and its forward price is obtained by applying the last equation to the CTD m.

More precise relations can be obtained by combining this last result with an interest-rate model such as those developed in Chap. 17. Using the notations of that chapter, we denote by F(t, T, TB) and Φ(t, T, TB), respectively, the price on date t of a T-futures contract and a T-forward contract written on a bond B(t,TB) with maturity TB > T. Using the one-factor Heath–Jarrow–Morton model (Chap. 17, Sect. 17.2.1.4), according to which the instantaneous volatility of the instantaneous forward rate is the constant σ, we derive an explicit formula for the relationship between F(t, T, TB) and Φ(t, T, TB) (Eq. 17.24 in Chap. 17):

$$ F\left(t,T,{T}_B\right)=\varPhi \left(t,T,{T}_B\right)\exp \left[-\frac{\sigma^2}{2}\left({T}_B-T\right){\left(T-t\right)}^2\right], $$
(15.36)

which is Eq. (15.12) in the text providing the convexity adjustment between the futures and forward clean prices of a zero-coupon bond due to margin calls .

  1. 4.

    Using the same one-factor Heath–Jarrow–Morton model, which is equivalent to the Ho and Lee (1986) model, we can derive a closed-form relation for the convexity adjustment relevant to contracts on short-term rates (note that, by contrast, Eq. (15.35) is general and relative to prices).

Assuming that the instantaneous spot interest rate obeys:

$$ dr=\theta (t) dt+\sigma dW(t), $$
(15.37)

where W(t) is a Wiener process, the price P(t,T) of the T-maturity zero-coupon bond is, in the risk-neutral world, equal to:

$$ P\left(t,T\right)=A\left(t,T\right){e}^{-r\left(T-t\right)}, $$
(15.38)

where A(t, T) is a deterministic function of time.

Define the current (continuously compounded) forward rate f(t, T1,T2) for lending/borrowing between T1 and T2 as:

$$ f\left(t,{T}_1,{T}_2\right)=\frac{LnP\left(t,{T}_1\right)- LnP\left(t,{T}_2\right)}{T_2-{T}_1}. $$

Note that in the main text relative to STIR contracts, T1 is denoted by T and T2 by T+K.

Applying Ito’s lemma to f(t, T1,T2) using Eqs. (15.37) and (15.38) yields:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l} df\left(t,{T}_1,{T}_2\right)=\frac{1}{T_2-{T}_1}\left[\left({T}_2-{T}_1\right)\sigma dW+\frac{1}{2}{\sigma}^2\left[{\left({T}_2-t\right)}^2-{\left({T}_1-t\right)}^2\right] dt\right]\\ {}\kern6em =\sigma dW+\frac{{\left({T}_2-t\right)}^2-{\left({T}_1-t\right)}^2}{2\left({T}_2-{T}_1\right)}{\sigma}^2 dt\end{array}} $$
(15.39)

The risk-neutral conditional expectation of df(.) is the second, deterministic, term on the r.h.s. of Eq. (15.39). By integrating this term between 0 and T1, we obtain the risk-neutral expected change in the forward rate between the current date (0) and date T1:

$$ {E}_t\left[f\left({T}_1\right)-f(t)\right]=\int_0^{T_1}\frac{{\left({T}_2-t\right)}^2-{\left({T}_1-t\right)}^2}{2\left({T}_2-{T}_1\right)}{\sigma}^2 dt=\frac{1}{2}{\sigma}^2{T}_1{T}_2. $$

Now, we know that under the risk-neutral probability, the futures rate is a martingale (see the Appendix to Chap. 9) so that the conditional expectation of its change between any two dates is 0. Therefore, the convexity adjustment between the forward and futures rates is conform to that given in Eq. (15.28) in the main text, i.e., 0.5σ2T1T2.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Poncet, P., Portait, R. (2022). Futures Markets (2): Contracts on Interest Rates. In: Capital Market Finance. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-84600-8_15

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics