GHG Emissions in Mexico and Covered Entities
Figure 12.1 shows average emissions by industry using data from RETC. Electricity generation produces the largest CO2 emissions, followed by cement and oil producers. In the case of NO2, the largest emissions come from electricity generation. Figure 12.2 Panel (a) shows the location of the 2018 RETC facilities by the marginalization level of the locality/AGEB that contains it. As an example of the spatial distribution of firms, Fig. 12.2 Panel (b) shows their location in Greater Mexico City.
While RETC facilities are located across the country, some areas have a higher point density, like the central region of the country—Greater Mexico City and the Bajío region—as well as some industrial areas along or near the northern border. No clear pattern of marginalization emerges although it appears that facilities with higher marginalization levels are concentrated in centre-to-south Mexico. In the case of Greater Mexico City, Panel (b) shows that there can be a juxtaposition of different marginalization levels in facilities close by, although a larger trend can be observed in which better-off AGEBs are located within the centre of Mexico City, and some other facilities are concentrated in peripheral areas with higher levels of marginalization.
Mexico’s ETS is planned to cover over 40\(\%\) of total GHG emissions in the country and inclusion in the program depends on whether CO2 emissions crossed the 100,000 tons threshold in any of the years of the 2016–2019 period. To analyse possible gains on GHG reductions due to the ETS, we considered the regulation threshold for the ETS. In Fig. 12.3, Panels a) and b) show the proportion of CO2 and NO2 emissions covered by the ETS as a function of the threshold above which facilities are automatically enrolled in the program. To calculate the coverage, we computed the annual average for the period 2016–2018 considering facilities above the CO2 emissions regulation threshold. This number was then divided by the yearly average total emissions in our dataset—either CO2 or NO2—for the same period. Panel c) shows the number of facilities that participate in the emissions trading system, also as a function of the threshold. The coverage for CO2 is close to 90\(\%\) and above 40\(\%\) of NO2. In contrast, facilities vary more with the threshold level, showing that regulating 287 facilities (under the current threshold in our dataset) compared to 305 under a more stringent cap may have monitoring and implementation costs and not as much gains in environmental coverage.
Characterization of GHG Emissions and Environmental Justice
Figure 12.4 shows average pollution emissions by marginalization level for the three largest CO2 emitting sectors for both rural and urban areas. This figure shows that on average, electricity generators with the highest emission levels are located in urban areas with “very high” marginalization levels. However, rural areas with “high” marginalization levels also face high levels of emissions coming from electricity generation. In the case of cement production, both urban and rural communities with “high” marginalization levels have facilities that release the highest levels of CO2 emissions.
Table 12.1 shows the descriptive statistics of facilities regulated by the ETS. As expected, regulated facilities show higher CO2 emissions as well as other pollutants emissions. Furthermore, regulated facilities are in neighbourhoods with higher levels of marginalization than non-regulated facilities.
Table 12.1 Facilities’ descriptive statistics In order to further explore these differences, we use a two-way fixed effect regression where we account for year and municipality fixed effects in order to control for emissions driven by year-to-year fluctuations and municipality characteristics. Equation (12.1) shows our empirical specification.
$${Y}_{it}=\mathrm{\alpha }+\sum\limits_{i=1}^{5}{\upbeta }_{i}1\{Marginalization Leve{l}_{i}\}+{X}_{i}+{\upgamma }_{t}+{\upmu }_{m}+{\upepsilon }_{it}$$
(12.1)
where \({Y}_{it}\) is CO2 emissions at locality/AGEB \(i\) in year \(t\) during the period 2016–2018. \(1\{MarginalizationLeve{l}_{i}\}\) are indicator variables that equal one for each marginalization level. \({\gamma }_{t}\) are year fixed effects, \({\mu }_{m}\) are municipality fixed effects, and \({X}_{i}\) is an indicator of whether the AGEB is rural or urban. \({\upepsilon }_{it}\) is the standard error clustered at the rural locality/AGEB level. Each specific \({\upbeta }_{i}\) shows the marginal difference in emissions compared to a base category, which in our case will be the “very low” marginalization level. Estimating this regression allows us to control for municipality-specific time-invariant effects during the 2016–2018 period. Examples of these variables are municipality-specific environmental programs, infrastructure, or municipality government characteristics, among others. Adding year-specific effects allows us to control for emission changes affecting all localities that are specific to one year. For example, a drop in emissions due to slower economic conditions during a specific year.
Panel (a) of Fig. 12.5 shows the coefficients estimated from Eq. (12.1) along with their confidence intervals for CO2, NO2, lead, and cadmium emissions. These results imply that AGEBs/rural localities with “high” marginalization levels are on average exposed to 7,600 additional tons of CO2 from the facilities located nearby compared to communities with “very low” marginalization levels. To the extent that these CO2 emissions are produced with co-pollutants, communities with “high” marginalization levels could be exposed to higher local pollution emissions than communities with “low” marginalization levels. This implies that an emissions trading program that targets facilities with high CO2 emissions could potentially benefit communities with “high” marginalization levels, conditional on existing co-benefits between CO2 emissions reductions and other local pollutants. As an illustrative comparison, we estimated Eq. (12.1) using other pollutants (NO2) and toxic emissions (Cadmium and Lead) in subpanels (b)–(d) of Fig. 12.5. Compared to the results for CO2, we cannot conclude that the emissions are significantly different across different income groups. However, this does not conclusively prove that there is no detectable difference in emissions by marginalization group, as we may simply lack the precision to estimate it. Future work could look at other pollution data such as air quality monitoring data near these facilities in order to further characterize this relationship. Panel (b) of Fig. 12.5 shows the corresponding coefficients for Fig. 12.5 where the “very low” marginalization level is the base category.
Simulation of Mexico’s ETS and Environmental Justice
The Mexican emissions trading program has the potential to create co-benefits in air quality improvements while reducing CO2 through cap and trade. As explained before, this will be determined by the correlation between CO2 emissions and co-pollutants. In order to explore the potential improvements in air quality as a result of the emissions trading program, we simulate an emissions-reduction scenario, by means of decreasing CO2 and NO2 emissions by 5\(\%\) in the first year of the program with respect to the 2016–2018 average for regulated facilities. This is consistent with the Mexican emissions reduction target for the industrial sector, as indicated in the General Law of Climate Change.Footnote 10 It should be noted that other feasible scenarios include non-uniform reductions within sectors, which also would be consistent with the Mexican emissions reduction target. This is the case for the electricity sector: it typically has a lower abatement cost than other sectors such as cement production and oil refining (Friedmann et al. 2019; INECC 2018).Footnote 11 We could expect that installations in this sector become net sellers of emissions allowances, thereby reducing emissions and associated co-pollutants locally. Our scenario is, therefore, a lower bound for the spatial and equity consequences of emissions reductions due to the Mexican ETS.
For the 5\(\%\) uniform decrease scenario, we predict the average emissions in the first year of the pilot program (2020) using the 2016–2018 data and estimating a two-way fixed effect regression given in Eq. (12.2) in order to obtain the average predicted emissions in the period after 2016–2018.
$${Y}_{it}={\mathrm{\alpha }}_{0}+{m}_{s}+{r}_{t}+{u}_{it}$$
(12.2)
where the dependent variable is either the tons of CO2 and NO2 emissions with sector (\({m}_{s}\)) and year (\({r}_{t}\)) fixed effects. We obtained the predicted values of CO2 and NO2 and simulated a 5\(\%\) decrease scenario with respect to the average emissions of CO2. Using these predicted emission reductions, we followed a similar approach to Eq. (12.1) and obtained the percent difference in emissions compared to the “very low” base category.Footnote 12
Panel a) of Fig. 12.6 shows the findings of our simulation. Panel a) shows the results for CO2 and panel b shows the results for NO2. In the case of CO2, we find that a 5\(\%\) decrease in emissions results in the previous differences across marginalization levels disappearing. Whereas baseline emissions indicate that “high” marginalization areas had on average more emissions than “very low” ones, and this reduction scenario levels the situation by making differences indiscernible. In the case of NO2, we find that there are differences in the predicted emissions across marginalization levels. Compared to the “very low” base category, communities with “medium” marginalization levels are expected to have higher NO2 emissions with a 5\(\%\) decrease in CO2 emissions. However, in the case of NO2, communities under the “high” marginalization level do not have higher predicted emissions compared to the “very low” marginalization communities. Therefore, we find a decrease in the exposure of NO2 pollution for the most vulnerable areas but increases to other communities in the “medium” and “high” marginalization levels. However, for the “high” marginalization communities, the increase is not significant. Panel b) of Fig. 12.6 shows the coefficient results associated with Panel a) where “very low” is the base category.
There are potential limitations to our methods. For instance, we do not consider the fate and transport of pollution in the environment, which could potentially change the conclusions of our NO2 analysis. Furthermore, we assumed that technology remains constant, which means that facilities do not invest in other technologies that change the relationship in emissions releases from CO2 and NO2. Finally, given data limitations, we do not include information about other potential pollutants such as SO2 or potential secondary formation of pollutants that create emissions of PM2.5. These are two valid concerns that we plan to explore further as the pilot program ends its first compliance cycle and as new emissions data are released.