Skip to main content

The Scope of the State as a Function of Transaction Costs: How Will Digitization Change the Role of Public Law?

An Analytical Framework Beyond Technological Determinism and the Longing for Politics Unconfined by Technological Context

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Democracy and Globalization

Part of the book series: Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship ((EALELS,volume 10))

Abstract

The analytical framework outlined in this chapter assumes that the character and the scope of states are partly determined by the technological environment in which they exist. If the invention of gunpowder, railways and internal combustion engines have led to fundamental transformations of the way communities are organized, then it would be outlandish to assume that digitization will leave the nation-state within which it unfolds essentially unchanged. Thus, our analytical framework attempts to assess the impact of digitization on public law (and therewith on the nature of the state) by developing an understanding of the state as a means to a transaction cost problem. According to this understanding, the state is a cluster of institutions whose continued existence could not be explained if there were no transaction costs. Digitization, according to this approach, is a driver for structural changes in transaction costs. The strength of this approach lies in its ability to encompass all fields of regulation and all technologies, which are summarised under the collective term “digitization”, in a coherent analysis. The insights of this approach will also be transferable to the jurisprudential and policy-oriented impact assessment of new and unknown technologies and their applications.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Radbruch (1980), emphasis added. Our translation.

  2. 2.

    See, for example, Senn (2015), pp. 471, 477; Gasser and Drolshammer (2015), p. 83, esp. 87. See also the various contributions on the topic in the thematic issue of the Columbia Law Review 7/119 (2019).

  3. 3.

    For the context of international law, concerning the Tallinn Manual, see Langer (2019), pp. 3, 10; Braun Binder (2019), p. 467.

  4. 4.

    Boehme-Neßler (2009), pp. 145, 148. The fact that digitization has a ubiquitous and limitless effect does not, however, exclude the possibility of strongly differing effects. There is a strong possibility of a “digital divide”.

  5. 5.

    Yermack (2017), p. 28; Desai (2014), pp. 1469, 1476. See also Boehme-Neßler (2009), p. 147.

  6. 6.

    Cf. Wükert et al. (2017), pp. 1, 11. As the research project “Transformation of the State” of the German Research Institute for Public Administration, puts it: “The state as a social system of order and as an institutional order will (further) transform itself in its outer and inner form in the course of advancing digitalization and undergo an assimilation to the digitized life and experience of its citizens and of the subparts of its society”: Martini (2016), p. 26. Our translation. See also De Filippi (2018), pp. 267, 276.

  7. 7.

    Cf. Gasser and Drolshammer (2015), p. 98, which emphasizes how digital transformation depends on its institutional environment. Our chapter deals with the reverse relationship, the question of how the character of (public) institutions depends on their technological environment. See also Cavelti and Jaag (2019), p. 66.

  8. 8.

    See Wükert et al. (2017), p. 14.

  9. 9.

    Yuval Harari, for instance, predicts that “(…) it is likely in the next 200 years or so homo sapiens will upgrade themselves [sic] into some idea of a divine being, either through biological manipulation or genetic engineering by the creation of cyborgs, part organic, part non-organic” Knapton (2015). The relationship of such speculations to the analytical grid of transaction costs is not immediately clear. However, Adam, the man-machine in Ian McEwan’s “Machines like me”, predicts that the fusion of men and machine will bring us into the vicinity of a transaction cost-free world: “[W]hen (…) a brain-machine interface is efficient and cheap, you’ll become a partner with your machines in the open-ended expansion of intelligence, and of consciousness generally. Colossal intelligence, instant access to deep moral acumen and to everything known, but more importantly access to each other. It could be the end of mental privacy. You’ll probably come to value it less in the face of the enormous gains. (…) We’ll inhabit a community of minds to which we have immediate access. Connectivity will be such that individual nodes of the subjective will merge into an ocean of thought, of which our Internet is the crude precursor. As we come to inhabit each other’s minds, we’ll be incapable of deceit” (McEwan 2019, p. 148f).

  10. 10.

    See also Weber (2019), p. 19f.

  11. 11.

    Oliver E. Williamson provides a helpful and somewhat more detailed analytical grid in this context by identifying four superimposed layers of institutions: the highest layer forms the socio-cultural context (informal institutions, religion, customs, etc.) which remains relevant for centuries; the second is constituted by the institutional environment, the “rules of the game” (i.e. primarily public institutions) which remain stable for decades; the third is the “play of the game” (i.e., in particular, the question of how corporate structures and contractual relationships are designed) and the fourth the everyday decisions on resource allocation. Our point is that the literature on digitization and law to date has focused too much on the third and fourth levels, and too little on the rules of the game and the socio-cultural context in which they are embedded, both of which may also come under strong pressure to change as a result of digitization. Williamson also mentions that above these levels lies a higher level, level 0, which is an evolutionary level where the structure of the human mind or consciousness is formed—again over a much longer period than on level 1 (Williamson 2000, pp. 596–600).

  12. 12.

    For an example of the discussion on this third level, concerning the legal issues in connection with the use of artificial intelligence in decisions in public administration, see Braun Binder (2019). However, the question of the extent to which the external form, the processes of everyday legal life will shape the content of substantive law is a complex question that lies at the interface between the second and third levels of analysis. See Gasser and Drolshammer (2015), p. 92; see also Fries (2018), p. 414, and especially 429.

  13. 13.

    Boehme-Neßler (2009), p. 147.

  14. 14.

    A very good discussion of the various conceivable meanings and the origin of the term can be found in Wükert et al. (2017).

  15. 15.

    Cf. Weber (2019), p. 20f.

  16. 16.

    Coase (1937), p. 386.

  17. 17.

    Coase (1960), pp. 1, 17. The question to what extent states are free from competition among each other should be discussed a new in a time of seamless mobility of people and factors of production as compared to the time in which Coase penned this remark.

  18. 18.

    See also Calabresi (2016), p. 96; Barzel (2012), p. 3.

  19. 19.

    This terminology is introduced by Calabresi (2016), especially pp. 24ff.

  20. 20.

    Desai (2014), p. 1482.

  21. 21.

    See Richter and Furubotn (2010), p. 70.

  22. 22.

    As will be explained below, the approach used here assumes that transaction costs are the reason why there are hierarchically integrated institutions such as firms and states. However, the normative requirement that transaction costs be reduced to such an extent that states become obsolete does not follow from this analytical approach.

  23. 23.

    Explaining the emergence and scope of the field of government activity based on transaction costs also helps to understand the separation between public law and private law as a gradual, not a systemic, separation (to admit this gradual nature is a prerequisite for an analytical framework on digitization of public law). Both private and administrative law, are entrusted with the allocation of goods—for example with the allocation of silence or cleanliness. We call the property rights to protect these goods a prerogative (or a regalian right, to use Piketty’s terminology [see: Piketty 2020, p. 45]) when public law deals with them. When private law, we call them (neighbourhood) rights of defence against nuisance. The instruments used by the two fields of law vary, but the function is the same: to reduce transaction costs to such an extent that social costs can be internalized as far as possible. Similarly, their respective functions cannot be understood without their continuity and complementarity being seen in the other field of law. Expressed in the language of interest theory, law is considered to be private law for as long as the protection of the interests of a group of private individuals is concerned. Where that group of private individuals with the same interest has become so large (or where the interest to be pursued is so widely dispersed) that it can be assumed that the interest in question is actually the public interest, legal rules are considered public law. Changes of the technological context are an important indication of how the boundary between private and public law has shifted in the past and could shift in the future.

  24. 24.

    Some authors insist on the difference between legal and economic property rights. Accordingly, legal property rights are those possibilities of action that are enforced by the legal system. Economic property rights are those that can actually be enforced or exercised. The terms are therefore not congruent. A world in which the legal system would lose its task because there would no longer be any transaction costs, however, also entails the assumption that legal property rights have become completely congruent with economic property rights. See Allen (2015), pp. 379, 387.

  25. 25.

    Hesse (1983), p. 80. Our translation.

  26. 26.

    Schäfer and Ott (2012), p. 72; Calabresi and Melamed (1972), pp. 1089, 1092.

  27. 27.

    Coase (1988), pp. 655, 656.

  28. 28.

    Mathis (2019), p. 88.

  29. 29.

    Richter and Furubotn (2010), p. 80.

  30. 30.

    Richter and Furubotn (2010), p. 82; see also Calabresi and Melamed (1972), p. 1095.

  31. 31.

    Oreskovic (2020).

  32. 32.

    Samaras et al. (2020).

  33. 33.

    Hao (2020).

  34. 34.

    Posner (2011), pp. 638–641.

  35. 35.

    Barzel (2012), pp. 19–20.

  36. 36.

    Coase used the term “marketing costs” before the more general concept of transaction costs was at hand. Coase (1937), p. 392.

  37. 37.

    For the most comprehensive possible definition of transaction costs, see Allen (2015).

  38. 38.

    One of the reasons for this is that there is no theory for discerning transaction costs and factor costs. See Schlag (2013), pp. 175, 219.

  39. 39.

    Allen (2015), p. 380, Fn. 4; Mathis (2019), p. 86.

  40. 40.

    Allen (2015), p. 380, Fn. 4.

  41. 41.

    Schlegel (2017), p. 58; Mathis (2019), p. 81; Cooter and Ulen (2014), p. 89.

  42. 42.

    Barzel (2012), p. 3, distinguishes a state theory based on the Coase Theorem from normative state theories and describes “operationality” as the former’s objective.

  43. 43.

    Langer (2019), p. 9.

  44. 44.

    Barzel (2012), p. 18.

  45. 45.

    Platforms are online applications for the purchase or exchange of services such as car lifts, food delivery, online trade and tourism.

  46. 46.

    Guggenberg (2017), p. 2577.

  47. 47.

    Statista Digital Market Outlook, Individuals who use Facebook via any device at least once per month (for services such as car lifts, food delivery, online trade and tourism) https://www.statista.com/statistics/568790/forecast-of-facebook-user-numbers-in-germany/ (accessed on July 4th, 2020).

  48. 48.

    Gasser and Drolshammer (2015), p. 86.

  49. 49.

    According to Guggenberger, the NetzDG violates higher-ranking law by, for example, unduly restricting the communication rights of citizens of the Federal Republic of Germany (Art. 5 I and II GG) without the obvious necessity of the measure. See Guggenberg (2017), p. 2581.

  50. 50.

    “In the Chinese context, the state will run the show and own it, not as a market project but as a political one, a machine solution that shapes a new society of automated behavior for guaranteed political and social outcomes: certainty without terror.”: Zuboff (2019a), p. 225.

  51. 51.

    “Surveillance capitalism diverged from many norms and practices that define the history of capitalism, especially the history of market democracy.” Zuboff (2019b). Accessed 23.10.2020.

  52. 52.

    The term “Smart Contract” describes digital programs that, based on a blockchain architecture, execute themselves when certain conditions occur and which, due to the decentralized and cryptographic design of the blockchain, are almost self-assertive and tamper-proof. Thus, they can execute legal obligations, such as payment obligations, on their own if the aforementioned conditions are met, which leads to a high level of security and low transaction costs. For these payments to trigger a change in the legal world (and not just within the programme), they require an underlying will of the parties to be bound by a contract. The will to be legally bound involves the (more or less) voluntary submission of a private relationship to the legal system of a state, including its contract law under private law and its civil procedural law under public law. The contract is embedded in the assumption that the parties wish to be legally bound and that, in the event of non-performance or defective performance, the other party may require performance and/or compensation awarded and, following a court ruling, leave the enforcement of the contract to the state with the full force of state authority.

  53. 53.

    Nozick (2013), p. ix.

  54. 54.

    Szabo (2019): according to Szabo, the difference between technological institutions (such as blockchains) and institutions such as the rule of law is primarily social scalability.

  55. 55.

    Cf Boehme-Neßler (2009), p. 189.

  56. 56.

    Whereas Meyer and Schuppli argue that the intent to legally bind oneself and thus the existence of a binding contract is called into question by idealized smart contracts (Meyer and Schuppli 2017, pp. 204, 208), Frankenreiter claims that the likelyhood of such a development is low (Frankenreiter 2019, pp. 149, 154). However, due to their inherent determinism, smart contracts can hardly reflect the dynamic nature of contracts: what was initially a contract based on mutually agreed declarations of intent can change over time, e.g. exceptions to the principle of pacta sunt servanda, such as the legal figure clausula rebus sic stantibus, may nullify formerly valid contracts for contracting parties ex tunc. Thus, smart contracts cannot cover the entirety of the existing and future contract components at the time of the conclusion of the contract. In this light, smart contracts appear as a promising means to reduce transaction costs, but not as an alternative to the contract enforcement regime based on states and courts.

  57. 57.

    Schumpeter (2005).

  58. 58.

    It is more useful to think of the relation of markets to states as a spectrum, rather than as a dychotomy: Ostrom (2010), p. 2.

  59. 59.

    Regarding this analogy, see Desai (2014).

  60. 60.

    See Weber (2019), p. 4; Bauböck (2018), p. 261.

  61. 61.

    See also Häberle (1984), p. 43. Another essential reading is North (2005), p. 41.

  62. 62.

    See Silver (2012), p. 2.

  63. 63.

    Khan (2017), p. 780.

  64. 64.

    See North (2005), pp. 50–51.

  65. 65.

    North (2005), p. 47; Desai (2014), p. 1477; Wallis and North (2007), pp. 95, 122f.

  66. 66.

    Desai (2014), p. 1468.

  67. 67.

    See Senn (2007), p. 2.

References

  • Allen DW (2015) The Coase theorem: coherent, logical, and not disproved. J Inst Econ 11(02):379–390. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137414000083

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barzel Y (2012) A theory of the state: economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Political economy of institutions and decisions, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bauböck R (ed) (2018) Debating transformations of national citizenship. IMISCOE Research Series. Springer International Publishing, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-92719-0

  • Boehme-Neßler V (2009) Das Ende des Staates? Zu den Auswirkungen der Digitalisierung auf den Staat. Zeitschrift für öffentliches Recht 64(2):145–199. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00708-009-0024-8

  • Braun Binder N (2019) Künstliche Intelligenz und automatisierte Entscheidungen in der öffentlichen Verwaltung. Schweizerische Juristenzeitung 115:467–476

    Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi G (2016) The future of law and economics: essays in reform and recollection. Yale University Press, New Haven, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi G, Melamed DA (1972) Property rules, liability rules, and inalienability: one view of the cathedral. Harv Law Rev 85(6):1089–1128. https://doi.org/10.2307/1340059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavelti L, Jaag C (2019) Die Bedeutung der Digitalisierung für das internationale Unternehmenssteuerrecht. Zeitschrift für Europarecht 21(3):66–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4(6):386–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1960) The problem of social cost. J Law Econ 3:1–44. https://doi.org/10.1086/466560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1988) The 1987 McCorkle Lecture: Blackmail. Va Law Rev 74(4):655–676

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooter R, Ulen T (2014) Law & economics. The Addison-Wesley series in economics, 6th edn. Pearson/Addison Wesley, Edinburgh Gate

    Google Scholar 

  • De Filippi P (2018) Citizenship in the era of blockchain-based virtual nations. In: Bauböck (ed) Debating transformations of national citizenship, pp 267–277

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai DR (2014) The new steam: on digitization, decentralization, and disruption. Hastings Law Rev:1469–1482

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankenreiter J (2019) The limits of smart contracts. J Inst Theor Econ JITE:149–162. https://doi.org/10.1628/jite-2019-0021

  • Fries M (2018) Automatische Rechtspflege. Rechtswissenschaft 4:414–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gasser U, Drolshammer J (2015) The Brave New World of (Swiss) Law. In: Gschwend et al (ed) Recht im digitalen Zeitalter, pp 83–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Guggenberg N (2017) Das Netzwerkdurchsetzungsgesetz in der Anwendung. Neue Juristische Wochenzeitschrift 36:2577–2582

    Google Scholar 

  • Häberle P (1984) Vielfalt der Property Rights und der verfassungsrechtliche Eigentumsbegriff. Archiv des öffentlichen Rechts (AöR) 109:36–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Hao K. How Facebook and Google are helping the CDC Forecast Coronavirus. Accessed 24 July 2020. https://www.technologyreview.com/2020/04/09/998924/facebook-and-google-share-data-to-forecast-coronavirus/

  • Hesse G (1983) Zur Erklärung der Änderung von Handlungsrechten mit Hilfe ökonomischer Theorie. In: Schüller A, Meyer W (eds) Property rights und ökonomische Theorie. WiSt-Taschenbücher. Vahlen, München, pp 79–109

    Google Scholar 

  • Khan LM (2017) Amazon’s antitrust paradox. Yale Law J 126:710–805

    Google Scholar 

  • Knapton S (2015) Humans ‘Will Become God-Like Cyborgs Within 200 Years’. The Telegraph, May 25, 2015. Accessed 18 Sep 2019. https://www.telegraph.co.uk/culture/hay-festival/11627386/Humans-will-become-God-like-cyborgs-within-200-years.html

  • Langer L (2019) “Cyberspace does not lie within your Borders” - Jurisdiktion und Menschenrechte im digitalen Raum. Swiss Rev Int Eur Law (SRIEL) 29:3–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Martini M (2016) Digitalisierung als Herausforderung und Chance für den Staat. FÖV Discussion Papers, Paper no. 85. Speyer. Accessed 24 July 2020. https://dopus.uni-speyer.de/frontdoor/deliver/index/docId/1462/file/DP-085.pdf

  • Mathis K (2019) Effizienz statt Gerechtigkeit? Auf der Suche nach den philosophischen Grundlagen der Ökonomischen Analyse des Rechts. 4. Aufl. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • McEwan I (2019) Machines like me: and people like you. Penguin Random House, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer S, Schuppli B (2017) “«Smart Contracts» und deren Einordnung in das Schweizerische Vertragsrecht.” recht. Zeitschrift für juristische Ausbildung und Praxis 3:204–224

    Google Scholar 

  • North D (2005) Capitalism and economic growth. In: Nee V, Swedberg R (eds) The economic sociology of capitalism. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, pp 41–52

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Nozick R (2013) Anarchy, State, and Utopia. Orig. paperback ed. Basic Books, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Oreskovic A. Google once predicted the Flu, now it’s one of many tech giants the Coronavirus has caught off guard. Accessed 24 July 2020. https://www.businessinsider.com/trending-google-once-predicted-flu-now-adapting-to-coronavirus-2020-3?r=US&IR=T

  • Ostrom E (2010) Beyond markets and states: polycentric governance of complex economic systems. Am Law Econ Rev 100:1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty T (2020) Capital and ideology. Belknap Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner RA (2011) Economic analysis of law, 8th edn. Aspen Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Radbruch G (1980) Einführung in die Rechtswissenschaft. 13. Auflage. K. F. Koehler Verlag, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Richter R, Furubotn EG (2010) Neue Institutionenökonomik: eine Einführung und kritische Würdigung, 4th edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Samaras L, García-Barriocanal E, Sicilia M-A (2020) Comparing Social Media and Google to detect and predict severe epidemics. Sci Rep 10(1):4747. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-020-61686-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schäfer H-B, Ott C (2012) Lehrbuch der Ökonomischen Analyse des Zivilrechts, 5th edn. Springer Berlin Heidelberg; Imprint: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlag P (2013) Coase minus the Coase theorem. Iowa Law Rev 99:175–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlegel S (2017) Der Entscheid über Migration als Verfügungsrecht: Eine Anwendung der Ökonomischen Analyse des Rechts auf das Migrationsrecht am Beispiel der Schweiz. 1. Auflage. Studien und Beiträge zum Öffentlichen Recht. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA, (2005) Kapitalismus, Sozialismus und Demokratie. 8., unveränderte Auflage. UTB für Wissenschaft Uni-Taschenbücher Politische Wissenschaft, Soziologie 172. A. Francke Verlag, Tübingen und Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Senn M (2007) Rechtsgeschichte - ein kulturhistorischer Grundriss: Mit Bildern, Schemen, Register, Biographien und Chronologie. 4. Aufl; Schulthess, Zürich

    Google Scholar 

  • Senn M (2015) Digitales Recht zwischen privatem und staatlichem Recht. In: Gschwend et al (eds) Recht im digitalen Zeitalter, pp 471–481

    Google Scholar 

  • Silver N (2012) The signal and the noise: the art and science of prediction. Always learning. Allen Lane Penguin Books, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Szabo N. Money, blockchains, and social scalability. Accessed 2 July 2019. http://unenumerated.blogspot.com/2017/02/money-blockchains-and-social-scalability.html

  • Wallis JJ, North D (2007) Measuring the transaction sector in the American economy, 1870–1970. In: Engerman SL, Gallman RE (eds) Long-term factors in American economic growth. NBER-Studies in Income and Wealth, vol 51. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 95–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber RH (2019) Digitalisierung und der Kampf ums Recht. In: Molin AD, Schneuwly AM, Stojanovic J (eds) APARIUZ XX, Digitalisierung - Gesellschaft - Recht, 3–26. Analysen und Perspektiven von Assistierenden des RWI (APARIUZ) 20. Dike Verlag, Zürich

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (2000) The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. J Econ Lit 38(3):595–613

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wükert F, Klafki A, Winter T (2017) Digitalisierung und Öffentliches Recht. In: Klafki A, Würkert F, Winter T (eds) Digitalisierung und Recht: Tagung des eingetragenen Vereins Junge Wissenschaft im öffentlichen Recht an der Bucerius Law School am 26. November 2016. 1. Auflage, 1–36. Schriften der Bucerius Law School II Band 31. Bucerius Law School Press; tredition GmbH, Hamburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Yermack D (2017) Corporate governance and blockchains. Rev Finance:7–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuboff S (2019a) The age of surveillance capitalism: the fight for a human future at the new frontier of power, 1st edn. Public Affairs, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuboff S (2019b) Facebook, Google and a dark age of surveillance capitalism. Financial Times. https://www.ft.com/content/7fafec06-1ea2-11e9-b126-46fc3ad87c65

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefan Schlegel .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Schlegel, S., Schuppli, B. (2021). The Scope of the State as a Function of Transaction Costs: How Will Digitization Change the Role of Public Law?. In: Sieber-Gasser, C., Ghibellini, A. (eds) Democracy and Globalization. Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship, vol 10. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-69154-7_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-69154-7_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-69153-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-69154-7

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics