Skip to main content

Burying Samuelson’s Multiplier-Accelerator and Resurrecting Goodwin’s Growth Cycle in Minsky

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Feedback Economics

Part of the book series: Contemporary Systems Thinking ((CST))

  • 1266 Accesses

Abstract

Samuelson’s Multiplier-Accelerator model is based on the economic mistake of adding together desired investment and actual savings to derive aggregate expenditure, when it is the sum of actual investment and actual savings. Its fluctuations are not a model of the business cycle, but convergence to or divergence from the trivial solution. Goodwin’s relatively neglected growth cycle model is shown to be a valid foundation for modelling the business cycle and is derived directly from macroeconomic definitions. When the private debt ratio is added to those definitions, Minsky’s “Financial Instability Hypothesis” results. I illustrate modelling of this hypothesis in the open-source system dynamics program named after Minsky, which has been designed predominantly to enable monetary dynamics to be modelled. I use Minsky’s unique feature of Godley Tables to show the macroeconomic difference between the false Loanable Funds model of banking and the realistic “bank originated money and debt” model. I show that a third-order difference equation growth cycle model can be derived from the concept of an investment accelerator. I close with an Appendix showing the use of Godley Tables in epidemic modelling.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Sargent was one of the founders of the “rational expectations” (Sargent and Wallace, 1976) and “real business cycle” approach to macroeconomics (Lucas and Sargent, 1978), which describes all fluctuations in output—including the Great Depression (Prescott, 1999)—as equilibrium adjustments to exogenous shocks. Attenuated only by the addition of “frictions” which slow down how fast the model of the economy returns to equilibrium, this approach is the foundation of the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models that dominate mainstream macroeconomic modelling today.

  2. 2.

    This includes an annual seminar (which has been cancelled in 2020 because of the Coronavirus) whose standard syllabus can be seen here: https://dseconf.org/dse2019.

  3. 3.

    All of these relationships can be treated as first-order Taylor series approximations to more complex nonlinear relationships and relaxed in the development of more realistic models built upon this foundation.

  4. 4.

    Blatt’s book is an excellent guide to economic dynamics and has recently been re-published as an e-book: see https://www.taylorfrancis.com/books/e/9781315496290 (and ignore the misplaced abstract about Common Law in Hong Kong!). I highly recommend its purchase by all readers of this book.

  5. 5.

    Corporate debt displayed the cyclicality of the Minsky model, and over the longer term, the trend of rising debt as well. “Ponzi Finance” aspect of household debt, which was not included in this simple model, made the cycles in overall private debt less apparent.

  6. 6.

    Personal conversations with Jorgen Randers.

  7. 7.

    The Wikipedia entry gives a good overview of the mathematics: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Compartmental_models_in_epidemiology.

References

  • Bernanke, B. S. (2004). The great moderation: Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, Washington, DC February 20 2004. Washington DC: Eastern Economic Association DC, Federal Reserve Board

    Google Scholar 

  • Blatt, J. M. (1983). Dynamic economic systems: A post-Keynesian approach. Armonk, N.Y., M.E: Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chari, V. V. (2010). Building a science of economics for the real world Subcommittee on investigations and oversight, Committee on science and technology. U. Congress. Washington, USA: Government printing office

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowdy, A. J., Ye, H., et al. (2019). Future changes in extreme weather and pyroconvection risk factors for Australian wildfires. Scientific Reports, 9(1).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. the Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1999). The corporate cost of capital and the return on corporate investment. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 1939–1967.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2004). The capital asset pricing model: Theory and evidence. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 25–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P. (2015). Goodwin’s MKS system: A baseline macro model. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 39(6), 1591–1605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forrester, J. W. (1968). Industrial dynamics-after the first decade. Management Science, 14(7), 398–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forrester, J. W. (1971). World dynamics. Cambridge: MA, Wright-Allen Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forrester, J. W., Gilbert, W. L., et al. (1974). The debate on “world dynamics”: A response to Nordhaus. Policy Sciences, 5(2), 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giraud, G., & Grasselli, M. (2019). Household debt: The missing link between inequality and secular stagnation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1966). Cycles and growth: A growth cycle. Econometrica, 34(5 Supplement), 46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1967). A growth cycle. In C. H. Feinstein (Ed.), Socialism, capitalism and economic growth (pp. 54–58). Press: Cambridge, Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, R. M. (1982). In R. M. Goodwin (Ed.), Essays in economic dynamics. London: Macmillan

    Google Scholar 

  • Grasselli, M., & Costa Lima, B. (2012). An analysis of the Keen model for credit expansion, asset price bubbles and financial fragility. Mathematics and Financial Economics, 6, 191–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grasselli, M. R., & Maheshwari, A. (2017). A comment on ‘Testing Goodwin: Growth cycles in ten OECD countries.’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 41(6), 1761–1766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvie, D., Kelmanson, M. A., et al. (2007). A dynamical model of business-cycle asymmetries: Extending goodwin. Economic Issues, 12(1), 53–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1949). Mr. Harrod’s dynamic theory. Economica, 16(62), 106–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1950). A contribution to the theory of the trade cycle. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ireland, P. N. (2011). A new Keynesian perspective on the great recession. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 43(1), 31–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, S. (1995). Finance and economic breakdown: Modeling Minsky’s ‘financial instability hypothesis’ . Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 17(4), 607–635.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, S. (2006). The Need and Some Methods for Dynamic Modelling in Post Keynesian Economics. Complexity, Endogenous Money and Macroeconomic Theory: Essays in Honour of Basil J. Moore. M. Setterfield. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham: 36–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, S. (2015). The macroeconomics of endogenous money: Response to Fiebiger, Palley & Lavoie. Review of Keynesian Economics, 3(2), 602–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kermack, W. O., McKendrick, A. G., et al. (1927 [1997]). A contribution to the mathematical theory of epidemics. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London A 115, 700–721

    Google Scholar 

  • Landesmann, M., Goodwin, R., et al. (1994). Productivity growth, structural change and macroeconomic stability. In Economic growth and the structure of long-term development: Proceedings of the IEA Conference Held in Varenna, Italy (pp. 205–240). New York: St. Martin's Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, M. (2014). SFC modeling isn't always easy! In UMKC Conference on the Stock Flow Consistent Approach. UMKC

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, M., & Godley, W. (2001). Kaleckian models of growth in a Coherent stock-flow monetary framework: A Kaldorian view. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 24(2), 277–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, T.-Y., & Yorke, J. A. (1975). Period Three implies chaos. The American Mathematical Monthly, 82(10), 985–992.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas Jr, R. E., & Sargent, T. J. (1978). After Keynesian macroeconomics. In F. E. Morrais (Ed.), After The Phillips curve: Persistence of high inflation and high unemployment. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1867). Capital. Moscow: Progress Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLeay, M., Radia, A., et al. (2014). Money creation in the modern economy. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2014(Q1), 14–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meadows, D. H., Randers, J., et al. (1972). The limits to growth. New York: Signet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. P. (1957). Monetary systems and accelerator models. The American Economic Review, 47(6), 860–883.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. P. (1977). The financial instability hypothesis: An interpretation of Keynes and an alternative to ‘standard’ theory. Nebraska Journal of Economics and Business, 16(1), 5–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. P. (1982). Can “it” happen again?: Essays on instability and finance. Armonk, N.Y., M.E: Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski, P. (2020). The neoliberal Ersatz nobel prize. In D. Plehwe, Q. Slobodian, & P. Mirowski (Eds.), Nine lives of Neoliberalism (pp. 219–254). London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1973). World Dynamics: Measurement without data. The Economic Journal, 83(332), 1156–1183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D., Stavins, R. N., et al. (1992). Lethal Model 2: The limits to growth revisited. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1992(2), 1–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pomeau, Y., & Manneville, P. (1980). Intermittent transition to turbulence in dissipative dynamical systems. Communications in Mathematical Physics, 74, 189–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E. C. (1999). Some observations on the great depression. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 23(1), 25–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quiggin, J. (2010). Zombie economics: How dead ideas still walk among us/John Quiggin. Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (2016). The trouble with macroeconomics. https://paulromer.net/trouble-with-macroeconomics-update/WP-Trouble.pdf.

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1939a). Interactions between the multiplier analysis and the principle of acceleration. Review of Economic and Statistics, 20, 75–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1939b). A Synthesis of the principle of acceleration and the multiplier. Journal of Political Economy, 47(6), 786–797.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J., & Stachurski, J. (2020a). Advanced quantitative economics with python.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J., & Stachurski, J. (2020b). Quantitative economics with python.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J., & Wallace, N. (1976). Rational expectations and the theory of economic policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 2(2), 169–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srinivasan, N. (2008). From the great inflation to the great Moderation: A literature survey. Journal of Quantitative Economics, New Series, 6(1–2), 40–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (2002). Has the business cycle changed and why? NBER Working Papers, National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walters, A. A. (1966). Incremental capital-output ratios. The Economic Journal, 76(304), 818–822.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Steve Keen .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Using a Godley Table in Epidemiology

Appendix: Using a Godley Table in Epidemiology

The basic SIR model of susceptibility, infection and recovery (Kermack, McKendrick et al., 1927 [1997]) can be seen as an extension of the predator–prey model, in which the consequence of predation is not death but infection.Footnote 7 In the basic predator–prey model, an assumed exponential growth of the prey population x at a rate \(\frac{1}{x}\frac{{\text{d}}x}{{{\text{d}}t}} = \alpha\) is reduced by a constant \(\beta\) times y, the prey population, so that \(\frac{1}{x}\frac{{\text{d}}x}{{{\text{d}}t}} = \alpha - \beta \times y\). Interaction between the predator and prey is thus shown as a multiplicative relationship.

In modelling a pandemic, the population N is normally treated as a constant, since it changes far less rapidly than the epidemic spreads. The rate of change of the fraction of the population that is infected depends on the interactions of those infected I with those susceptible S, which in turn depends on the frequency of both groups in the overall population, S/N and I/N, and the transmissibility of the disease, which is modelled by the parameter \(\beta\):

$$\frac{{\text{d}}}{{\text{d}}t}\frac{S}{N} = - \beta \cdot \frac{I}{N} \cdot \frac{S}{N}$$
(18.32)

Since population is treated as constant, this reduces to:

$$\frac{{\text{d}}}{{\text{d}}t}S = - \beta \cdot \frac{I \cdot S}{N}$$
(18.33)

Since the increase in those infected is equal to the fall in those who are susceptible, the rate of growth of those infected is the negative of the rate of decline of those susceptible, minus the recovery rate R, which is modelled as a parameter \(\gamma\) times the number infected:

$$\begin{aligned} & \frac{{\text{d}}}{{\text{d}}t}I = \beta \cdot \frac{S \cdot I}{N} - \gamma \cdot I \\ & \frac{{\text{d}}}{{\text{d}}t}R = \gamma \cdot I \\ \end{aligned}$$
(18.34)

Figure 18.10 shows this model implemented in Minsky, using time constants rather than parameters. The Godley Table’s tabular format makes it easy to see the interrelations between the susceptible, infected, and recovered compartments. Flowchart tools are only needed to define the flows themselves (and future versions will allow these to be defined off the canvas, using standard LATEX equation notation).

Fig. 18.10
figure 10

Cyclical growth in the third-order Multiplier-Accelerator Model, with a higher savings rate meaning lower growth

The Godley Table interface also makes it very easy to extend this model to a more realistic situation in which there is a more complicated transmission chain—see Fig. 18.11. Other comparmentalizations—such as dividing the susceptible population into the general public and medical staff, including quarantined versus non-quarantined, hospitalized versus non-hospitalized, etc.—are equally straightforward to add and define by adding additional columns and matching flows to Fig. 18.12.

Fig. 18.11
figure 11

Simple SIR model of a pandemic

Fig. 18.12
figure 12

SEIRD model developed by editing Godley table of SIR model

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Keen, S. (2021). Burying Samuelson’s Multiplier-Accelerator and Resurrecting Goodwin’s Growth Cycle in Minsky. In: Cavana, R.Y., Dangerfield, B.C., Pavlov, O.V., Radzicki, M.J., Wheat, I.D. (eds) Feedback Economics. Contemporary Systems Thinking. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-67190-7_18

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics