Skip to main content

Economics of Socialism 2: Planning vs. The Market

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Democracy or Socialism
  • 171 Accesses

Abstract

The property-rights-based, Leninist definition of socialism operates based on an orthodox application of Marxist economic theory. Its labor-value theory excludes economic exchange under market prices, and therefore any form of government promoting such. By contrast, the redistributive, democratic definition of socialism has been economically more successful. It retains free-market prices for microeconomic allocation of resources. There is, however, a tension between microeconomic, free-market resource allocation, and macroeconomic redistribution. The challenge for democratic socialism is to apply their political method while maintaining an economic advantage over the Leninist socialist method and its teleological central planning.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Any attempt to put Marxist theory to work also runs into an egg-or-chicken problem, alluded to by Samuelson (1967, 619). Scarce resources are by necessity priced by the market; to shift away from market prices onto labor-value exchange rates, the central-planning agency must first overcome the scarcity, or else market prices will supersede the labor value. The only way out is for government to suspend the free market by force.

  2. 2.

    It is often said that these are minor examples that do not show a consistent ideological trend. However, the very purpose of the welfare state is precisely that: to gradually, by small steps, reconfigure the economy in the image of economic redistribution.

  3. 3.

    Again, socialists who choose the traditional, orthodoxically Marxist method to achieve their ideological goal, do not do so because ending capitalism is their end goal. They see it simply as the most effective policy method to eliminate economic differences between individual citizens.

  4. 4.

    Comparable numbers for the United States with the same statistical meaning are not available.

  5. 5.

    To even reach this volume, one has to define their welfare-state work broadly, including published material that is not even aimed at reforming welfare-state spending, only to describe and explain it.

  6. 6.

    https://danieljmitchell.wordpress.com/2012/06/10/sweden-the-sensible-and-slowly-shrinking-welfare-state/. Accessed 23 June 2020.

  7. 7.

    https://finance.townhall.com/columnists/danieljmitchell/2019/07/16/socialism-and-the-welfare-state-in-nordic-nations-n2550121. Accessed 23 June 2020.

  8. 8.

    https://www.forbes.com/sites/jeffreydorfman/2018/07/08/sorry-bernie-bros-but-nordic-countries-are-not-socialist/#5459c58974ad. Accessed 23 June 2020.

  9. 9.

    https://nypost.com/2020/06/20/democrats-socialism-looks-more-like-venezuela-than-scandinavia/. Accessed 23 June 2020.

  10. 10.

    Larson (2018, chapter 6) discusses these theories at length.

  11. 11.

    It is possible that these four writers, again representative of American conservatism in general, are of the neoconservative opinion that there is a golden mean to be struck between the welfare state and the free-market economy. The neoconservative ideology is discussed in chapter 6 below.

  12. 12.

    These numbers are based on pre-coronavirus conditions. It remains to be seen how much the welfare state will grow as a result of Congressional spending bills in response to the epidemic.

References

  • Baer, H. (2020). Democratic eco-socialism as a real utopia: Transitioning to an alternative world system. Berghahn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronfenbrenner, M. (1967). Marxian influences in “bourgeois” economics. The American Economic Review, 57(2), 624–635.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickinson, H. (1957). The falling rate of profit in Marxian economics. The Review of Economic Studies, 24(2), 120–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster, J. (1982). Marxian economics and the state. Science & Society, 46(3), 257–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. (1973). Economics and the public purpose. Houghton: Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hauser, P. (1955). Freedom and economic planning. Philippine Sociological Review, 3(2), 3–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirst, P. (1988). Associational socialism in a pluralist state. Journal of Law and Society, 15(1), 139–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. Brace and company: Harcourt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (2000). What the change of system from socialism to capitalism does and does not mean. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), 27–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larson, S. (2014). Industrial poverty: Yesterday Sweden, today Europe. Gower: Tomorrow America.

    Google Scholar 

  • Larson, S. (2018). The rise of big government: How egalitarianism conquered America. Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. (1960). Beyond the welfare state. London: Duckworth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (1980). A general equilibrium approach to Marxian economics. Econometrica, 48(2), 505–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1967). Marxian economics as economics. The American Economic Review, 57(2), 616–623.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherman, H. (1966). Marxist economics and Soviet planning. Soviet Studies, 18(2), 169–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. (1993). Post walrasian and post marxian economics. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(1), 109–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swilling, M. (1992). Socialism, democracy and civil society: The case for associational socialism. Theoria: A Journal of Social and Political Theory, 79(May), 75–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor IV, F. (Ed.) (2011). The great lie: Classic and recent appraisals of ideology and totalitarianism. Wilmington, DE: ISI Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilling, C., Krol, M., Attema, A. E., Tsuchiya, A., Brazier, J., van Exel, J., & Brouwer, W. (2016). Exploring a new method for deriving the monetary value of a QALY. The European Journal of Health Economics, 17(7), 801–809.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Larson, S.R. (2021). Economics of Socialism 2: Planning vs. The Market. In: Democracy or Socialism. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-65643-0_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics