Skip to main content

Financing Climate Change Policies: A Multi-phase Integrated Assessment Model for Mitigation and Adaptation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Dynamic Economic Problems with Regime Switches

Abstract

We present an extended integrated assessment model (IAM) that optimizes climate financing policies over multiple phases of discrete policy action. We build on Semmler et al. (Control systems and mathematical methods in economics. Springer, 2018) which develops a single-phase model of the optimal allocation of infrastructure expenditure to carbon-neutral physical capital, climate change adaptation, and emissions mitigation. That model is solved by discretizing the optimal control problem and applying large-scale optimization techniques. A new algorithm, the arc parameterization method (APM), allows us to extend the model to multiple regimes, operationalized through a 3-phase policy environment. The first policy regime is defined by a limited set of policy tools. In the second regime, green bonds (i.e. climate-focused financing) are introduced, and in the final regime, green bonds are repaid with a new tax. We demonstrate that this multi-phase model incorporating climate, fiscal and financial policies is superior to single-phase models.

This paper was developed while Willi Semmler was a visiting scholar at the IIASA in July and August 2016. He would like to thank the IIASA for its hospitality. A related version of this paper was worked out while Willi Semmler was a visiting scholar at the IMF Research Department in April 2016. The authors would like to thank Prakash Loungani and his colleagues for many helpful insights.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Bonen et al. [2] for a further discussion.

  2. 2.

    All variables are in per capita terms.

  3. 3.

    The exponent \(\beta \) is the output elasticity of public infrastructure, \(\nu _{1}g\).

  4. 4.

    Use of R emits carbon dioxide increasing M at the rate \(\gamma \). The stable level of CO2 emissions is \(\kappa >1\) of the pre-industrial level \(\widetilde{M}\). Some CO2 is absorbed into oceanic reservoirs at the rate \(\mu \).

  5. 5.

    Note that instead of an independent damage function mapping climate change into output reductions, (6.7) treats climate change as a direct welfare loss. Adaptation efforts are modelled in a similarly direct fashion. We adopt this approach because the welfare impacts of climate change are not limited to lost productivity. For example, loss of life will increase from changing disease vectors and more intense heat waves.

  6. 6.

    Under a single-regime setting, Semmler et al. [15] demonstrate incorporating the \(\nu _i\) as controls in U improves welfare outcomes versus treating them as fixed parameters.

  7. 7.

    See Eq. (6.6) and accompanying text. We also want to note the long period of no fossil fuel energy extraction comes from the fact that the carbon stock is presumed to start at a low initial level as well as the low efficiency of the fossil fuel-based energy assumed, i.e. \(A_u=100\) (see Sect. 6.6 below).

  8. 8.

    Of course, the initial values apply only to the starting values in phase 1 and the terminal constraints bind only at \(T=70\), at the end of the third phase.

  9. 9.

    DSGE models have also recently allowed for regime switches (see [12], Sect. 7.2), but not address the issue of discontinuities in the control variables.

  10. 10.

    In addition, when green bonds portend reductions in CO\(_{2}\)-emitting energy sources, their issuance might lead to significant devaluation of assets representing fossil fuels if this is expected to increase the risk of these assets becoming (so-called) “stranded” assets. Formally introducing this effect is left for later work.

  11. 11.

    Note that in the present context the Ricardian equivalence theorem, which says that the real side of the economy will not be affected by deficit spending financed through issuing of bonds, is not applicable in this context. This is because green bonds are used to reduce future damages to GDP, and thus carry some future returns from their investments (in particular from public infrastructure). For details, see Orlov et al. [13].

  12. 12.

    In this context, a recent discussion of proposals for central banks to accept climate bonds as collateralizable securities is available in Flaherty et al. [6].

References

  1. Augustin, D., & Maurer, H. (2000). Second order sufficient conditions and sensitivity analysis for optimal multiprocess control problems. Control and Cybernetics, 29, 11–31.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Bonen, A., Semmler, W., & Klasen, S. (2014). Economic damages from climate change: A review of modeling approaches. SCEPA working paper 2014–03, Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Chiarella, C., Semmler, W., Hsiao, C.-Y., & Mateane, L. (2016). Sustainable asset accumulation and dynamic portfolio decisions. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Clarke, F. H., & Vinter, R. B. (1989). Applications of optimal multiprocesses. SIAM Journal of Control and Optimization, 27, 1048–1071.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Clarke, F. H., & Vinter, R. B. (1989). Optimal multiprocesses. SIAM Journal of Control and Optimization, 27, 1072–1091.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Flaherty, M., Gevorkyan, A., Radpour, S., & Semmler, W. (2017). Financing climate policies through climate bonds: A three stage model and empirics. Research in International Business and Finance, 42, 468–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Heine, D., Semmler, W., Mazzucato, M., Braga, J. P., Flaherty, M., Gevorkyan, A., et al. (2019). Financing low-carbon transitions through carbon pricing and green bonds. Quarterly Journal of Economic Research, 88, 29–49.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Herbst, E., & Schorfheide, F. (2015). Bayesian estimation of DSGE models. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Hotelling, H. (1931). The economics of exhaustible resources. Journal of Political Economy, 39(2), 137–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Lin, Q., Loxton, R., & Teo, K. L. (2014). The control parameterization method of optimal control problems: A survey. Journal of Industrial and Management Optimization, 10, 275–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Loxton, R., Lin, Q., Rehbock, V., & Teo, K. L. (2012). Control parameterization for optimal control problems with continuous inequality constraints: New convergence results. Numerical Algebra, Control and Optimization, 2, 571–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Maurer, H., Büskens, C., Kim, J.-H., & Kaya, C. Y. (2005). Optimization methods for the verification of second order sufficient conditions for bang-bang controls. Optimal Control: Applications and Methods, 26, 129–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Orlov, S., Rovenskaya, E., Puascunder, J., & Semmler, W. (2018). Green bonds, transition to a low-carbon economy, and intergenerational fairness: Evidence from an extended dice model. IIASA working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Sachs, J. (2014). Climate change and intergenerational well-being. In L. Bernard & W. Semmler (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of the macroeconomics of global warming (pp. 248–259). Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Semmler, W., Maurer, H., & Bonen, A. (2018). An extended integrated assessment model for mitigation & adaptation policies on climate change. In G. Feichtinger, R. Kovacevic, & G. Tragler (Eds.), Control systems and mathematical methods in economics (Vol. 687). Lecture notes in economics and mathematical. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Tobin, J. (1969). A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Baking, 1(1), 15–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tony Bonen .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Multi-phase Optimal Control Problems and Their Numerical Solution

Appendix: Multi-phase Optimal Control Problems and Their Numerical Solution

Multi-process (multi-phase) optimal control problems have been studied by Clarke and Vinter [4, 5] and later by Augustin and Maurer [1]. Suppose that a dynamic economic process on a given time interval [0, T] consists of \((s+1)\) phases (regimes) that switch at the transition times \(t_{k}\in (0,T),\,k=1,...,s\). The switching times are ordered according to

$$\begin{aligned} 0=t_{0}<t_{1}<t_{2}<\cdots<t_{s}<t_{s+1}=T. \end{aligned}$$
(6.11)

In each interval \([t_{k},t_{k+1}],\,k=0,1,\ldots s,\) the dynamics and objectives may be different.

Let \(x\in \mathbb {R}^{n}\) be the state variable and \(u\in \mathbb {R}^{m}\) the control variable. The dimensions of the state vector and control vector may be different in different phases. For simplicity, we refrain here from discussing this general case and assume the same dimensions in each subinterval. Hence, the dynamics of the economic process in the interval \([t_k,t_{t+1}]\) is given by the ordinary differential equation,

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{x}(t)=f_{k} \big ( x(t),u(t) \big ) ,\quad t_{k}\le t\le t_{k+1}\quad (k=0,1,\ldots ,s), \end{aligned}$$
(6.12)

where the right-hand side of the ODE is a \(C^{1}\) function \(f_{k}:\mathbb {R}^{n}\times \mathbb {R}^{m}\rightarrow \mathbb {R}^{n}.\) The time \(t_{k}\) in (6.12) is understood from the right, while the time \(t_{k+1}\) is taken from the left. The initial condition and terminal constraints are given as

$$\begin{aligned} x(0)=x_{0},\quad \psi (x(T))=0. \end{aligned}$$
(6.13)

We further impose control constraints in each interval,

$$\begin{aligned} u_{k,\min }\le u(t)\le u_{k,\max }\,,\quad t_{k}\le t\le t_{k+1}\quad (k=0,1,\ldots ,s), \end{aligned}$$
(6.14)

with \(-\infty \le u_{k,\min }<u_{k,\max }\le +\infty \).

A continuous state trajectory x(t) on the whole interval [0, T] is obtained by imposing the continuity condition

$$\begin{aligned} x(t_{k})=x(t_{k}-),\qquad k=1,\ldots ,s. \end{aligned}$$
(6.15)

Note that the continuity of the state variables in (6.15) does not automatically ensure the continuity of the control variables; in fact, these can jump, as we demonstrate below, when the system transitions between policy phases are studied. Moreover, we can prescribe interior (transition) conditions for the state variables by

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi _k(x(t_k-) = 0 ,\quad k= 1,\ldots ,s , \end{aligned}$$
(6.16)

with \(C^{1}\) functions \(\varphi _k : \mathbb {R}^n \rightarrow \mathbb {R}.\)

In each interval one may also have different objectives which are defined by functions \(L_{k}:\mathbb {R}^{n}\times \mathbb {R}^{m}\rightarrow \mathbb {R}^{n},\;k=0,1,\ldots ,s\). Then the optimal multi-phase control problem is defined by the following objective:

$$\begin{aligned} J(x,u) = \max _{u} \left\{ \sum _{k=0}^{k=s}\;\int \limits _{t_{k}}^{t_{k+1}}\,e^{-r_k\cdot t}L_{k}(x(t),u(t))\,dt \right\} , \end{aligned}$$
(6.17)

subject to the constraints (6.12)–(6.15), and \(r_k > 0\) for \(k = 0, 1, \ldots , s\).

To solve the optimal multi-phase control problem, we implement the arc-parametrization in Maurer et al. [12] in conjunction with discretization and nonlinear programming methods. Although they apply the arc-parametrization method (APM) only to bang-bang control problems, the APM can easily be extended to continuous, multi-phase control problems as follows. Let

$$\begin{aligned} \xi _{k}=t_{k+1}-t_{k},\quad k=0,1,\ldots ,s, \end{aligned}$$
(6.18)

denote the arc lengths (or, arc durations) of the multi-process. The time interval \([t_{k},t_{k+1}]\) is mapped onto the fixed interval \([k/(s+1),(k+1)/(s+1)]\) by the linear transformation

$$\begin{aligned} t&= a_{k}+b_{k}\tau , \quad \tau \in \left[ \frac{k}{s+1},\frac{k+1}{s+1}\right] , \end{aligned}$$
(6.19)

where \(a_k = t_k - k \xi _k\) and \(b_{k}=(s+1)\xi _{k}\). Taken together, the complete time interval [0, T] is thereby mapped onto the unit interval [0, 1]. Identifying \(x(\tau )=x(a_{k}+b_{k}\tau )=x(t)\) in the relevant intervals, we obtain the scaled ODE system

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dx}{d\tau } = \xi _{k}(s+1) \cdot f_{k} \big (t_{k}+\tau \cdot \xi _{k}, x(\tau ), u(\tau ) \big ) \end{aligned}$$
(6.20)

for \(\tau \in \left[ \frac{k}{s+1},\frac{k+1}{s+1}\right] \). Note that \(\xi _{k}\) are treated as optimization variables if the transition times \(t_{k}\) are free.

The time transformation leads us to rescale the objective function (6.17) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} J(x,u)= \max _{u} \left\{ \sum _{k=0}^{k=s} \int \limits _{\frac{k}{s+1}}^{\frac{k+1}{s+1}} \xi _{k}(s+1)e^{-r_k \cdot (a_{k}+b_{k}\tau )}L_{k}(x(\tau ),u(\tau ))\,d\tau \right\} , \end{aligned}$$
(6.21)

and subject to (6.12)–(6.15) and rescaled according to (6.19). For the purposes of exposition, we fix the transition points \(t_k\) to reflect the exogenous (and often sub-optimally protracted) nature of introducing and implementing new policies.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Semmler, W., Maurer, H., Bonen, T. (2021). Financing Climate Change Policies: A Multi-phase Integrated Assessment Model for Mitigation and Adaptation. In: Haunschmied, J.L., Kovacevic, R.M., Semmler, W., Veliov, V.M. (eds) Dynamic Economic Problems with Regime Switches. Dynamic Modeling and Econometrics in Economics and Finance, vol 25. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-54576-5_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics