Skip to main content

Power in Networks and the Urban Space

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Cultural Commons and Urban Dynamics

Abstract

The urban space paper is introduced by a brief “report” on the founding of Rome by Romulus; he traced a furrow and thereby defined the urban space. The core of the paper, however, defines the urban space by the dimension of collective decision-making expressed in the form of voting games. It offers a power index analysis of the relationship between the agents of a network—applying the Public Good Index (PGI) and the Public Value (PV)—reinterprets previous work by Holler and Rupp (Power in networks: A PGI analysis of Krackhardt’s Kite Network. Transactions on computational collective intelligence. Springer, Heidelberg, 2019), and presents new numerical results and gives alternative interpretations. The results confirm our expectations: an increase of links and thereby connectedness tends to increase the power of an agent. The message for policymaking in the urban space is evident. This motivated us to discuss the question of why we should be interested in evaluating the power distribution within a network. Here, our focus is on the accountability of the agents—and the Smart City concept.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    This date is given in Fustel de Coulange (2006 [1864]: 138). The following account derives from this text.

  2. 2.

    These intervals of carrying the plow were called portae (Fustel de Coulange 2006 [1864]: 138).

  3. 3.

    Holler and Marciano (2010) discussed Machiavelli’s “possibility hypothesis” with reference to Arrow’s notorious “impossibility theorem” which says that, given a set of quite reasonable condition, we cannot exclude that an aggregation of individual preference fails and we cannot derive a social welfare function—unless we accept that it is dictatorial (see Arrow (1963[1951]).

  4. 4.

    Figures 1 and 2, the introduction to the Public Good Index and Public Value, etc., are borrowed from Holler and Rupp (2019).

  5. 5.

    Vertex D has the highest degree centrality, H and I rate highest with respect to betweenness centrality, and F and G have, on the average, the shortest path distance to the other vertices (closeness centrality).

  6. 6.

    The swing players define the power for the indices of Shapley–Shubik, Penrose–Banzhaf–Coleman, Johnston, and Deegan–Packel. These measures vary in what coalitions are to be considered and how the coalition surplus is distributed among their members.

  7. 7.

    Myerson (1977) presents a bargaining model for networks that connects the (fair) bargaining outcome and the corresponding Shapley value.

  8. 8.

    For a recent discussion of the PGI, see Holler (2019). Note there are more than ten power indices, but there is only one measure that is serious about measuring the impact of a player in producing a public good, i.e., the PGI.

  9. 9.

    However, Fragnelli (2012) applies the Banzhaf index to measure power which takes into account all winning coalitions. It is not obvious that this index expresses the impact of a decision-maker in the case of a public good. (See Holler 1982, 2019).

  10. 10.

    In general, parliaments and city councils do not change their majority rules if links between parties altered, and, in the extreme, a party became unconnected to any other like going from Γ and Γ1.

  11. 11.

    In order to form a winning coalition, i needs to be connected to at least d − 1 vertices (such that they form a connected subgraph). The required d − 1 many nodes can be on any side of i in the network such that the winning coalitions i belong to a circle/sphere with maximal radius d − 1. Here, the notion of a radius is in terms of graph neighborhoods: if i has a high enough degree it may be the case that the coalition is formed by direct neighbors of i only, i.e., i is connected to each of the members of its coalition by minimal paths of length 1. In this sense, the worst case that can occur, maximizing the distance, is that actually a d − 1 neighbor has to be a member of the coalition. (The shortest path between i and this vertex has length d − 1).

  12. 12.

    In his Picture of Dorian Gray, Oscar Wilde characterized a Radical member of Parliament by the by now notorious quote: “Like all people who try to exhaust a subject, he exhausted his listeners.”

  13. 13.

    For a more intensive discussion of the relationship of power and responsibility, see Holler (2007).

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1963 [1951]). Social choice and individual value (2nd ed.). New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandes, U., & Hildenbrand, J. (2014). Smallest graphs with distinct Singleton Centers. Network Science, 2, 416–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fragnelli, V. (2012). A note on communication structures. Homo Oeconomicus, 29, 163–171. Republished in Holler, M. J., & Nurmi, H. (Eds.). (2013). Power, voting, and voting power: 30 years after (pp. 467-473). Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fustel de Coulange, N. D. (2006 [1864]). The ancient city: A study of religion, laws, and institutions of Greece and Rome (Orig.: La cité antique, Paris 1864), Mineola, NY: Dover Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. (1982). Forming coalitions and measuring voting power. Political Studies, 30, 262–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. (2007). Freedom of choice, power, and the responsibility of decision makers. In J.-M. Josselin & A. Marciano (Eds.), Democracy, freedom and coercion: A law and economics approach (pp. 22–45). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. (2019). The story of the poor public good index. In N. T. Nguyen, R. Kowalzyk, J. Mercik, & A. Motylska-Kruzma (Eds), Transactions on computational collective intelligence (Vol. 34, pp. 171–179). Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Li, X. (1995). From public good index to public value: An axiomatic approach and generalization. Control and Cybernetics, 24, 257–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Marciano, A. (2010). Machiavelli’s possibility hypothesis. AUCO Czech Economic Review, 4, 18–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Packel, E. W. (1983). Power, luck, and the right index. Journal of Economics (Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie), 43, 21–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. & Rupp, F. (2019). Power in networks: A PGI analysis of Krackhardt’s Kite Network. In N. T. Nguyen, R. Kowalzyk, J. Mercik & A. Motylska-Kruzma (Eds), Transactions on computational collective intelligence (Vol. 34, pp. 21–34). Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krackhardt, D. (1990). Assessing the political landscape: Structure, cognition, and power in organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 342–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machiavelli, N. (1882). Discourses on the first ten books of Titus Livius. In: The Historical, Political, and Diplomatic Writings of Niccolò Machiavelli (Trans. from the Italian by Christian E. Detmold, Boston: James R. Osgood and Co.).

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1977). Graphs and cooperation in games. Mathematics of Operations Research, 2, 225–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orłowski, C., Sitek, T., Ziółkowski, A., Kapłański, P., Orłowski, A. & Pokrzywnicki, W. (2019). Introduction. In C.Orłowski, T. Sitek, A. Ziółkowski, P., Kapłański, A. Orłowski & W. Pokrzywnicki (Eds), Considerations in the design and implementation of Smart Cities systems. Gdańsk, Poland: CAS IBM Center for Advanced Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Leewen, B., Ramalingam, A., Arjona, D. R., & Schram, A. (2019). Centrality and cooperation in networks. Experimental Economics, 16, 178–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1948[1924]). Class, status and party. In H. H. Gerth & C. Wright Mills (Eds.), Essays from Max Weber. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Barbara Klose-Ullmann for the helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Manfred J. Holler .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Holler, M.J., Rupp, F. (2020). Power in Networks and the Urban Space. In: Macrì, E., Morea, V., Trimarchi, M. (eds) Cultural Commons and Urban Dynamics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-54418-8_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics