Skip to main content

A Case of Arbitrage in a Worldwide Trade: Roman Coins in India

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Managing Information in the Roman Economy

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in Ancient Economies ((PASTAE))

  • 364 Accesses

Abstract

For centuries, there has been a steady and profitable commerce between the Roman Empire and India. One of the most striking evidence of such trade are the Roman coins found in India over the last two centuries. This body of evidence has always used to try to guess the scale and the fluctuations of the Roman exports to the East. Nevertheless, such attempts have been so far fruitless, because they mostly failed to understand the real nature of this sort of evidence. This paper aims to revise the available evidence to demonstrate, firstly, that the phenomenon of the Roman coins in India cannot be properly understood without a proper theoretical economic framework to interpret it. From this point of view, the analytical tools of both New Institutional Economics (NIE) and asymmetric information theory are essential. Secondly, this paper argues that Roman coins were only exported to India when this was profitable. The reason that drove Roman merchants to trade Roman currency in India was the different ratio between silver and gold in the two regions of the Ancient World. Because of this difference, there were moments in which trading coins was more profitable than it would have been inside the Empire. This would represent a case for arbitrage. A combination of the evidence of the Periplus Maris Erythreai and of some Indian inscriptions allow us to shed light on a sophisticated financial process that was part of the international business between the Roman Empire and India, and, in more general terms, on the features of the Roman economic system.

This research was carried out in the framework of the STAR programme, funded by UniNa and Compagnia San Paolo. I would like to express my gratitude here to Prof William V. Harris and Prof Domenico Fausto for their willingness to read an earlier version of this work and give me their extensive feedbacks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Bang 2012: 303. On the same subject, see also Hingley 2005: 106; Lo Cascio 2007: 622; 2009: 208; Tchernia 2016: 72–96.

  2. 2.

    In economic history, this tendency is even more pronounced, because of the inclination of economists to describe economic activities in mathematical terms. An interesting and updated debate on such a leaning can be found in Boer and Petterson 2017: 1–48; Blanton IV and Hollander 2019: 9–11.

  3. 3.

    See the classic Hicks 1969: 1–8 for an economist’s purview on the matter.

  4. 4.

    On the topic, see for example the discussion in Meikle 2002; Bang 2012: 301–302.

  5. 5.

    For an interesting treating of the issues related to the application of economic theories and models on the ancient economy, see recently for example Verboven 2015a and Erdkamp 2015; see also the very recent and extremely compelling collective book edited by Hollander, Blanton IV and Fitzgerald 2019, which is full of stimulating new insights aimed at breaking the limits of a ‘market-oriented’ scholarship on the ancient economy.

  6. 6.

    The problem of describing non-modern economic activities in modern terms is already fully discussed by Karl Marx in his Grundrisse: Marx 1973: 105–106; see also Marx 2002. See recently Boer and Petterson 2017: xi–xxi for an engaging discussion on the usefulness of applying modern approaches to the study of Antiquity.

  7. 7.

    Morris 1994.

  8. 8.

    I will refer to Morley 2009 and Manning 2018 for a very elegant discussion of the issues related to this huge topic.

  9. 9.

    See for instance Frederiksen 1975: 10: “the old debate between primitivists and modernists (is) a small and rather unimportant duel (…) Neither thesis (is) really acceptable without a good deal of emendation”. The attempts to shift the debate intensified since the ‘90s of the last century: see Harris 1993. An interesting overall rethinking of the economy of Antiquity is in Andreau and Maucourant 1999; Bresson 2000. In the new millennium, see the monumental Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World (Scheidel et al. 2007), followed by a considerable step forward thanks to the works of for example Erdkamp and Verboven 2015; Kehoe et al. 2015; Boer and Petterson 2017; Manning 2018; Hollander et al. 2019.

  10. 10.

    Among the most interesting cases of comparative history of the last few years, Scheidel’s and Bang’s works are definitely noteworthy. See Scheidel 2009 and 2015 for a contrast between the Roman Empire and ancient China. See also Morris and Scheidel 2009 for a wider range of comparisons among pre-industrial societies. See instead Bang 2008 for a comparison between the Roman Empire and the Moghul Empire. See also Bang and Kołodziejczyk 2012 for a comparison between Eurasian empires.

  11. 11.

    Bowman and Wilson 2009; Scheidel 2012b: 1; Jongman 2014: 75–77; Lo Cascio 2018: 117–118; Zuiderhoek 2019: 51.

  12. 12.

    Harris 2011: 156.

  13. 13.

    It should be noted incidentally that even the importance of trade as a proxy to understand the structures of the ancient economy is a concept that has always been taken for granted. See now on this subject Hollander et al. 2019.

  14. 14.

    For a survey of the different points of view and interpretations on the subject, see for example the chapter “A Forum on Trade” in Scheidel 2012a: 287–317. The idea that eastern merchandise were only luxury items dates back as far as Gibbon (1776), and, despite being proved wrong by many scholars (see e.g. Sidebotham 1986; Morley 2007, 573–574) still has some supporters among modern scholars: see for example McLaughlin 2010.

  15. 15.

    Appian (Introduction 15) explicitly refers to such documents. Other hints in Suet. Vita Aug. 101; Stat. Silv. 3.3.85–108. See also Nicolet 1982; Wilson 2009.

  16. 16.

    See for example the classic criticisms of Braudel 1979; Finley 1985: 61.

  17. 17.

    Rostovtzeff 1926 and 1957. See also Hopkins 1983; Cartledge 1998; Morley 2004; Temin 2001, 2013.

  18. 18.

    Morley 2007: 5. Similarly, see also Vivenza 2012.

  19. 19.

    Again, I have specifically in mind the recent works of Erdkamp and Verboven 2015; Kehoe et al. 2015; Hollander et al. 2019.

  20. 20.

    Nappo 2018.

  21. 21.

    A very short synthesis of the most important works of the three Nobel laureates can be found in Löfgren et al. 2002.

  22. 22.

    Eatwell et al. 2000: 133–135.

  23. 23.

    The theory was first developed in Akerlof 1970. See Eatwell et al. 2000: 133–135.

  24. 24.

    Stiglitz 1989.

  25. 25.

    Akerlof 1970.

  26. 26.

    Jones 2014: 236.

  27. 27.

    Ael. Arist. Oration 6.12–13.

  28. 28.

    Aug. Res Gest. 31: Ad me ex India regum legationes saepe missae sunt non visae ante id tempus apud quemquam Romanorum ducem.

  29. 29.

    The first to deal with the subject was Gibbon, in his The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire (1776–1789); see also Warmington (1928, revised edition 1974). But the turning point for such studies was the excavations made by Wheeler at Arikamedu, in India, that for the first time provided some actual archaeological evidence of the trade between the two areas of the world (Wheeler 1976). Since then, the number of papers and works published on the topic has constantly increased.

  30. 30.

    See Young 2001 for a full discussion.

  31. 31.

    Sidebotham 1986: 20–21. Most of the following scholarship has now accepted this important point. See for example Ball 2000: 130; Young 2001: 14–17. Yet the old approach to the Indian trade as merely a trade in luxury items is still present in some recent works unwilling to engage with the progress of modern scholarship (e.g. McLaughlin 2010: 7–10; and again 2016: 1).

  32. 32.

    Every attempt to list all the relevant monographs appeared after Sidebotham’s first book is doomed to be incomplete. Among the most relevant studies on the subject, it is certainly necessary to mark out the works of De Romanis 2006, 1998, 2020; Young 2001; Sidebotham 2011; Power 2012; Seland 2008, 2010, 2014; Gurukkal 2016; Boussac et al. 2016; Mathew 2016; Manzo et al. 2018; Cobb 2015a, 2018a, c.

  33. 33.

    For an engaging discussion on the applicability of concepts such as globalisation and world economy to Antiquity, see Hingley 2005; LaBianca and Scham 2006; Jennings 2011; Pitts and Versluys 2015; more recently Terpstra 2019: 1–32. On the definition of Global History, see for example Conrad 2016.

  34. 34.

    See for example the works of McLaughlin 2010 and 2016; Manzo et al. 2018, which all in their titles rather ambitiously refer to the concepts of World Economy and Globalisation, while not specifically addressing such sensible topics. More interesting is the purview of Seland (2008, 2010: 18–20; 2014: 386–387), who prefers to speak of ‘oikoumenisation’. See also Cobb 2018b: 5–7.

  35. 35.

    Plin. NH 6.101.

  36. 36.

    Plin. NH 12.84 (trans. Bostock and Riley (1855)).

  37. 37.

    See Tac., Ann., 3.53 (reporting Tiberius’ words): Promiscas viris et feminis vestis atque illa feminarum propria, quis lapidum causa pecuniae nostrae ad externas aut hostilis gentis transferuntur. (‘The apparel worn indiscriminately by both sexes, or that peculiar luxury of women which, for the sake of jewels, diverts our wealth to strange or hostile nations’). As pointed out by Tchernia (2016: 239), the words of Pliny and Tiberius are very similar, suggesting that “either Pliny was directly influenced by an idea actually expressed in Tiberius’ discourse, or it was a topos widely used in the middle decades of the first century, or more precisely, an adaptation of an old topos on luxury and autarky to a particular set of circumstances.”

  38. 38.

    More examples of such a point of view are to be found in the ancient literary sources, such as Dio Chrysostom, Orations 79.5–6: Ἆρα ἐνθυμεῖσθε ὅτι πάντες οὗτοι, λέγω δὲ τοὺς Κελτοὺς καὶ Ἰνδοὺς καὶ Ἴβηρας καὶ Ἄραβας καὶ Βαβυλωνίους, φόρους παρ᾽ ἡμῶν λαμβάνουσιν, οὐ τῆς χώρας οὐδὲ τῶν βοσκημάτων, ἀλλὰ τῆς ἀνοίας τῆς ἡμετέρας; […] πλὴν ὅτι λίθους μικροὺς καὶ ἀσθενεῖς καί, νὴ Δία, θηρίων ὀστᾶ διδόντες λαμβάνουσιν ἀργύριον καὶ χρυσίον, ἀντὶ χρηστῶν ἄχρηστα ἀντικαταλλαττόμενοι. (‘Are you aware that all these peoples—the Celts, Indians, Iberians, Arabs, and Babylonians—exact tribute from us, not from our land or from our flocks and herds, but from our own folly? […] They do offer tiny, fragile pebbles and, forsooth, bones of wild beasts when they take our silver and gold, exchanging useless things for useful’).

  39. 39.

    Raschke 1978: 604–608; Veyne 1979; De Romanis 1982-87: 199; Tchernia 2016: 238–239.

  40. 40.

    See the interesting discussion of De Romanis 2006 on the topic. Also, see MacDowall 2003b: 39. See also recently Cobb 2015b: 199.

  41. 41.

    Note the different opinion expressed by Harris (2011: 227) who argues that payments could also be done in bullion.

  42. 42.

    Yet, our sources make reference also to the possibility of trading with Indians through the means of barter. See for instance Pausanias, Descriptio Graeciae, 3.12, 3–4: Λακεδαιμονίοις δὲ κατὰ τὴν ὁδὸν ταύτην ἐστίν, ὡς ἤδη λέλεκταί μοι, τὰ ὀνομαζόμενα Βοώνητα, Πολυδώρου ποτὲ οἰκία τοῦ βασιλέως: ἀποθανόντος δὲ παρὰ τοῦ Πολυδώρου τῆς γυναικὸς ἐπρίαντο ἀντιδόντες βοῦς. ἀργύρου γὰρ οὐκ ἦν πω τότε οὐδὲ χρυσοῦ νόμισμα, κατὰ τρόπον δὲ ἔτι τὸν ἀρχαῖον ἀντεδίδοσαν βοῦς καὶ ἀνδράποδα καὶ ἀργὸν τὸν ἄργυρον καὶ χρυσόν: οἱ δὲ ἐς τὴν Ἰνδικὴν ἐσπλέοντες φορτίων φασὶν Ἑλληνικῶν τοὺς Ἰνδοὺς ἀγώγιμα ἄλλα ἀνταλλάσσεσθαι, νόμισμα δὲ οὐκ ἐπίστασθαι, καὶ ταῦτα χρυσοῦ τε ἀφθόνου καὶ χαλκοῦ παρόντος σφίσι.

    ‘On this road the Lacedaemonians have, as I have already said, what is called the Booneta, which once was the house of their king Polydorus. When he died, they bought it from his widow, paying the price in oxen. For at that time there was as yet neither silver nor gold coinage, but they still bartered in the old way with oxen, slaves, and uncoined silver and gold. Those who sail to India say that the natives give other merchandise in exchange for Greek cargoes, knowing nothing about coinage, and that though they have plenty of gold and of bronze.’

  43. 43.

    For the references to the text of the PME, I used here the version of Casson 1989. For a complete overview on the nature and problems of this text, see now Boussac et al. 2012.

  44. 44.

    PME 39.

  45. 45.

    Casson 1989: 75.

  46. 46.

    PME 49.

  47. 47.

    PME 56.

  48. 48.

    An updated and amended catalogue of all the Roman coins found in India is still missing. So far, the best available accounts are Turner 1989 and Suresh 2003.

  49. 49.

    Nappo 2018 for the full description of the case study.

  50. 50.

    PME, 49. Transl. Casson (1989: 81). Note that the Greek text has the word ‘denarion’ which Casson (with reason) takes as meaning generally ‘Roman coin.’

  51. 51.

    First published in Senart 1905/1906: n. 12, 82–85. For amendments and intepretations, see Lüders 1912: n. 1132; Mirashi 1981: n. 38, 95–100; MacDowall 1991: 151–152.

  52. 52.

    Rapson 1908: clxxxiv; Altekar 1940: 4–5; MacDowall 1996: 92; MacDowall 2003: 43–44. Contra Bhandrkar (1921: 191–192), who assumed a gold:silver ratio of 1:14. A different opinion is now in De Romanis (2020: 327–332), although it is not really clear to me what the ratio should be, according to him.

  53. 53.

    Butcher and Ponting 2015: 451.

  54. 54.

    It is indeed true, as pointed out by De Romanis (2020: 328) that the Periplus explicitly talks of gold and silver coins to be traded in Barygaza, but the corpus of Roman coins found in India, so far, does not endorse such claim. For the inaccuracies of the Periplus, see Arnaud 2012, more precisely page 40 for the problems with the area of Barygaza.

  55. 55.

    That is how I interpret the words ἐπικέρδειάν τινα used by the Periplus.

  56. 56.

    Eatwell et al. 2000: 100.

  57. 57.

    See De Romanis (2020: 59–80) for a detailed description of the timing of the Indian commercial enterprises.

  58. 58.

    On the economic implication of the risk of wrecking, see Harris 2019a. See also Duncan-Jones (1990: 47), referring to Fronto assessing the high risk of shipwreck embedded in sea-transport.

  59. 59.

    Bang 2008: 4–5.

  60. 60.

    Pace De Romanis 2020: 332.

  61. 61.

    Bresson 2015: 382–384 reports a case for arbitrage happening between the city of Athens and grain traders, in the second half of the fourth century BC.

  62. 62.

    RIC 2.207.

  63. 63.

    RIC 2.25.

  64. 64.

    Sutherland and Carson 1984: 97.

  65. 65.

    Turner 1989: 21.

  66. 66.

    Bolin 1958: 73. See also Burnett 1998: 181–182.

  67. 67.

    Crawford 1979: 207–218. It should be noted that his idea of a significant involvement of the imperial entourage in the trade is overall confirmed by the documentary sources. See Sidebotham 1986.

  68. 68.

    Cobb 2018c: 259.

  69. 69.

    MacDowall 1991: 146–147; MacDowall 1996: 83.

  70. 70.

    MacDowall 1996, 2003, 2003b.

  71. 71.

    Suresh 2003: 29. See also the discussion in Lo Cascio (1980: 445–470) on the effects of Gresham’s Law after Nero’s devaluation of the denarius. Lo Cascio points out that denarii from Augustus, Tiberius, Caligula, and Claudius are rare in the hoards during the Flavian era: according to him, the best coins must have either been melted down or sent abroad for trade.

  72. 72.

    Tac., Ann., 3.53; Pliny, NH, 6.85.

  73. 73.

    Duncan-Jones 1994: 121.

  74. 74.

    Strab. 17.1.7.

  75. 75.

    De Romanis 2020: 127–132.

  76. 76.

    For the text, see above, n. 38.

  77. 77.

    Strab. 17.1.7: ταύτῃ δὲ καὶ τὰ ἐκκομιζόμενα ἐξ Ἀλεξανδρείας πλείω τῶν εἰσκομιζομένων ἐστί: γνοίη δ᾽ ἄν τις ἔν τε τῇ Ἀλεξανδρείᾳ καὶ τῇ Δικαιαρχείᾳ γενόμενος, ὁρῶν τὰς ὁλκάδας ἔν τε τῷ κατάπλῳ καὶ ἐν ταῖς ἀναγωγαῖς ὅσον βαρύτεραί τε καὶ κουφότεραι δεῦρο κἀκεῖσε πλέοιεν.

  78. 78.

    Duncan-Jones 1994: 118–123.

  79. 79.

    De Romanis 2012 and 2020. For a more traditional interpretation of the Pompeian evidence, see Lo Cascio 1980.

  80. 80.

    See Ménard and Shirley 2018 for an up-to-date discussion of this issue. In particular, see the chapter of Terpstra 2018 in the book, on NIE and the ancient economy. See also Blanton IV and Hollander 2019: 14–18.

  81. 81.

    Coase 1937: 390.

  82. 82.

    Coase 1960: 15; Kehoe et al. 2015: 5–7.

  83. 83.

    Coase 1992: 716.

  84. 84.

    North 1990: 27.

  85. 85.

    Tchernia 2016: 91–96; Lo Cascio 2018.

  86. 86.

    There are many works which carefully explain the most evident issues with the NIE model. For an example of a severe and ideologically motivated criticism, see Boldizzoni 2011; for an alternative view, see Verboven 2015b.

  87. 87.

    The topic of the natural inclination of men to trade, as well as the possibility of using the concept of ‘market economy’ to usefully describe any economic system are very sensitive ones. There is a rich and very heated debate going on these subjects. See for instance Temin 2013, who advocates for the presence of a strong integrated market economy in the Roman World; Bang 2008 for a completely opposite view on the topic.

  88. 88.

    A classic exposition of how the burden of transaction costs would have weighted pre-modern economies is in North and Thomas 1973.

  89. 89.

    Kehoe et al. 2015: 9, adapted from Allen 1991.

  90. 90.

    For more theoretical thinking on this, see Lo Cascio 2006: 219; 2018: 118–120.

  91. 91.

    Quotation from North 1991: 97. On the same subject, see also North 1981.

  92. 92.

    It should be noted as well that the definition of institution went through evolution and revision in the thinking of D. North. On the subject, see Wallis 2014.

  93. 93.

    Even the existence of a proper “Commercial Law” within the Empire is a hotly debated problem. See Cerami, Di Porto, and Petrucci 2004; Aubert 2015; Sirks 2018.

  94. 94.

    See Hollander 2015 (especially pages 148–155) for an overview of the main private institutions devised to overcome transaction costs by Roman traders.

  95. 95.

    I think that Cobb (2018a, b, c: 259) has come to a very similar conclusion, pointing out that these types of coin were selected for the confidence they would inspire on those receiving them. Cobb does not however link this practice to the concept of institution.

  96. 96.

    Harrauer and Sijpesteijn 1985: 124–155; Thür 1987: 229–245; 1988: 227–233; Casson 1986: 73–79; 1990: 195–206; Foraboschi and Gara 1989: 280–282; De Romanis 2006: 183–196; 1998: 11–60; 2010/11: 75–101; 2014: 73–90; 2017; Rathbone 2000: 39–50; 2002: 179–198; Morelli 2011: 199–236; De Romanis 2020.

  97. 97.

    The papyrus was bought in 1980 for the Austrian National Library, but its provenance is unfortunately unknown. See Rathbone 2000: 39.

  98. 98.

    On Pattanam-Muziris, see Cherian 2007, 2008, 2009; Cherian et al. 2009.

  99. 99.

    On the importance of familiar and friendly ties in ancient trade, see Verboven 2002. Also, Harris 2019b.

  100. 100.

    See Hollander 2007: 104–111; Kay 2014: 143–144, and 314–318; Terpstra 2019: 4–8.

  101. 101.

    Bang 2008: 140.

Bibliography

  • Akerlof, G. 1970. The Market for ‘Lemons’. Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, D.W. 1991. What Are Transaction Costs. Research in Law and Economics 14: 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altekar, A.S. 1940. The Relative Prices of Metals and Coins in Ancient India. The Journal of the Numismatic Society of India 2: 1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreau, J., and J. Maucourant. 1999. À propos de la rationalité économique dans l’Antiquité gréco-romaine. Une interprétation des thèses de D. Rathbone (1991). Topoi 9 (1): 47–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnaud, P. 2012. Le Periplus Maris Erythraei: une oeuvre de compilation aux préoccupations géographiques. Topoi Suppl. 11: 27–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert, J.-J. 2015. Trade. In The Cambridge Companion to Roman Law, ed. D. Johnston, 213–245. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ball, W. 2000. Rome in the East. The Transformation of an Empire. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bang, P.F. 2008. The Roman Bazaar. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012. A Forum on Trade. Bazaars, Empires, and Roman Trade, in Scheidel 2012, 296–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bang, P.F., and D. Kołodziejczyk. 2012. Universal Empire. A Comparative Approach to Imperial Culture and Representation in Eurasian History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bhandarkar, D.R. 1921. Lectures on Ancient Indian Numismatics. Kolkata: The University of Calcutta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanton IV, T.R., and D.B. Hollander. 2019. The Extramercantile Economy, in Hollander, Blanton IV and Fitzgerald, 8–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boer, R., and C. Petterson. 2017. Time of Troubles. A New Economic Framework for Early Christianity. Minneapolis: Fortress Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boldizzoni, F. 2011. The Poverty of Clio. Resurrecting Economic History. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bolin, S. 1958. State and Currency in the Roman Empire to 300 AD. Stockholm: Almqvist and Wiksell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boussac, M.-Fr., J.-Fr. Salles, and J.-B. Yon. 2012. Autour du Périple de la mer Érythrée. Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016. Ports of the Ancient Indian Ocean. New Delhi: Primus Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowman, A., and A. Wilson. 2009. Quantifying the Roman Economy. Methods and Problems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Braudel, F. 1979. Civilisation Matérielle, Économie et Capitalisme, XVe–XVIIIe siècle. Paris: Armand Colin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bresson, A. 2000. La cité marchande. Pessac: Ausonius Éditions.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015. The Making of the Ancient Greek Economy: Institutions, Markets, and Growth in the City-States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Burnett, A. 1998. Roman Coins from India and Sri Lanka. In Origin, Evolution and Circulation of Foreign Coins in the Indian Ocean, ed. O. Bopearachi and D.P.M. Weerakkody, 179–189. Manohar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Butcher, K., and M. Ponting. 2015. The Metallurgy of Roman Silver Coinage: From the Reform of Nero to the Reform of Trajan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cartledge, P. 1998. The Economy (Economies) of Ancient Greece. Dialogos 5: 4–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casson, L. 1986. P.Vindob. G. 40822 and the Shipping of the Goods from India. BASP 23: 73–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1989. The Periplus Maris Erythraei: Text with Introduction, Translation, and Commentary. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1990. New Light on Maritime Loans: P. Vindob. G. 40.822. ZPE 84: 195–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerami, P., A. Di Porto, and A. Petrucci. 2004. Diritto Commerciale Romano. Profilo Storico. 2nd ed. Turin: Giappichelli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherian, P.J. 2007. The Muziris Heritage Project: Excavation at Pattanam – 2007. Journal of Indian Ocean Archaeology 4: 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2008. The Muziris Heritage Project and the Archaeological Research at Pattanam: An Overview. In The Living Dead and the Lost Knowledge, 5–20. Thiruvananthapuram.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. The Exchanges between Early Historic Ports on the Malabar Coast and the Red Sea Port of Berenike. Mumbai.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherian, P.J., G.V. Ravi Prasad, K. Dutta, D.K. Ray, V. Selvakumar, and K.P. Shajan. 2009. Chronology of Pattanam: A Multi-Cultural Port Site on the Malabar Coast. Current Science 97 (2): 236–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4: 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1992. The Institutional Structure of Production. The American Economic Review 82 (4): 713–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cobb, M. 2015a. The Chronology of Roman Trade in the Indian Ocean from Augustus to Early Third Century. JESHO 58 (3): 362–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cobb, M.A. 2015b. Balancing the Trade: Roman Cargo Shipments to India. OJA 34 (2): 185–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2018a. The Indian Ocean Trade in Antiquity. London/New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2018b. The Indian Ocean in Antiquity and Global History, in Cobb 2018a, 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2018c. Rome and the Indian Ocean Trade from Augustus to the Early Third Century CE. Leiden/Boston: Brill.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, S. 2016. What is Global History? Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, M. 1980. Economia Imperiale e Commercio Estero. In Tecnologia, Economia e società nel Mondo Romano: Atti del Convegno di Como, 27–29 Settembre 1979, Como, 207–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Romanis, F. 1982-87. Roma e i Nótia dell’India, ricerche sui rapporti tra Roma e l’India dravidica dal 30 a.C. all’età Flavia. Helikon 22–27: 143–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. Cassia Cinnamomo Ossidiana. Rome: L’Erma di Bretschneider.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1998. Commercio, metrologia, fiscalità. Su P. Vindob. G 40822 Verso. MEFRA 110: 11–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. Aurei after the Trade: Western Taxes and Eastern Gifts. In Dal Denarius al Dinar. L’Oriente e la Moneta Romana, ed. F. De Romanis and S. Sorda, 55–82. Rome.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010/11. Playing Sudoku on the verso of the Muziris papyrus: pepper, malabathron and tortoise shell in the cargo of the Hermapollon. Journal of Ancient Indian History 27: 75–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012. Julio-Claudian Denarii and Aurei in Campania and India. AIIN 58: 161–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Time to repay a maritime loan: A Note on SB III 7169 and SB XVIII 1367 Recto. Sileno 40: 73–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. A Muziris Export: Schidai or Ivory Trimmings. In Imperial Rome, Indian Ocean Regions and Muziris: Recent Researches and New Perspectives on Maritime Trade. Proceedings of the International Seminar Held at Irinjalakuda, Kerala, India 8-12 September 2013, ed. K.S. Mathew, 369–380. London/New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2020. The Indo-Roman Pepper Trade and the Muziris Papyrus. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan-Jones, R. 1990. Structure and Scale in the Roman Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1994. Money and Government in the Roman Empire. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eatwell, J., M. Milgate, and P. Newman. 2000. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 1–4. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erdkamp, P. 2015. Structural Determinants of Economic Performance in the Roman World and Early Modern Europe. A Comparative Approach, in Erdkamp and Verboven 2015, 17–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erdkamp, P., and K. Verboven. 2015. Structure and Performance in the Roman Economy. Models, Methods and Case Studies. Bruxelles: Editions Latomus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finley, M.I. 1985. Ancient History: Evidence and Models. London: Pimlico.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foraboschi, D., and A. Gara. 1989. Le direttrici del commercio alessandrino. Quaderni Ticinesi di Numismatica e Antichità Classiche 18: 280–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederiksen, M.W. 1975. Theory, Evidence, and the Ancient Economy. Journal of Roman Studies 65: 164–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garnsey, P., K. Hopkins, and C.R. Whittaker, eds. 1983. Trade in the Ancient Economy. London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbon, E. 1776–1789. The History of the Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire. London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurukkal, R. 2016. Rethinking Classical Indo-Roman Trade. Political Economy and Eastern Mediterranean Exchange Relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Harrauer, H., and P. Sijpesteijn. 1985. Ein neues Dokument zu Roms Indienhandel, P. Vindob. G 40822. Anzeiger der Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, Phil.-Hist. Klasse 122: 124–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, W.V. 1993. Between Archaic and Modern: Problems in Roman Economic History. In The Inscribed Economy: Production and Distribution in the Roman Empire in the Light of Instrumentum Domesticum: The Proceedings of a Conference Held at the American Academy in Rome on 10-11 January, 1992, ed. Id, 11–29. Ann Arbor.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. Rome’s Imperial Economy. Twelve Essays. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2019a. A Strange Fact about Shipboard Coin Hoards Throws Light on the Roman Empire’s Financial System. Athenaeum 107.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2019b. Credit-Money in the Roman Economy. Klio 101 (1): 158–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. 1969. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hingley, R. 2005. Globalizing Roman Culture: Unity, Diversity and Empire. London/New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hollander, D.B. 2007. Money in the Late Roman Republic. Leiden: Brill.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015. Risky Business: Traders in the Roman World. In Traders in the Ancient Mediterranean, ed. T. Howe, 141–172. Chicago: Ares Publishers Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hollander, D.B., T.R. Blanton IV, and J.T. Fitzgerald. 2019. The Extramercantile Economies of Greek and Roman Cities. New Perspectives on the Economic History of Classical Antiquity. London/New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins, K. 1983. Introduction, in Garnsey, Hopkins and Whittaker 1983, ix–xxv.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jennings, J. 2011. Globalizations and the Ancient World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, D.W. 2014. Economic Theory and the Ancient Mediterranean. Chichester: Wiley Blackwell.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jongman, W.M. 2014. Re-constructing the Roman Economy. In The Cambridge History of Capitalism. Volume I. The Rise of Capitalism: From Ancient Origins to 1848, ed. L. Neal and J.G. Williamson, 75–100. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Kay, P. 2014. Rome’s Economic Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, D.P., D.M. Ratzan, and U. Yiftach. 2015. Law and Transaction Costs in the Ancient Economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • LaBianca, Ø.S., and S.A. Scham. 2006. Connectivity in Antiquity. Globalization as a Long-Term Historical Process. London: Equinox.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo Cascio, E. 1980. La riforma monetaria di Nerone: l’evidenza dei ripostigli. MEFRA 92: 445–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. The Role of the State in the Roman Economy: Making Use of the New Institutional Economics. In Ancient Economies Modern Methodologies, ed. P.F. Bang, M. Ikeguchi, and H.G. Ziche, 215–234. Bari: Edipuglia.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2007. The Early Roman Empire: The State and the Economy, in Scheidel, Morris, and Saller 2007, 619–647.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. Crescita e Declino: Studi di storia dell’economia romana. Roma: L’Erma di Bretschneider.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2018. Market Regulation and Transaction Costs in the Roman Empire, in Wilson and Bowman 2018, 117–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Löfgren, K.-G., T. Persson, and J.W. Weibull. 2002. Markets with Asymmetric Information: The Contributions of George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 104 (2): 195–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lüders, H. 1912. A List of Brahmi Inscriptions from the Earliest Times to about AD 400 with the Exception of those of Asoka. Epigraphica Indica 10: 1–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacDowall, D.W. 1991. Indian Imports of Roman Silver Coins. In Coinage Trade and Economy, ed. A.K. Jha, 145–163. Maharashtra: Indian Institute of Research in Numismatic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1996. The Evidence of the Gazetteer of Roman Artefacts in India. In Tradition and Archaeology: Early Maritime Contacts in the Indian Ocean, ed. H.P. Ray and J.-F. Salles, 79–95. Lyon/New Delhi.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2003a. Foreign Coins found in India. In Foreign Coins Found in the Indian Subcontinent, ed. D.W. MacDowall and A. Jha, 9–14. Maharashtra: Indian Institute of Research in Numismatic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2003b. The Indo-Roman Metal Trade. In Foreign Coins Found in the Indian Subcontinent, ed. D.W. MacDowall and A. Jha, 39–44. Maharashtra: Indian Institute of Research in Numismatic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning, J.G. 2018. The Open Sea. The Economic Life of the Ancient Mediterranean World from the Iron Age to the Rise of Rome. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Manzo, A., C. Zazzaro, and D.J. De Falco. 2018. Stories of Globalisation. The Red Sea and the Persian Gulf from Late Prehistory to Early Modernity. Brill, Leiden and Boston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. 1973. Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy. Trans. M. Nicolaus. Harmondsworth.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2002. Pre-Capitalist Economic Formations, ed. E. Hobsbawn. Geneve.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathew, K.S. 2016. Imperial Rome, Indian Ocean Regions and Muziris: New Perspectives on Maritime Trade. London/New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McLaughlin, R. 2010. The Roman Empire and the Indian Ocean. Barnsley.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016. The Roman Empire and the Silk Routes. The Ancient World Economy and the Empires of Parthia, Central Asia and Han China. Pen and Sword, Barnsley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meikle, S. 2002. Modernism, Economics and the Ancient Economy. In The Ancient Economy, ed. W. Scheidel and S. von Reden, 233–250. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ménard, C., and M.M. Shirley. 2018. A Research Agenda for New Institutional Economics. Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mirashi, V.V. 1981. The History and Inscriptions of the Sātavāhanas and the Western Kshatrapas. Maharashtra State Board for Literature and Culture, Mumbai.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morelli, F. 2011. Dal Mar Rosso ad Alessandria. Il verso (ma anche il recto) del ‘papiro di Muziris’ (SB XVIII 13167). Tyche 26: 199–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morley, N. 2004. Theories, Models and Concepts in Ancient History. London/New York: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2007. Trade in Classical Antiquity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. Antiquity and Modernity. London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris, I. 1994. The Athenian Economy Twenty Years after the Ancient Economy. Classical Philology 89: 351–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, I., and W. Scheidel, eds. 2009. The Dynamics of Ancient Empires. State Power from Assyria to Byzantion. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nappo, D. 2018. Money and Flows of Coinage in the Red Sea Trade, in Wilson and Bowman 2018, 557–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicolet, C. 1982. Il Pensiero Economico dei Romani. In Storia delle Idee Politiche, Economiche, Sociali, ed. L. Firpo, 877–960. Turin.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D.C. 1981. Structures and Changes in Economic History. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1991. Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives 5: 97–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D.C., and R.P. Thomas. 1973. The Rise of the Western World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pitts, M., and M.J. Versluys. 2015. Globalisation and the Roman World. World History, Connectivity and Material Culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Power, T. 2012. The Red Sea from Byzantium to the Caliphate. AD 500-1000. Cairo: American University in Cairo Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rapson, E.J. 1908. Catalogue of the Coins of the Andhra Dynasty, the Western Kṣatrapas, the Traikūṭaka Dynasty, and the ‘Bodhi’ Dynasty. London: British Museum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raschke, M.G. 1978. New Studies in Roman Commerce with the East. In Aufstieg und Niedergang der Römischen Welt 2.9, 604–1076. Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rathbone, D. 2000. The ‘Muziris’ Papyrus (SB XVIII 13167): Financing Roman Trade with India. BSAA 46: 39–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rathbone, D.W. 2002. Koptos the emporion. Economy and society, I–III AD. In Autour de Coptos. Actes du colloque organisé au Musée des Beaux-Arts de Lyon, ed. M.-F. Boussac, 179–198. Lyon: Topoi.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rostovtzeff, M.I. 1926. A History of the Ancient World. Vol. I. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1957. The Social and Economic History of the Roman Empire. 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W. 2009. Rome and China. Comparative Perspectives on Ancient World Empires. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012a. The Cambridge Companion to the Roman Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012b. Approaching the Roman Economy, in Id. 2012, 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015. State Power in Ancient China and Rome. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W., I. Morris, and R. Saller. 2007. The Cambridge Economic History of the Greco-Roman World. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Seland, E. 2008. The Indian Ocean and the Globalisation of the Ancient World. Ancient West and East 7: 67–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010. Ports and Political Power in the Periplus: Complex Societies and Maritime Trade on the Indian Ocean in the First Century AD. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Archaeology of Trade in the Western Indian Ocean, 300 BC-AD 700. Journal of Archaeological Research 22: 367–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senart, E. 1905/1906. The Inscriptions in the Caves at Nâsik. Epigraphica Indica 8: 59–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidebotham, S.E. 1986. Roman Economic Policy in the Erythra Thalassa. 30 B.C.–A.D. 217. Leiden: Brill.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. Berenike and the Ancient Maritime Spice Route. Los Angeles: University of California Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sirks, B. 2018. Law, Commerce, and Finance in the Roman Empire, in Wilson and Bowman 2018, 53–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. 1989. Markets, Market Failures, and Development. American Economic Review 79: 197–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suresh, S. 2003. Symbols of Trade. New Delhi.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutherland, C.H.V. and Carson, R.A.G. 1984. Roman Imperial Coinage Vol. I: From 31 BC to AD 69 - Augustus to Vitellius. London: Spink.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tchernia, A. 2016. The Romans and Trade. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Temin, P. 2001. A Market Economy in the Early Roman Empire. Journal of Roman Studies 91: 169–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2013. The Roman Market Economy, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Terpstra, T. 2018. Neo-Institutionalism in Ancient Economic History: The Road Ahead, in Ménard and Shirley 2018, 233–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2019. Trade in the Ancient Mediterranean. Private Order and Public Institutions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Thür, G. 1987. Hypotheken-Urkunde eines Seedarlehens für eine Reise nach Muziris und Apographe für die Tetarte in Alexandria. Tyche 2: 229–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1988. Zum Seedarlehen κατὰ Μουζεῖριν. Tyche 3: 227–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, P.J. 1989. Roman Coins from India. London: Royal Numismatic Soc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verboven, K. 2002. The Economy of Friends: Economic Aspects of Amicitia and Patronage in the Late Republic. Bruxelles: Latomus.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015a. Models or Muddles? What are Theories Good for in Ancient Economic History? in Erdkamp and Verboven 2015: 9–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015b. The Knights who Say NIE. Can Neo-Institutional Economics Live up to Its Expectation in Ancient History Research?, in Erdkamp and Verboven 2015, 33–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veyne, P. 1979. Rome devant la prétendue fuite de l’or: Mercantilisme ou politique disciplinaire? Annales ESC 34 (2): 211–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vivenza, G. 2012. Roman Economic Thought, in Scheidel 2012, 25–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, J.J. 2014. Persistence and Change in Institutions. The Evolution of Douglass C. North. In Institutions, Property Rights, and Economic Growth. The Legacy of Douglass North, ed. S. Galiani and I. Sened, 30–49. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Warmington, E.H. 1928. The Commerce between the Roman Empire and India. 1st ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Warmington, E. H. 1974. The Commerce between the Roman Empire and India. 2nd rev. ed. Curzon Press, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wheeler, R.E.M. 1976. My Archaeological Mission to India and Pakistan. London: Thames & Hudson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, A. 2009. Approaches to Quantifying Roman Trade, in Bowman and Wilson 2009, 213–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, A., and A. Bowman. 2018. Trade, Commerce and the State in the Roman World. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, G.K. 2001. Rome’s Eastern Trade. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuiderhoek, A. 2019. Benefactors, Markets, and Trust in the Roman East, in Hollander, Blanton IV, and Fitzgerald 2019, 51–62.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Nappo, D. (2021). A Case of Arbitrage in a Worldwide Trade: Roman Coins in India. In: Rosillo-López, C., García Morcillo, M. (eds) Managing Information in the Roman Economy. Palgrave Studies in Ancient Economies. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-54100-2_12

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-54100-2_12

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-54099-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-54100-2

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics