Abstract
Development economics is a new sub-discipline in modern economics. Its first generation, the Structuralism, focused on market failures and advised the government to adopt import-substitution strategy to develop modern industries. Its second generation, the Neoliberalism, focused on government failures and advised the government to implement Washington Consensus reform with a shock therapy to transit to a well-functioning market system. Developing countries, following the Structuralism and Neoliberalism, failed to achieve development and transition successfully. This chapter introduces the third generation of development economics, the New Structural Economics, which emphasizes the endogeneity of structure for countries at different levels of development and provides pragmatic guide to formulate industrial policy for accelerating economic development. This chapter calls for a structural revolution in modern economics.
Access this chapter
Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout
Purchases are for personal use only
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
- 1.
“White elephants” refers to assets or firms which are very costly to maintain but generate output of low value, so that they fail to make a profit.
- 2.
The widening of income gap between developed and developing countries after the Second World War does not mean that there has been no improvement of income and living standards in developing countries. Rather, it means that the average annual per capita GDP growth rate in developing countries was less than the average annual per capita GDP growth rate of 2% per year in high-income countries over last 100 years (Maddison 1995).
- 3.
Old Structuralism, or early development economics, has been described in the previous section.
- 4.
One of the major differences between New Structural Economics (NSE) and Neoclassical Economics is the role of the state in industrial upgrading. NSE advocates the adoption by the state of a facilitating role to compensate for the first mover’s externality and to coordinate/provide necessary improvements in hard and soft infrastructure for the industries of new comparative advantages determined by the changing endowment structure. In contrast, Neoclassical Economics shies away from the state’s proactive role in facilitating structural transformation because of concerns about rent-seeking and state capacity. NSE develops a Growth Identification and Facilitation Framework (GIFF) to identify industries of latent comparative advantages and infrastructure bottlenecks and advises governments on how to turn latent comparative advantages into competitive advantages in a pragmatic way, which can be followed by a state with any capacity and does not generate distortions and rent-seeking (Lin 2017; Lin and Monga 2011). See also the discussion in Sect. 4.
- 5.
The state’s removal of bottlenecks in hard and soft infrastructure to reduce transaction costs for the new industries will not cause distortions and generate rents, so that rent-seeking can be avoided.
References
Arndt, H. W. (1985). The Origin of Structuralism. World Development, 13(2), 151–159.
Brady, D. H., & Spence, M. (2010). The Ingredients of Growth. Stanford Social Innovation Review, 8(2), 34–39.
Commission on Growth and Development. (2008). Growth Report: Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Easterly, W. (2001). The Lost Decades: Developing Countries’ Stagnation in Spite of Policy Reform 1980–1998. Journal of Economic Growth, 6, 135–157.
Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective, a Book of Essays. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Gruber, J., & Johnson, S. (2019). How Breakthrough Science Can Revive Economic Growth and the American Dream. New York: PublicAffairs.
Ju, J., Lin, J. Y., & Wang, Y. (2015). Endowment Structures, Industrial Dynamics, and Economic Growth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 76, 244–263.
Keynes, J. M. (1935 [1964]). The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World.
Krueger, A. O. (1997). Trade Policy and Economic Development: How We Learn. American Economic Review, 87(1), 1–22.
Kuznets, S. (1966). Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure and Speed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Lal, D. (1983). The Poverty of ‘Development Economics’. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Leibenstein, H. (1966). Allocative Efficiency vs. X-Efficiency. American Economic Review, 56(3), 392–415.
Lin, J. Y. (2009). Economic Development and Transition: Thought, Strategy, and Viability. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Lin, J. Y. (2011). New Structural Economics: A Framework for Rethinking Economic Development. The World Bank Observer, 26, 193–221.
Lin, J. Y. (2013a). Demystifying the Chinese Economy. The Australian Economic Review, 46, 259–268.
Lin, J. Y. (2013b). Global Infrastructure Initiative and Global Recovery. Journal of Policy Modeling, 35(3), 400–411.
Lin, J. Y. (2016). The Latecomer Advantages and Disadvantages: A New Structural Economics Perspective. In M. Andersson & T. Axelsson (Eds.), Diverse Development Paths and Structural Transformation in Escape from Poverty (pp. 43–67). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lin, J. Y. (2017). Industrial Policies for Avoiding the Middle-income Trap: A New Structural Economics Perspective. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies, 15(1), 5–18.
Lin, J. Y., & Monga, C. (2011). Growth Identification and Facilitation: The Role of State in the Process of Dynamic Growth. Development Policy Review, 29(3), 264–290; “Rejoinder”: 304–309.
Lin, J. Y., Sun, X., & Jiang, Y. (2013). Endowment, Industrial Structure and Appropriate Financial Structure: A New Structural Economics Perspective. Journal of Economic Policy Reform, 16(2), 1–14.
Lin, J. Y., & Tan, G. (1999). Policy Burdens, Accountability, and the Soft Budget Constraint. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 89(2), 426–431.
Lin, J. Y., & Wang, Y. (2017). Going Beyond Aid: Development Cooperation for Structural Transformation. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Maddison, A. (1995). Monitoring the World Economy, 1820–1992. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Mazzucato, M. (2011). The Entrepreneurial State. London: Demos.
Murphy, K., Schleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1992). The Tradition to a Market Economy: Pitfall of Partial Reform. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 889–906.
Pomeranz, K. (2000). The Great Divergence: China, Europe and the Making of Modern World. Princeton University Press.
Prebisch, R. (1950). The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems. New York: United Nations.
Pritchett, L. (1997). Divergence, Big Time. Journal of Economic Perspective, 11(3), 3–17.
Rodrik, D. (2011). The Future of Economic Convergence. NBER Working Paper #17400.
Rodrik, D. (2016). Premature Deindustrialization. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(1), 1–33.
Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–S102.
Rosenstein-Rodan, P. N. (1943). Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe. Economic Journal, 53, 202–211.
Williamson, J. (1990). What Washington Means by Policy Reform. In J. Williamson (Ed.), Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Editor information
Editors and Affiliations
Rights and permissions
Copyright information
© 2021 The Author(s)
About this chapter
Cite this chapter
Lin, J.Y. (2021). Economic Development, Transition, and New Structural Economics. In: Douarin, E., Havrylyshyn, O. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Comparative Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-50888-3_21
Download citation
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-50888-3_21
Published:
Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham
Print ISBN: 978-3-030-50887-6
Online ISBN: 978-3-030-50888-3
eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)