Abstract
In order to shed light on the patterns of economic development characterized by sustained growth and persistent wealth inequality, we develop an agent-based model in which generations overlap and parents leave bequests to offspring. The model shows how neighborhood effects influence the long-run trajectory of human capital investments and wealth distribution. The analyses proceed in three steps. First, we implement the agent-based version of an overlapping generations model, enabling validation of our baseline simulations. Second, we introduce direct, local interactions to demonstrate how human capital investments and inequality respond to neighborhood effects. As far as we know, our study is among the first to explore the impact of local interactions on wealth inequality in an agent-based model with intergenerational transfers. Finally, we show how local interactions can influence the efficacy of policies that aim to generate an equitable distribution of wealth. The main results indicate that human capital is highest when local interactions are moderate, that is, neither too weak nor too strong. At the optimal level, either higher- or lower-intensity interactions would reduce aggregate human capital and therefore output. The distributional impact exhibits a similar pattern albeit with very different ramifications. Specifically, the moderate interactions that maximize output also generate the most unequal distribution of wealth. An exogenous shock leading to a more cohesive community lowers output but produces a more equitable distribution. By contrast, weak interactions precipitate a mild output contraction and, at the same time, significantly lower wealth inequality. The agent-based simulations thus suggest diametrically opposed responses of output and equity to changes in the intensity of local interactions. The agent-based model developed for this study offers the potential to improve our understanding of the complex interplay between human capital, intergenerational transfers, and neighborhood effects.
Access this chapter
Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout
Purchases are for personal use only
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
- 1.
See the extensive survey in Card (1999).
- 2.
ABM is also known as Agent-based Computational Economics (ACE) (Tesfatsion 2005). Tesfatsion stressed the importance of ACE in dealing with complicated micro-behavior in real world (e.g., asymmetric information, imperfect information, and multiple equilibria).
- 3.
The formulation (known as Cobb-Douglas) of the production function belongs to the general class of concave functions that GZ use in a more abstract setting. Because our model is computational, we need to specify a functional form so that the algorithm can compute the numerical values of output. The Cobb-Douglas formulation is chosen because it remains the most ubiquitous form of production function in today’s theoretical and empirical analyses of output growth (Felipe and Adams 2005).
- 4.
GZ assume endogenous wages for unskilled workers for their purely mathematical treatment. For a numerical model like ours, fixing unskilled wages while permitting skilled ones to vary as a “free” variable allows the simulations to be initialized much more efficiently.
- 5.
We use Repast library version 3.1, developed by North et al. (2006). Repast is a free open source toolkit and available at Repast homepage at https://repast.sourceforge.net/repast_3/index.html (Road 2004).
- 6.
This restriction is necessary in order to prevent the economy from spiraling out of control.
- 7.
See Sen (1997) for historical perspectives and mathematical treatment.
- 8.
It turns out that results of the subsidy scenario analysis are qualitatively very similar under Setups 2 and 3.
- 9.
Results not reported here due to space considerations.
- 10.
The total expenditures would be ex-post identical only in the trivial case where every agent invests in human capital because education has been rendered affordable to all agents.
References
Andergassen, R., & Nardini, F. (2007). Educational choice, endogenous inequality and economic development. Journal of Macroeconomics, 29, 940–958.
Becker, G. S. (1964). Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education. New York: NBER.
Becker, G. S. (1991). A note on restaurant pricing and other examples of social influence on price. Journal of Political Economy, 99(5), 1109–1116.
Becker, G. S., Kominers, S. D., Murphy, K. M., & Spenkuch, J. L. (2018). A theory of intergenerational mobility. Journal of Political Economy, 126(S1), S7–S25.
Becker, G. S., & Tomes, N. (1979). An equilibrium theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility. Journal of Political Economy, 87(6), 1153–1189.
Bénabou, R. (1996). Equity and efficiency in human capital investment: The local connection. Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 237–264.
Berube, A. (2014). All cities are not created unequal. The Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/research/papers/2014/02/cities-unequal-berube/. Accessed February 22, 2014.
Bowles, S., Loury, G. C., & Sethi, R. (2014). Group inequality. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(1), 129–152.
Card, D. (1999). The causal effect of education on earnings. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (1st ed., Vol. 3A). North Holland.
Chetty, R., Hendren, N., Kline, P., & Saez, E. (2014). Where is the land of opportunity? The geography of intergenerational mobility in the United States. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(4), 1553–1623.
Chiang, A. C. (1984). Fundamental methods of mathematical economics (3rd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.
Clark, G. (2014). The son also rises: Surnames and the history of social mobility. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Corcoran, M., Gordon, R., Laren, D., & Solon, G. (1990). Effects of family and community background on economic status. The American Economic Review, 80(2), 362–366.
Das, M. (2007). Persistent inequality: An explanation based on limited parental altruism. Journal of Development Economics, 84, 251–270.
Durlauf, S. N. (1996). Neighborhood feedbacks, endogenous stratification, and income inequality. In W. Barnett, G. Gandolfo, & C. Hillinger (Eds.), Dynamic Disequilibrium Modelling: 9th International Symposium on Economic Theory and Econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Fan, C. S. (2006). Do the rich save more? A new view based on intergenerational transfers. Southern Economic Journal, 73(2), 362–373.
Felipe, J., & Adams, F. G. (2005). “A Theory of Production” The estimation of the Cobb-Douglas function: A retrospective view. Eastern Economic Journal, 31(3), 427–445.
Galor, O., & Zeira, J. (1993). Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies, 60(1), 35–52.
Glaeser, E. L., & Mare, D. C. (2001). Cities and skills. Journal of Labor Economics, 19(2), 316–342.
Glaeser, E. L., & Vigdor, J. L. (2012). The end of segregated century: Racial separation in America’s neighborhood, 1890–2010. Civic Report 66, Jan 2012. Manhattan Institute for Policy Research.
Gordon, R. J. (2013). Revisiting U.S. productivity growth over the past century with a view of the future. In D. S. P. Rao & B. V. Ark (Eds.), World economic performance: Past, present and future (p. 317). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Heckman, J. J., & Krueger, A. B. (2003). Inequality in America: What role for human capital policies. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Hicks, J. R. (1932). The theory of wages. London: Macmillan.
Howell, D. R. (2013). The great laissez-faire experiment: American inequality and growth from an international perspective. Center for American Progress. https://www.americanprogress.org/. Last visited February 2, 2014.
IMF. (2019). World economic outlook: Global manufacturing downturn, rising trade barriers. Washington, DC, October. https://www.imf.org/. Accessed December 12, 2019.
Jargowsky, P. A. (1996). Take the money and run: Economic segregation in U.S. Metropolitan Areas. American Sociological Review, 61(6), 984–998.
Kiyotaki, N., & Wright, R. (1998). On money as a medium of exchange. Journal of Political Economy, 97(4), 927–954.
Kreps, D. M. (2012). Microeconomic foundations I: Choice and competitive markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Krueger, D., Perri, F., Pistaferri, L., & Vilante, G. L. (2010). Cross-sectional facts for macroeconomists. Review of Economic Dynamics, 13(1), 1–14.
Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. The American Economic Review, 45(1), 1–28.
Mansury, Y., & Gulyas, L. (2007). The emergence of Zipf’s Law in a system of cities: An agent-based simulation approach. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 31, 2438–2460.
Mincer, J. (1958). Investment in human capital and personal income distribution. Journal of Political Economy, 66(4), 281–302.
Mookherjee, D., Napel, S., & Ray, D. (2010a). Aspiration, segregation and occupational choice. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(1), 139–168.
Mookherjee, D., Napel, S., & Ray, D. (2010b). Social interactions and segregation in skill accumulation. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(2–3), 388–400.
Moretti, E. (2004). Estimating the social return to higher education: Evidence from longitudinal and repeated cross-sectional data. Journal of Econometrics, 121, 175–212.
Nakajima, T., & Nakamura, H. (2009). The price of education and inequality. Economic Letters, 105, 183–185.
Nomura, T. (2007). Contribution of education and educational equality to economic growth. Applied Economics Letters, 14, 627–630.
North, M. J., Collier, N. T., & Vos, J. R. (2006). Experiences creating three implementations of the repast agent modeling toolkit. ACM Transactions on Modeling and Computer Simulation, 16(1), 1–25.
OECD. (2013). OECD economic outlook (Vol. 2013/2). Paris: OECD Publishing. https://www.oecd.org. Accessed February 2, 2014.
OECD. (2015). In it together: Why less inequality benefits all. Paris: OECD Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264235120-en. Accessed December 15, 2019.
Parker, D., & Filatova, T. (2008). A theoretical design for a bilateral agent-based land market with heterogeneous economic agents. Computers, Environment and Urban Systems, 32, 454–463.
Piketty, T. (2011). On the long-run evolution of inheritance: France 1820–2050. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(3), 1071–1131.
Reardon, S. F., & Bischoff, K. (2011). Income inequality and income segregation. American Journal of Sociology, 116(4), 1092–1153.
Reardon, S. F., Bischoff, K., Owens, A., & Townsend, J. B. (2018). Has income segregation really increased? Bias and bias correction in sample-based segregation estimates. Demography, 55(6), 2129–2160.
Road. (2004). Repast home page. Repast organization for architecture and design, Chicago IL. https://repast.sourceforge.net/. Accessed January 13, 2014.
Roca, J. D. L., & Puga, D. (2017). Learning by working in big cities. Review of Economic Studies, 84(1), 106–142.
Rosenthal, S. S., & Strange, W. C. (2001). The determinants of agglomeration. Journal of Urban Economics, 50, 191–229.
Saez, E., & Zucman, G. (2016). Wealth inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence from capitalized income tax data. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131(2), 519–578.
Sampson, R. J. (2012). Great American city: Chicago and the enduring neighborhood effect. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Samuelson, P. A. (1958). An exact consumption loan model of interest, with or without the social contrivance of money. Journal of Political Economy, 66(6), 467–482.
Sen, A. (1997). On economic inequality. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Schelling, T. C. (1971). Dynamic models of segregation. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 1, 143–186.
Solon, G. (2002). Cross-country differences in intergenerational earnings mobility. Journal of Economic Perspective, 16(3), 59–66.
Solon, G. (2018). What do we know so far about multigenerational mobility? The Economic Journal, 128(612), F340–F352.
Stewart, E. B., Stewart, E. A., & Simons, R. L. (2007). The effect of neighborhood context on the college aspirations of African American adolescents. American Educational Research Journal, 44(4), 896–919.
Tesfatsion, L. (2005). Agent-based computational economics: A constructive approach to economic theory. https://www2.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/ace.htm. Accessed January 8, 2014.
Usher, A., & Medow, J. (2010). Global higher education rankings 2010: Affordability and accessibility in comparative perspective. https://higheredstrategy.com/wp-content/uploads/2011/09/GHER2010_FINAL.pdf. Accessed February 13, 2014.
Walker, K. (2018). Locating neighbourhood diversity in the American metropolis. Urban Studies, 55(1), 116–132.
Wilson, W. J. (1987). The truly disadvantaged. Chicago: Chicago University Press.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Editor information
Editors and Affiliations
Rights and permissions
Copyright information
© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG
About this chapter
Cite this chapter
Wicaksono, G., Mansury, Y. (2020). An Agent-Based Model of Wealth Inequality with Overlapping Generations, Local Interactions, and Intergenerational Transfers. In: Thill, JC. (eds) Innovations in Urban and Regional Systems. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-43694-0_10
Download citation
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-43694-0_10
Published:
Publisher Name: Springer, Cham
Print ISBN: 978-3-030-43692-6
Online ISBN: 978-3-030-43694-0
eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)