Skip to main content

A Steindlian Model of Income Distribution, Economic Growth, and Stagnation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Secular Stagnation Theories

Part of the book series: Springer Studies in the History of Economic Thought ((SSHET))

  • 408 Accesses

Abstract

In line with the classical and post-Keynesian/Kaleckian tradition, in his original demand-side stagnation theory Josef Steindl focused on the functional distribution of income. In this chapter, Steindl’s twentieth-century theoretical model is adjusted to also include the personal distribution of income. The extended model includes both the profit share and a measure of the personal distribution of income. Based on a comparative static analysis, it is shown that economic shocks which lead to an increase in the unequal distribution of personal income and/or a rise in the profit share can be accompanied by a slowdown in long-term economic growth. Moreover, it is pointed out that changes in the long-term rate of economic growth feed back on both the personal and functional distribution of income.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    On the difficulty of solving delay differential equations, see also Andrews (2005, pp. 79–80, 92).

  2. 2.

    Dutt (2006), for instance, presents a Steindlian growth model which considers both demand- and supply-side effects. Hein (2014, pp. 375–440), on the other hand, refers to Kaleckian growth models which explicitly take account of financial markets and finance-dominated capitalism (see also Hein 2016, pp. 35–38).

  3. 3.

    On the importance of firms’ internal accumulation, the degree of capacity utilization, and technological progress for firms’ investment decisions, see also Guger et al. (2006, pp. 435–437).

  4. 4.

    Kaleckian and Steindlian growth models treat the degree of capacity utilization \((u)\) as an endogenous variable which, both in the short and the long run, is not necessarily equal to the planned degree of capacity utilization \((u_0)\). This characteristic has been criticized by several authors throughout the years, such as Committeri (1986), Auerbach and Skott (1988), and Skott (2012), who argue that long-run stable equilibria cannot be attained if \(u\) is not equal to \(u_0\) in the long run. Yet, as pointed out by Hein et al. (2011, 2012), for instance, deviations of \(u\) from \(u_0\) can be justified. In fact, the planned degree of capacity utilization \((u_0)\) must not be a definite, particular value, but may rather be understood as a range of values. Moreover, firms are likely to have multiple objectives, so they may accept deviations of \(u\) from \(u_0\) to reach other targets. Along similar lines, Dutt (2005, p. 68) concludes that “[...] there is no necessary inconsistency in the Steindlian framework.” See also Hein (2014, pp. 441–471) and Lavoie (2014, pp. 387–410).

  5. 5.

    Harrod (1948, pp. 22–23), when first defining his neutral technological progress, additionally assumed a constant interest rate. Given both a constant capital coefficient and a constant interest rate, Harrod-neutral technological progress is, in fact, characterized by a constant functional distribution of income. As will be shown further below, in the Steindlian model developed here, a change in the rate of technological progress alters the functional distribution of income. Hence, while technological progress as assumed in this Steindlian model involves key characteristics of Harrod neutrality, it does not completely conform to all of Harrod’s (1948, pp. 22–23) original assumptions. On the nexus between (Harrod-neutral) technological progress and the distribution of income, see also Krämer (1996, pp. 170–178, 193–196).

  6. 6.

    While the partial derivatives of \(u\), \(\pi \), and \(\psi \) with respect to \(z\) (see Eqs. D.8, D.16, and D.24 in Appendix D.1.1.1) seem to be uncertain, they are unambiguously defined if it is assumed that total profits \((R)\) are positive (see Eq. 8.12). With a positive \(R\), private households’ capital income \((Z)\) is also positive. The signs of the partial derivatives of \(u\), \(\pi \), and \(\psi \) with respect to \(z\) are given in Table 8.1.

  7. 7.

    In the opposite case of a cumulative upward spiral, the process comes to a halt when full capacity utilization is reached.

  8. 8.

    See Appendix D.1.2.1 for further details. From Eq. (8.49) and given the assumption that both \(\alpha _3\) and \(h_1\) are greater than zero (see Eqs. 8.8 and 8.10), it also follows that \(0 \,< \alpha _3h_1\, < 1\).

  9. 9.

    In the case of an unstable equilibrium, if the partial derivative of \(\mathrm {d}g/\mathrm {d} t\) with respect to an exogenous variable or parameter is negative (positive), the function in Fig. 8.1b shifts downward (upward) as well. A new equilibrium is not reached, however, as the actual growth rate \((g)\) keeps on falling (rising).

  10. 10.

    The terms profit-led growth and wage-led growth are used here following the discussion on profit-led and wage-led economic regimes in the existing literature, such as outlined in Bhaduri and Marglin (1990), Lavoie and Stockhammer (2013, p. 17), and Lavoie (2014, pp. 374–377). According to Lavoie (2014, p. 374), for instance, one can “[...] speak of a wage-led regime when an increase in real wages or the share of wages leads to a positive effect on the variable being considered [...].” Similarly, a profit-led regime exists “[...] when an increase in real wages or in the share of wages, that is, a decrease in the share of profits, leads to a negative effect on the variables under consideration [...].”

  11. 11.

    The terms equality-led and inequality-led are also used by Dutt (2017). He writes, “[...] [A]lthough wage and profit shares are indicators of inequality in many circumstances [...], the wage share it not an adequate measure of income equality. We should be more interested in the possibility of equality-led growth than wage-led growth [...]” (Dutt 2017, p. 193).

  12. 12.

    See also Skott (2017) on this issue.

  13. 13.

    As can be seen in Appendix D.1.2.2, the results in Tables 8.2 and 8.3 have been calculated by partially deriving Eq. (8.46) with respect to the model’s exogenous variables and parameters.

  14. 14.

    While the partial derivative of \(\mathrm {d}g/\mathrm {d} t\) with respect to \(z\) (see Eq. D.40 in Appendix D.1.2.2) seems to be ambiguous, it is definitely positive if it is assumed that \(R\), and hence \(Z\), is always positive (see Eq. 8.12). See also footnote 6 in Sect. 8.3.1.2.

  15. 15.

    The profit share \(\pi \, = \, m_1\, - \, m_2/u\) can be included in both Eqs. (8.51) and (8.52). While Eq. (8.51) can be written as \(W/K\, = \, (1 \, - \, \pi ) \, u\), Eq. (8.52) can be changed to \(Z/K\, = \,(1 \, - \, a_2) \, i\, + \, a_2\pi u\).

  16. 16.

    If there were no overhead labor costs, i.e., if \(m_2K\) in Eq. (8.12) were zero, \(\pi ^s\) would be a constant function with a value of \(m_1\). The \(\pi ^s\) schedule in Fig. 8.3 would thus be a horizontal line at \(\pi ^s\, = \, m_1\).

  17. 17.

    Additionally, Appendix D.2 provides a graphical analysis of a rise in the dividend payout parameter \((a_2)\), a rise in the saving rate of the rich private households \((s_h^r)\), and a decline in the parameter \(\alpha _2\).

  18. 18.

    The following graphical analysis is based on computer simulations of the functional relationships that have been outlined in the previous Sect. 8.4.1.

  19. 19.

    It should be noted that \(\alpha _3\, (h_0\, + \, h_1g)\), the term representing the impact of technological change in the \(g^d\) schedule, does not vary in the short run, as \(g\) is constant in the short run.

  20. 20.

    With a rise in \(m_1\), the \(g^d\) schedule shifts upward due to, first, the impact of \(m_1\) on \(S_f/K\) and, secondly, the impact of \(m_1\) on \(g\) in the term \(\alpha _3\, (h_0\, + \, h_1g)\). Yet, the impact of \(m_1\) on technological change, i.e., on the term \(\alpha _3\, (h_0\, + \, h_1g)\) in the \(g^d\) schedule, cannot alone shift the \(g^d\) schedule to such an extent that the \(g^s_1\) and \(g^d_1\) functions intersect at a growth rate \(g^*_1\) which lies above the original growth rate \(g^*_0\). The reason is that, according to the Keynesian stability condition, \(0 \,< \, \alpha _3h_1\, < \, 1\). Hence, considering only the impact of \(m_1\) on \(\alpha _3\, (h_0\, + \, h_1g)\), changes in \(m_1\) cannot shift the \(g^d\) function to the same extent as the \(g^s\) function. Only a strong impact of \(m_1\) on \(S_f/K\) can potentially raise the long-run equilibrium rate of real capital accumulation.

  21. 21.

    While in Fig. 8.6 \(\pi ^*_1\) is higher than \(\pi ^*_0\), it is also possible that \(\pi ^*_1\) falls below \(\pi ^*_0\).

  22. 22.

    While in Fig. 8.6 \(\psi ^*_1\) is higher than \(\psi ^*_0\), it is also possible that \(\psi ^*_1\) falls below \(\psi ^*_0\).

  23. 23.

    While in Fig. 8.8 \(\psi ^*_1\) is higher than \(\psi ^*_0\), it is also possible that \(\psi ^*_1\) falls below \(\psi ^*_0\).

  24. 24.

    In a similar context, Dutt (2017, p. 180) writes, “Examining the effects of changes in distribution (or some determinants of it) on growth does not, of course, imply that distribution is actually exogenous, but that this relation needs to be examined prior to embedding it into an enlarged model in which distribution (or its determinants) is made endogenous in the sense that growth and other related variables are allowed to affect it.”

  25. 25.

    The respective condition determining whether a rise (fall) in \(g^*\) raises or lowers \(\psi \) from the short to the long run has been outlined in Sect. 8.3.2.3 and Appendix D.1.2.2.

  26. 26.

    Graphically, in a typical \(u\)-\(\pi \)-diagram, ceteris paribus the \(\pi ^s\) schedule is steeper the lower \(g\) and \(u\). Hence, at low levels of economic activity, each rise in \(w\) and/or \(z\), which shifts the \(\pi ^d\) schedule upward, is accompanied by a relatively strong increase in the profit share \((\pi )\). Ceteris paribus, a rise in the profit share \((\pi )\) is more beneficial for the rich private households than for the poor private households.

  27. 27.

    For a systematic overview of the different economic regimes, see, for instance, Blecker (2002, p. 134). It should be noted that Bhaduri and Marglin (1990, p. 384) are solely concerned with the short run. Hence, although many growth models have originated from their seminal paper, their original model cannot be characterized as a growth model. In fact, Bhaduri and Marglin (1990) do not focus on the impact of changes in the profit and wage share on economic growth, but on output and capacity utilization (see also Dutt 2017, p. 172). Marglin and Bhaduri (1990), on the other hand, also refer to the rate of real capital accumulation. They write, “One advantage of the present model is that it is normalized in terms that permit it to be applied to the determination of equilibrium over a longer period [...]” (Marglin and Bhaduri 1990, p. 155).

  28. 28.

    For instance, if the degree of capacity utilization rises, but the profit rate remains constant, the profit share is necessarily lower than its initial value. Despite a higher degree of capacity utilization and a constant profit rate, real capital accumulation may decline if the impact of the profit share on real capital accumulation is relatively large. See also Lavoie (2014, pp. 370–371) and Blecker (2002, pp. 135–138).

  29. 29.

    As it has been defined that the measure of personal income inequality \((\psi )\) is always larger than one, \(Y_h^p\) must be lower than \(Y_h^r\), though.

References

  • Andrews M (2005) On industry concentration and the transition to monopoly capitalism: a knife-edge model of “Steindlian” dynamics. In: Mott T, Shapiro N (eds) Rethinking capitalist development: essays on the economics of Josef Steindl. Routledge, New York, NY, pp 79–94

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach P, Skott P (1988) Concentration, competition and distribution—a critique of theories of monopoly capital. Int Rev Appl Econ 2(1):42–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhaduri A, Marglin S (1990) Unemployment and the real wage: the economic basis for contesting political ideologies. Camb J Econ 14(4):375–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blecker RA (2002) Distribution, demand and growth in neo-Kaleckian macro-models. In: Setterfield M (ed) The economics of demand-led growth: challenging the supply-side vision of the long run. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and Northhampton, MA, pp 129–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Committeri M (1986) Some comments on recent contributions on capital accumulation, income distribution and capacity utilization. Polit Econ 2(2):161–186

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowling K (2005) Monopoly capitalism and stagnation. In: Mott T, Shapiro N (eds) Rethinking capitalist development: essays on the economics of Josef Steindl. Routledge, New York, NY, pp 147–163

    Google Scholar 

  • Dullien S (2017) A new, “magic square” for inclusive and sustainable economic growth: a policy framework for Germany to move beyond GDP. Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Bonn

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (1984) Stagnation, income distribution and monopoly power. Camb J Econ 8(1):25–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (1994) On the long-run stability of capitalist economies: implications of a model of growth and distribution. In: Dutt AK (ed) New directions in analytical political economy. Edward Elgar Publishing, Aldershot and Brookfield, VT, pp 93–120

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (2003) New growth theory, effective demand, and post-Keynesian dynamics. In: Salvadori N (ed) Old and new growth theories: an assessment. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham and Northampton, MA, pp 67–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (2005) Steindl’s theory of maturity and stagnation and its relevance today. In: Mott T, Shapiro N (eds) Rethinking capitalist development: essays on the economics of Josef Steindl. Routledge, New York, NY, pp 55–78

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (2006) Aggregate demand, aggregate supply and economic growth. Int Rev Appl Econ 20(3):319–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (2017) Income inequality, the wage share, and economic growth. Rev Keynes Econ 5(2):170–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ (2016) The rise and fall of American growth. The U.S. standard of living since the Civil War. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Guger A, Marterbauer M, Walterskirchen E (2006) Growth policy in the spirit of Steindl and Kalecki. Metroeconomica 57(3):428–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen AH (1939) Economic progress and declining population growth. Am Econ Rev 29(1):1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrod RF (1948) Towards a dynamic economics: some recent developments of economic theory and their application to policy. Macmillan & Co., Ltd, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hein E (2014) Distribution and growth after Keynes: a post-Keynesian guide. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and Northampton, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Hein E (2016) Secular stagnation or stagnation policy? Steindl after Summers. PSL Quarterly Rev 69(276):3–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Hein E (2017) The Bhaduri-Marglin post-Kaleckian model in the history of distribution and growth theories: an assessment by means of model closures. Rev Keynes Econ 5(2):218–238

    Google Scholar 

  • Hein E, Lavoie M, van Treeck T (2011) Some instability puzzles in Kaleckian models of growth and distribution: a critical survey. Camb J Econ 35(3):587–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hein E, Lavoie M, van Treeck T (2012) Harrodian instability and the ‘normal rate’ of capacity utilization in Kaleckian models of distribution and growth—a survey. Metroeconomica 63(1):139–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor N (1966) Causes of the slow rate of economic growth of the United Kingdom. Cambridge University Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalecki M ([1954] 1965) Theory of economic dynamics. An essay on cyclical and long-run changes in capitalist economy. Modern Reader Paperbacks, New York, NY, and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalmbach P (2000) Höhere Arbeitsmarktflexibilität oder flexiblere Wirtschaftspolitik? Zu den Ursachen der unterschiedlichen Beschäftigungsentwicklung in den USA und in Deutschland (Gutachten im Auftrag der Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung). Wirtschafts- und Sozialpolitisches Forschungs- und Beratungszentrum der Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Abteilung Wirtschaftspolitik, Bonn

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM ([1930] 1972) Economic possibilities for our grandchildren. The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol IX: essays in persuasion, Macmillan St. Martin’s Press for the Royal Economiy Society, London and Basingstoke, pp 321–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM ([1937] 1973) Some economic consequences of a declining population. In: Moggridge D (ed) The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol XIV: the general theory and after (part II: Defence and development). Macmillan St Martin’s Press for the Royal Economic Society, London and Basingstoke, pp 124–133

    Google Scholar 

  • Krämer H (1996) Bowley’s Law, Technischer Fortschritt und Einkommensverteilung: Eine methodische, empirische und theoretische Untersuchung der langfristigen funktionalen Einkommensverteilung. Metropolis-Verlag, Marburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz HD (1991) Technical change, growth and distribution: a steady-state approach to ‘unsteady’ growth on Kaldorian lines. In: Nell EJ, Semmler W (eds) Nicholas Kaldor and mainstream economics: confrontation or convergence? Macmillan, Basingstoke and London, pp 421–448

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie M (2014) Post-Keynesian economics: new foundations. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and Northampton, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie M, Stockhammer E (2013) Wage-led growth: concept, theories and policies. In: Lavoie M, Stockhammer E (eds) Wage-led growth: an equitable strategy for economic recovery. Palgrave Macmillan and International Labour Organization, London, pp 13–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Lösch A (1938) Das Problem einer Wechselwirkung zwischen Bevölkerungs- und Wirtscahfts-entwicklung. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 48(1938):454–469

    Google Scholar 

  • Marglin SA, Bhaduri A (1990) Profit squeeze and Keynesian theory. In: Marglin SA, Schor JB (eds) The golden age of capitalism: reinterpreting the postwar experience. Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp 153–186

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2012) Economic policy reforms 2012: going for growth. OECD Publishing, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Palley TI (2017) Inequality and growth in neo-Kaleckian and Cambridge growth theory. Rev Keynes Econ 5(2):146–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowthorn B (1981) Demand, real wages and economic growth. Thames Papers in Political Economy Autumn 1981

    Google Scholar 

  • Skott P (2012) Theoretical and empirical shortcomings of the Kaleckian investment function. Metroeconomica 63(1):109–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skott P (2017) Weaknesses of ‘wage-led growth’. Rev Keynes Econ 5(3):336–359

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistisches Bundesamt (2018) Overall economic equilibrium: 50th anniversary of the magic square. Statistisches Bundesamt, Wiesbaden. https://www.destatis.de/EN/FactsFigures/NationalEconomyEnvironment/NationalAccounts/MagicSquare.html. Accessed 07 Aug 2018

  • Steindl J ([1952] 1976) Maturity and stagnation in American capitalism (with a new introduction by the author). Monthly Review Press, New York, NY, and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Steindl J ([1979] 1990) Stagnation theory and stagnation policy. In: Steindl J (ed) Economic papers 1941–88. St Martin’s Press, New York, NY, pp 107–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Steindl J ([1980] 1990) Technical progress and evolution. In: Steindl J (ed) Economic papers 1941–88. St Martin’s Press, New York, NY, pp 83–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Steindl J ([1982a] 1990) Technology and the economy: the case of falling productivity growth in the 1970s. In: Steindl J (ed) Economic papers 1941–88. St Martin’s Press, New York, NY, pp 94–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Steindl J ([1984] 1990) Reflections on the present state of economics. In: Steindl J (ed) Economic papers 1941–88. St Martin’s Press, New York, NY, pp 241–252

    Google Scholar 

  • Steindl J ([1989] 1990) From stagnation in the 30s to slow growth in the 70s. In: Steindl J (ed) Economic papers 1941–88. St Martin’s Press, New York, NY, pp 166–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers LH (2014a) Reflections on the ‘new secular stagnation hypothesis’. In: Teulings C, Baldwin R (eds) Secular stagnation: facts, causes and cures. CEPR Press, London, pp 27–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers LH (2014b) US economic prospects: secular stagnation, hysteresis, and the zero lower bound. Bus Econ 49(2):65–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers LH (2016) The age of secular stagnation: what it is and what to do about it. Foreign Affairs February 15, 2016. https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/united-states/2016-02-15/age-secular-stagnation. Accessed 24 Aug 2016

  • Verdoorn PJ (1949) Fattori che regolano lo sviluppo della produttività del lavoro. L’Industria 1(1949):45–53

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christina Anselmann .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Anselmann, C. (2020). A Steindlian Model of Income Distribution, Economic Growth, and Stagnation. In: Secular Stagnation Theories. Springer Studies in the History of Economic Thought. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-41087-2_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics