Skip to main content

Immigration and Job Creation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Understanding Migration with Macroeconomics
  • 417 Accesses

Abstract

Chassamboulli discusses recent research on the effect of immigration policies on job creation. New findings show that various types of immigrants can have a positive impact on employers’ incentives to post vacancies and create new jobs, which benefits also competing natives. Policies that restrict the presence of foreign labour in the labour market are less beneficial to natives compared to policies that do not decrease immigration, but shift instead its composition towards the types of immigrants that benefit the natives the most. We explore one such policy combination that eliminates illegal immigration but allows for foreigners to enter on temporary work permits. Chassamboulli shows that this policy can help attenuate the negative job creation effect of fewer illegal immigrants in the market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Firms produce labour inputs by employing workers. The inputs they produce are then sold in competitive markets. Because markets are competitive, the price of the labour input, which represents the firm’s revenue from operating the job is the worker’s marginal product.

  2. 2.

    In the United States, for example, not all legal immigrants qualify for unemployment benefits extending beyond the period of 26 weeks and are paid during recessions by the federal government. Moreover, since the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act (PRWORA) of 1996 many federal government benefits (Food stamps, TANF, AFDC and others) were restricted to US citizens only. In some states some of these benefits were reinstated in the 2000s, but not all of them. Overall, immigrants in the US, even the legal ones, either on temporary visas or permanent residency, have access to significantly fewer benefits than US citizens, especially when unemployed.

  3. 3.

    Several other papers (e.g. LaLonde and Topel 1991; Kerr and Kerr 2011) show that immigrants are paid less than natives even after controlling for other observable productivity determinants such as education and language.

  4. 4.

    Most legal immigrants in the US are on family unification visas. A foreigner, irrespective of his skill level, can apply for a family visa as long as a member of his family is a legal permanent resident of the US and those admitted are not selected based on skills. Given this, we think it is reasonable to assume that opportunities for legal entry arise at the same rate for both skilled and unskilled foreigners.

  5. 5.

    According to estimates reported by the Migration Policy Institute in 2012, more than 80% of undocumented immigrants in the US had at most a high school degree.

  6. 6.

    The function M(ui, vi) exhibits the standard properties: it is at least twice continuously differentiable, increasing in its arguments, exhibits constant returns to scale and satisfies the Inada conditions.

  7. 7.

    Compared to a legalization programme, this policy is less beneficial to native workers because it keeps the total number of immigrants that same. With a legalization programme, the entry of new illegal immigrants increases, and they are then legalized to keep the number of illegal immigrants low. As a result, although illegal immigration decreases, total immigration increases.

References

  • Battisti, Michele, Gabriel Falbermayr, Giovanni Peri. (2018), Immigration, search and redistribution: A quantitative assessment of native welfare, Journal of the European Economic Association, 16(4), 1137–1188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, George, Friedberg, Rachel. (2009), Recent trends in the earnings of new immigrants to the United States. NBER Working Paper No. 1540.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bound, John, Gaurav Khanna and Nicolas Morales. (2017), Understanding the economic impact of the H-1B Program on the US, NBER Working Paper No. 23153.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chassamboulli, Andri and Theodore Palivos. (2013), The impact of immigration on the employment and wages of native workers, Journal of Macroeconomics, 38 (part A), 19–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chassamboulli, Andri and Theodore Palivos. (2014), A search-equilibrium approach to the effects of immigration on labour market outcomes, International Economic Review, 55, 111–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chassamboulli, Andri, Giovanni Peri. (2015), The labour market effects of reducing the number of illegal immigrants, Review of Economic Dynamics, 18, 792–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chassamboulli, Andri, Giovanni Peri. (2019), The economic effect of immigration policies: Analyzing and simulating the U.S. case, NBER Working Paper No. 25074.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Robert E., and Paul R. Milgrom. “The limited influence of unemployment on the wage bargain.” American Economic Review 98, no. 4 (2008): 1653–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hosios, Arthur J. “On the efficiency of matching and related models of search and unemployment.” Review of Economic Studies 57, no. 2 (1990): 279–298.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunt, Jennifer. (2011), “Which immigrants are most innovative and entrepreneurial? Distinctions by entry visa”, Journal of Labour Economics, vol. 29(3), 417–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunt, Jennifer, Marjolaine Gauthier-Loiselle. (2010), How much does immigration boost innovation?, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(2), 31–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaimovich, Nir and Henry Siu. (2017), “High-skilled immigration, STEM employment and non-routine-biased technical change,” NBER Working Paper No. 23185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, Sari Pekkala, Kerr, William. (2011), Economic impacts of immigration: a survey. Finnish Economic Papers, 24 (1), 1–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, William, and William Lincoln. (2010), The supply side of innovation: H-1B visa reforms and U.S. ethnic invention, Journal of Labour Economics, 28(3): 473–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LaLonde, Robert, Robert Topel. (1991), Immigrants in the American labour market: quality, assimilation, and distributional effects, American Economic Review, 81 (2), 297–302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, Ethan, Giovanni Peri, (2015), Immigration and the economy of cities and regions, Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, 5, 625–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Xiangbo. (2010), On the macroeconomic and welfare effects of illegal immigration. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34, 2547–2567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Xiangbo, Theodore Palivos, Xiaomeng Zhang. (2017), Immigration skill heterogeneity and qualification mismatch, Economic Inquiry, 55(3), 1231–1264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lofstrom, Magnus and Hayes, Joseph. (2011), H-1Bs: how do they stack up to US born workers?, IZA Discussion Papers 6259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moreno-Galbis, Eva, Ahmed Tritah. (2016), European Economic Review, 84, 76–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, Gianmarco IP, and Giovanni Peri. “Rethinking the effect of immigration on wages.” Journal of the European Economic Association 10, no. 1 (2012): 152–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orrenius, Pia, Madeline Zavodny and Alexander Abraham (2020), The Effect of Immigration on Business Dynamics and Employment. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Working Paper 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palivos, Theodore. (2009), Welfare effects of illegal immigration, Journal of Population Economics, 22, 131–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peri, Giovanni, Kevin Shih, and Chad Sparber. (2015). STEM workers, H-1B visas, and productivity in US cities, Journal of Labour Economics, 33(S1, Part 2), 225–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peri, Giovanni. (2016), Immigrants, productivity, and labour markets, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 30(4), 3–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrongolo, Barbara, and Christopher A. Pissarides. “Looking into the black box: A survey of the matching function.” Journal of Economic Literature 39, no. 2 (2001): 390–431.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, Christopher (2000), Equilibrium unemployment theory, Second edition. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zavodny, Madeline, (2011) Immigration and American Jobs, New American Economy. Retrieved from: https://www.newamericaneconomy.org/sites/all/themes/pnae/img/NAE_Im-AmerJobs.pdf

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andri Chassamboulli .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Model Details

1.1.1 Bellman Equations

The Bellman equations describing the values of job vacancies for unskilled and skilled workers in country 1 are as follows:

$$ r{V}_u=-{c}_u+q\left({\theta}_u\right)\left[\frac{u_I}{u_u}{J}_I+\frac{u_{uL}}{u_u}{J}_{uL}+\frac{u_{uN}}{u_u}{J}_{uN}\right] $$
(5.22)
$$ r{V}_s=-{c}_s+q\left({\theta}_s\right)\left[\frac{u_{sL}}{u_s}{J}_{sL}+\frac{u_{sN}}{u_s}{J}_{sN}\right] $$
(5.23)

Next, the value of a job depends on the type of worker filling the job:

$$ r{J}_{sN}={p}_s-{w}_{sN}+\left({s}_s+\tau \right)\left[{V}_s-{J}_{sN}\right] $$
(5.24)
$$ r{J}_{uN}={p}_u-{w}_{uN}+{x}_T{J}_T+\left({s}_u+\tau \right)\left[{V}_u-{J}_{uN}\right] $$
(5.25)
$$ r{J}_{sL}=\lambda {p}_s-{w}_{sL}+\left({s}_s+{d}_L+\tau \right)\left[{V}_s-{J}_{sL}\right] $$
(5.26)
$$ r{J}_{uL}={p}_u-{w}_{uL}+{x}_T{J}_T+\left({s}_u+{d}_L+\tau \right)\left[{V}_u-{J}_{uL}\right] $$
(5.27)
$$ r{J}_T={p}_u-{w}_T+\left({d}_T+\tau \right)\left[{V}_u-{J}_T\right] $$
(5.28)
$$ r{J}_I={p}_u-{w}_I+{x}_T{J}_T+\left({s}_u+{d}_I+\tau \right)\left[{V}_u-{J}_I\right] $$
(5.29)

The value of unemployment for each worker type satisfies:

$$ \left(r+\tau \right){U}_{iN}={b}_i-m\left({\theta}_i\right)+\left[{E}_{iN}-{U}_{iN}\right],\kern0.5em i=\left[s,u\right] $$
(5.30)
$$ \left(r+\tau \right){U}_{iL}={b}_i-{\pi}_L+m\left({\theta}_s\right)\left[{E}_{iL}-{U}_{iL}\right]+{d}_L\left[{U}_i^2-{U}_{iL}\right] $$
(5.31)
$$ \left(r+\tau \right){U}_I={b}_u-{\pi}_I+m\left({\theta}_u\right)\left[{E}_I-{U}_I\right]+{d}_I\left[{U}_u^2-{U}_I\right] $$
(5.32)

There is no value of being unemployed in country 1 for an immigrant on temporary work permit, since, as already mentioned, stay in country 1, in this case, is conditional on having a job. All immigrants on temporary work permits are employed, otherwise they must return home.

Finally, the value of being employed in steady state is given by the following five conditions relative to each country and worker type:

$$ \left(r+\tau \right){E}_{iN}={w}_{iN}+{s}_i\left[{U}_{iN}-{E}_{iN}\right],\kern0.5em i=\left[s,u\right] $$
(5.33)
$$ \left(r+\tau \right){E}_{iL}={w}_{iL}+{s}_i\left[{U}_{iL}-{E}_{iL}\right]+{d}_L\left[{U}_i^2-{E}_{iL}\right] $$
(5.34)
$$ \left(r+\tau \right){E}_I={w}_I+{s}_u\left[{U}_I-{E}_I\right]+{d}_I\left[{U}_u^2-{E}_I\right] $$
(5.35)
$$ \left(r+\tau \right){E}_T={w}_T+{d}_T\left[{U}_s^2-{E}_T\right] $$
(5.36)

1.1.2 Steady-State Conditions

By equating the outflow of immigrants of each type, which includes returns to the home country and labour force exits, to the inflow of new immigrants into each group we obtain the steady-state conditions for the number of legal immigrants, skilled and unskilled, Ls and Lu, respectively, the number of temporary workers, T, and the number of illegal immigrants, I:

$$ \left({d}_L+\tau \right){L}_i={x}_L{u}_i^2F\left({\tilde{z}}_{iL}\right) $$
(5.37)
$$ \left({d}_T+\tau \right)T={x}_T\left({e}_{uN}+{e}_{uL}+{e}_I\right) $$
(5.38)
$$ \left({d}_I+\tau \right)I={x}_I{u}_u^2F\left({\tilde{z}}_I\right) $$
(5.39)

where euL = Lu − uuL is the number of unskilled legal immigrants that are employed, eI = I − uI is the number of unskilled illegal immigrants that are employed and euN = 1 − S − uuN is the number of unskilled natives that are employed.

The conditions for the steady-state unemployment of natives (usN and uuN), legal immigrants (usL and uuL) and illegal immigrants (uI) are as follows

$$ \tau \kern0.28em S+{s}_s\left(S-{u}_{sN}\right)=\left(m\left({\theta}_s\right)+\tau \right){u}_{sN} $$
(5.40)
$$ \tau \kern0.28em \left(1-S\right)+{s}_u\left(1-S-{u}_{uN}\right)=\left(m\left({\theta}_u\right)+\tau \right){u}_{uN} $$
(5.41)
$$ {s}_i\left({L}_{iL}-{u}_{iL}\right)+{x}_L{u}_i^2F\left({\tilde{z}}_{iL}\right)=\left(m\left({\theta}_i\right)+{d}_L+\tau \right){u}_{iL} $$
(5.42)
$$ {s}_u\left(I-{u}_I\right)+{x}_I{u}_u^2F\left({\tilde{z}}_I\right)=\left(m\left({\theta}_u\right)+{d}_I+\tau \right){u}_I $$
(5.43)

1.1.3 Wages

Using the Bellman Eqs. (5.22)–(5.36), the free-entry conditions (5.6), the Nash bargaining conditions (5.7)–(5.9) and the immigration conditions in (5.10) and (5.11), we can solve for the equilibrium wage rates:

$$ {w}_{sN}=\beta {p}_s+\left(1-\beta \right)\left[{b}_s+\beta m\left({\theta}_s\right){S}_{sN}\right] $$
(5.44)
$$ {w}_{uN}=\beta \left[{p}_u+{x}_T{J}_T\right]+\left(1-\beta \right)\left[{b}_u+\beta m\left({\theta}_u\right){S}_{uN}\right] $$
(5.45)
$$ {w}_{sL}=\beta \lambda {p}_s+\left(1-\beta \right)\left[{b}_s-{\pi}_L+\beta m\left({\theta}_s\right){S}_{sN}\right] $$
(5.46)
$$ {w}_{uL}=\beta \left[{p}_u+{x}_T{J}_T\right]+\left(1-\beta \right)\left[{b}_u-{\pi}_L+\beta m\left({\theta}_u\right){S}_{uN}\right] $$
(5.47)
$$ {w}_I=\beta \left[{p}_u+{x}_T{J}_T\right]+\left(1-\beta \right)\left[{b}_u-{\pi}_I+\beta m\left({\theta}_u\right){S}_I\right] $$
(5.48)
$$ {w}_T=\beta {p}_u+\left(1-\beta \right)\left(r+\tau \right){U}_u^2 $$
(5.49)

1.1.4 Value of a Job

Setting Vi = 0 in (5.24)–(5.29), we get:

$$ {J}_{sN}=\frac{p_s-{w}_{sN}}{r+{s}_s+\tau } $$
(5.50)
$$ {J}_{uN}=\frac{p_u+{x}_T{J}_T-{w}_{uN}}{r+{s}_u+\tau } $$
(5.51)
$$ {J}_{sL}=\frac{\lambda {p}_s-{w}_{sL}}{r+{s}_s+{d}_L+\tau } $$
(5.52)
$$ {J}_{uL}=\frac{p_u+{x}_T{J}_T-{w}_{uL}}{r+{s}_u+{d}_L+\tau } $$
(5.53)
$$ {J}_I=\frac{p_u+{x}_T{J}_T-{w}_I}{r+{s}_u+{d}_I+\tau } $$
(5.54)
$$ {J}_T=\frac{p_u-{w}_T}{r+{d}_T+\tau } $$
(5.55)

Apparently, the values of jobs to the firms increase with the worker’s productivity and decrease with the worker’s break up probability and wage, while the possibility of hiring a temporary worker increases the value of unskilled jobs.

Substituting the equilibrium wages (given in Eqs. (5.44)–(5.49)) into the equations above and using the Nash bargaining conditions in (5.7)–(5.9) we can write:

$$ {J}_{sN}=\left(1-\beta \right){S}_{sN}=\frac{\left(1-\beta \right)\left({p}_s-{b}_s\right)}{r+{s}_s+\tau +\beta m\left({\theta}_s\right)} $$
(5.56)
$$ {J}_{uN}=\left(1-\beta \right){S}_{uN}=\frac{\left(1-\beta \right)\left({p}_u-{b}_u\right)+{x}_T{J}_T}{r+{s}_u+\tau +\beta m\left({\theta}_u\right)} $$
(5.57)
$$ {J}_{sL}=\left(1-\beta \right){S}_{sL}=\frac{\left(1-\beta \right)\left(\lambda {p}_s-{b}_s+{\pi}_L\right)}{r+{s}_s+{d}_L+\tau +\beta m\left({\theta}_s\right)} $$
(5.58)
$$ {J}_{uL}=\left(1-\beta \right){S}_{uL}=\frac{\left(1-\beta \right)\left({p}_u-{b}_u+{\pi}_L\right)+{x}_T{J}_T}{r+{s}_u+{d}_L+\tau +\beta m\left({\theta}_u\right)} $$
(5.59)
$$ {J}_I=\left(1-\beta \right){S}_I=\frac{\left(1-\beta \right)\left({p}_u-{b}_u+{\pi}_I\right)+{x}_T{J}_T}{r+{s}_u+{d}_I+\tau +\beta m\left({\theta}_u\right)} $$
(5.60)
$$ {J}_T=\left(1-\beta \right){S}_I=\frac{\left(1-\beta \right)\left({p}_u-\left(r+\tau \right){U}_s^2\right)}{r+{d}_T+\tau } $$
(5.61)

1.1.5 Net Income

The net income of natives is given by the following expression:

$$ \tilde{Y}=Y+{b}_s{u}_{sN}+{b}_u{u}_{uN}-{c}_s{v}_s-{c}_u{v}_u-{w}_{sL}{e}_{sL}-{w}_{uL}{e}_{uL}-{w}_I{e}_I-{w}_TT $$

The expression above assumes that employers are natives and it shows that net income to natives includes total wage income to natives plus unemployment income to natives minus the cost of vacancy posting and the wages paid to immigrants. An alternative definition can be obtained by omitting the natives’ unemployment income.

$$ {\tilde{Y}}_1=\tilde{Y}-{b}_s{u}_{sN}+{b}_u{u}_{uN} $$

1.2 Parameterization of the Model

Table 5.2 Parameterization and matched moments

1.3 Sensitivity Checks

In the benchmark parameterization we set the duration of work permits to 12 months. In Table 5.3 below we examine how the results of the policy combination of replacing illegal immigrants with temporary workers change when the duration of work permits changes. The effects are robust to changes in the duration of work permits, since in all cases considered, both types of natives benefit in terms of job creation. We see that the positive job creation effect on unskilled workers decreases as the duration increases, mainly because with longer duration of work permits the inflow of temporary workers necessary to replace illegal immigrants is smaller. This means that opportunities to hire temporary workers are less frequent (i.e. xT is smaller), which implies, in turn, that firms’ benefit less from the introduction of the temporary-worker programme.

Table 5.3 Sensitivity analysis with respect to the duration of work permits

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Chassamboulli, A. (2020). Immigration and Job Creation. In: Vella, E., Caballé, J., Llull, J. (eds) Understanding Migration with Macroeconomics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-40981-4_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-40981-4_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-40980-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-40981-4

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics