Skip to main content

Adam Smith’s International Thought

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Adam Smith’s Pragmatic Liberalism
  • 284 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter I explore Adam Smith’s international thought by examining his conception of the ideal global regime of commercial strangership and his attitudes to imperialism, global integration, American independence, Stoic cosmopolitanism, war, mercantilism, the changing character of international relations under commercialism, patriotism and his own alleged nationalism. There is a special focus on his attitude to British control over America because it offers insight, not only to his views on international affairs, but to his skill as a political strategist and navigator of public opinion. It shows that Smith was extremely well equipped to engage with the realities of political life.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The time of globalisation’s birth has been contested. Flynn and Giraldez ‘propose that globalisation began when the Old World became directly connected with the Americas in 1571 via Manila’ (2004). Smith also dates the beginnings of globalisation from the discoveries of America and ‘a passage to the East Indies, by the Cape of Good Hope’ (WN, II.V.i.32–3: 448–49).

  2. 2.

    Smith does note, however, that imperial conquest can hasten development and stimulate population growth among the indigenous population (WN, IV.vii.b: 568–69). David Williams has argued, however, that ‘Smith’s opposition to colonial rule derived largely from its impact on the metropole, rather than on its impact on the conquered and colonised’ (Williams 2014: 285).

  3. 3.

    For an excellent and detailed discussion of arguments made in this vein prior to Smith see Hont (2005).

  4. 4.

    The same image of concentric circles, or ‘gradations of duty’, appears in Cicero (trans. 1990, 1.160: 165), and in a fragment attributed to the later period Stoic Hierocles (reproduced in Annas 1993: 267–68).

  5. 5.

    Oikeiosis roughly translates as ‘belonging’ and implies a natural orientation towards one’s own good; social oikeiosis is the social process of ‘making akin to’.

  6. 6.

    Notwithstanding the Imperial Parliament he proposed as a last-ditch measure to resolve the American conflict and whose membership was limited to the British Isles and America (see below).

  7. 7.

    In spite of all this rhetoric of ‘justice’ in international relations, as Pitts notes, Smith nowhere specifies ‘what rights nations should be understood to have: whether rights not to be interfered with, or perhaps simply not to be robbed and destroyed’ (Pitts 2005: 57).

  8. 8.

    Condorcet dreamed, meanwhile, of a kind of international court to preside impartially over ‘the execution of laws of commerce, seizures of foreign vessels, violations of territory, the interpretation of treaties, successions, etc.’ (Rothschild 2004: 12).

  9. 9.

    Smith gives as his example the ‘horrible, and therefore intolerable, practice of infanticide’ (TMS, V.ii.13–16: 209–11).

  10. 10.

    According to Ian Ross, the ideas expressed in the Memorandum ‘are similar to those of the WN’ (Ross 1975: 14–15). However, there are some differences and omissions, as I show below.

  11. 11.

    Morrison contests late readings of Smith’s influence here by refuting the ‘materialist’ thesis that the latter’s ideas were only ‘embraced’ retrospectively ‘because they fit Britain’s new circumstances, namely, the loss of the American colonies’. Morrison instead ‘defends the ‘ideographic’ counterfactual that if Shelburne had not engaged Smith’s ideas, the American Revolutionary War would have ended on vastly different terms (Morrison 2012: 401–402).

  12. 12.

    Skinner notes that, objectively, there had been considerable mutual benefit in the arrangement since ‘the colonists [were] confined to the production of primary products and the British to manufactures, thus creating a system of complementary markets’ (Skinner 1977: 75; see also Skinner 1996 and Stevens 1975: 212).

  13. 13.

    According to Andrew Skinner, the acts of trade and navigation that Smith saw as ‘unjust violations of natural liberty, were not at the same time seen in this light by the colonists themselves’ and ‘neither the Declaration of Colonial Rights and Grievances not the Declaration of Independence (which included a comprehensive indictment of British Policy) contained any critical reference to them’ (Skinner 1996: 127).

  14. 14.

    The document is dated February 1778 and ‘was first published by G.H. Guttridge in the American Historical Review, 38, 1932–33’ (Skinner 1976: 68).

  15. 15.

    See Fergusson (1934) for Dempster’s letters to Sir Adam Fergusson of 26 January 1775 and 4 February 1778.

  16. 16.

    However, by 1778 Pownell is reported to have told the House of Commons: ‘Until you shall be convinced that you are no longer sovereigns over America, but that the United States are an independent sovereign people … it is of no consequence at all, what schemes or plans of conciliation this side the House or that may adopt’ (see Stephens in Corr. App.B: 379–80).

  17. 17.

    He still evinced some sympathy for the idea as late as 1775 but soon after determined that only complete emancipation could be accepted (see Crane 1950: 72, n.28). Franklin was consulted by Smith on numerous occasions during the preparation of Wealth of Nations (Benians 1925: 252).

  18. 18.

    Others agreed that under a Union, America would eventually be dominant, among them, Thomas Pownell, as well as Benjamin Franklin, the latter of whom wrote to Lord Kames: ‘Scotland and Ireland are differently circumstanced. Confined by the sea, they can scarcely increase in numbers, wealth and strength, so as to overbalance England. But America, an immense territory, favoured by Nature with all advantages of climate, soil, great navigable rivers, and lakes, etc. must become a great country, populous and mighty; and will, in less time than is generally conceived, be able to shake off any shackles that may be imposed on her, and perhaps place them on the imposers’ (cited in Ross 1972: 340–41). John Adams thought the scheme practicable only if eventually ‘Crown and legislature’ ‘migrate[d] to America’ (Adams 1856: 119; Benians 1925: 263).

  19. 19.

    Smith’s use of the term ‘project’ requires some explanation here. Going by his use of the term in comparable contexts, ‘projectors’ are mere speculators who get behind projects that they are ill-equipped to manage and conclude (e.g. WN, I.x.b.42:131; WN, II.ii.69: 310–12). Hence, when Smith refers to the Empire as a mere ‘project’ he means it pejoratively as a speculative scheme ill-executed and unrealised.

References

  • Adams, J. (1856). The Works, Vol. IV, C. F. Adams (Ed.). Boston: Little Brown and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Annas, J. (1993). The Morality of Happiness. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldry, H. C. (1965). The Unity of Mankind in Greek Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Benians, E. A. (1925). Adam Smith’s Project of an Empire. Cambridge Historical Journal, 1(3), 249–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berdell, J. (2002). International Trade and Economic Growth in Open Economies. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, T. D., & Ross, I. S. (1981). The Utilitarianism of Adam Smith’s Policy Advice. Journal of the History of Ideas, 42(1), 73–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr, E. H. (1946). The Twenty Years’ Crisis 1919–1939. London: Palgrave.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cicero. (1990). On Friendship and the Dream of Scipio (Laelius de Amicitia & Somnium Scipionis) (J. G. F. Powell, Trans. and Ed.). Warminster: Aris & Phillips.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, S. R. L. (1987). The City of the Wise. Apeiron, 20(1), 63–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crane, V. W. (1950). Benjamin Franklin’s Letters to the Press. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edelstein, L. (1966). The Meaning of Stoicism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Erskine, A. (1990). The Hellenistic Stoa. London: Duckworth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagerstrom, D. I. (1954). Scottish Opinion and the American Revolution. The William and Mary Quarterly, 11(2), 252–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fay, C. R. (1930). Adam Smith and the Dynamic State. The Economic Journal, 40(157), 25–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fergusson, J. (1934). Letters of George Dempster to Sir Adam Fergusson, 1756–1813. London: Macmillan & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fitzgibbons, A. (1995). Adam Smith’s System of Liberty, Wealth and Virtue. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleischacker, S. (2004). On Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations: A philosophical Companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flynn, D. O., & Giraldez, A. (2004). Path Dependence, Time Lags and the Birth of Globalisation: A Critique of O’Rourke and Williamson. European Review of Economic History, 8(1), 81–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forman-Barzilai, F. (2006). Smith on ‘Connexion’, Culture and Judgment. In L. Montes & E. Schliesser (Eds.), New Voices on Adam Smith. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilpin, R. (1971). The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations. International Organisation, 25(3), 398–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griswold, C. (1999). Adam Smith and the Virtues of Enlightenment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guttridge, G. H. (1933). Adam Smith and the American Revolution. The American Historical Review, 38(4), 714–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadas, M. (1943). From Nationalism to Cosmopolitanism in the Greco-Roman World. Journal of the History of Ideas, 4(1), 105–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hewins, W. A. S. (1903, June 5). The fiscal policy of the Empire. The Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill, L. (2000). The Two Republicae of the Roman Stoics. Citizenship Studies, 4(1), 65–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, L. (2004). Further Reflections on the ‘Hidden Theology’ of Adam Smith. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 11(4), 629–635.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hont, I. (2005). Free Trade and the Economic Limits to National Politics: Neo-Machiavellian Political Economy Revisited. In I. Hont (Ed.), Jealousy of Trade: International Competition and the Nation-State in Historical Perspective (pp. 185–266). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. (1932). Letters of David Hume, J. Y. T. Greig (Ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kittrell, E. R. (1965). The Development of the Theory of Colonization in English Classical Political Thought. Southern Economic Journal, 31(3), 189–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knorr, K. E. (1944). British Colonial Theories, 1570–1850. Toronto: Toronto University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marcus Aurelius. (1964). Meditations, translated and with an Introduction by M. Staniforth. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minowitz, P. (1989). Invisible Hand, Invisible Death: Adam Smith on War and Socio-Economic Development. Journal of Political and Military Sociology, 17(Winter), 305–315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minowitz, P. (1993). Profits, Priests, and Princes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montesquieu, C. L. (1989). The Spirit of the Laws (A. M. Cohler, Trans. and Ed.). Cambridge, B. C. Miller & H. M. Stone.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, J. A. (2012). Before Hegemony: Adam Smith, American Independence and the Origins of the First Era of Globalization. International Organisation, 66(3), 395–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muthu, S. (2008). Adam Smith’s Critique of International Trading Companies: Theorizing ‘Globalization’ in the Age of Enlightenment. Political Theory, 36(2), 105–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicholson, J. S. (1909). A Project of Empire, a Critical Study of the Economics of Imperialism, With Special Reference to the Ideas of Adam Smith. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nussbaum, M. (1995). Poetic Justice: The Literary Imagination and Public Life. Boston: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oldenquist, A. (1982). Loyalties. The Journal of Philosophy, 79(4), 173–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palen, M. W. (2014). Adam Smith as Advocate of Empire, c. 1870–1932. The Historical Journal, 57(1), 179–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitts, J. (2005). A Turn to Empire. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Reinert, S. A. (2011). Translating Empire: Emulation and the Origins of Political Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, I. S. (1972). Lord Kames and the Scotland of His Day. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, I. S. (1975). Political Themes in the Correspondence of Adam Smith. The Scottish Tradition, 5, 5–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, I. S. (1995). Life of Adam Smith. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, E. (2001). Economic Sentiments: Adam Smith, Condorcet and the Enlightenment. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, E. (2004). Global Commerce and the Question of Sovereignty in the Eighteenth-Century Provinces. Modern Intellectual History, 1(1), 3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuyler, R. L. (1921). The Climax of Anti-imperialism in England. Political Science Quarterly, 36(4), 537–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schuyler, R. L. (1945). The Fall of the Old Colonial System: A Study of British Free Trade, 1770–1870. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shariff, I. (2003). Global Economic Integration: Prospects and Problems. Economic Development Review, 1(2), 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, A. (1976). Adam Smith and the American Economic Community: An Essay in Applied Economics. Journal of the History of Ideas, 37(1), 59–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, A. S. (1977). Adam Smith and the American Revolution. Presidential Studies Quarterly, 7(2/3), 75–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, A. S. (1996). Adam Smith: The Demise of the Colonial Relationship with America. Cahiers d’Economie Politique, 27(8), 113–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1976 [1759]). The Theory of Moral Sentiments, D. D. Raphael & A. L. MacFie (Eds.). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1978). Lectures on Jurisprudence (A and B), R. L. Meek, D. D. Raphael, & L. G. Stein (Eds.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1979 [1776]). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, R. H. Campbell & A. S. Skinner (Eds.). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1987 [1778]). Smith’s Thoughts on the State of the Contest with America, February 1778. In E. C. Campbell & I. S. Ross (Eds.), The Correspondence of Adam Smith (Appendix B). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, D. (1975). Adam Smith and the colonial disturbances. In A. S. Skinner & T. Wilson (Eds.), Essays on Adam Smith. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teichgraeber, R. F. (1987). ‘Less Abused than I had Reason to Expect’: The Reception of the Wealth of Nations in Britain, 1776–90. The Historical Journal, 30(2), 337–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, D. O. (1932). British Economists and the Empire I. Political Science Quarterly, 46(2), 248–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waltz, K. N. (2001 [1959]). Man, the State and War. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wight, M. (1991). International Theory: The Three Traditions. London: Leicester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, D. (2014). Adam Smith and Colonialism. Journal of International Political Theory, 10(3), 283–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wyatt-Walter, A. (1996). Adam Smith and the Liberal Tradition in International Relations. Review of International Studies, 22(1), 5–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xenakis, I. (1969). Epictetus: Philosopher-Therapist. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lisa Hill .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Hill, L. (2020). Adam Smith’s International Thought. In: Adam Smith’s Pragmatic Liberalism. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-19337-9_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics