Skip to main content

Technology and Innovation for Sustainable Development

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics
  • 2886 Accesses

Abstract

This Chapter presents the evolution of analysis and policy with regard to technology and innovation in the post-World War II period. It starts with a review of analytical issues and notes that (1) technology is created, and requires resources and focused and dedicated effort. The driving force for technological innovation and for productivity growth in capitalism has been the quest by capitalists for producer rents; (2) technology is malleable and the direction of technological progress is induced by a series of environmental factors as well as by the unfolding imperatives of the technology itself. The chapter documents the evolution of innovation and technology policy and its associated analytical discussion during the phase of import substituting industrialisation, beginning in the 1950s and ending around the end of the 1970s. This was a period in which low and middle income countries were heavily dependent on technologies imported from the high income economies, many of which were inappropriate to operating environments in low and middle income environments. Import substitution was complemented, and then succeeded by outward-oriented growth strategies from the early 1970s. This transition was associated with the growth of human and technological capabilities in many low and middle income economies. From the mid-1980s, a rapidly growing proportion of global trade occurred within Global Value Chains, which now dominate global trade and this helped to shape the direction of technological progress.

However, since the millennium, growth trajectories have faltered globally. Productivity growth has declined in the advanced economies and is static in many low and middle income economies. At the same time, the dominant growth trajectories have run into a crisis of sustainability. Not only is economic growth uneven and unstable, but its environmental and social character threaten its sustainability and the survival of life on earth. This has posed new challenges for the organisation and path of innovation, giving rise to growing attempts to foster more inclusive patterns of innovation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Not all economic rents are innovation rents (Kaplinsky 2019). For example, resource rents arise from ownership or exclusive access to scare natural resources. Another important type of rent provided by barriers to entry arises from monopolistic and oligopolistic control of input and output markets.

  2. 2.

    This is only a simplified model. As shown later, whilst competition may indeed spur innovation, there are important respects in which it produces economically, social and environmentally sub-optimal outcomes.

  3. 3.

    Another characterisation of the disadvantages arising from path dependency is the concept of core rigidities (Leonard-Barton 1992), in which firms are locked into static competitive advantages and fail to make the transition into dynamic competences.

  4. 4.

    For example, IBM neglected the arrival of the 51/4 floppy disc since it was hopelessly inadequate for the needs of its customers who required vast quantities of data storage. Its problem was that it knew its existing corporate and military customer base too well, but it had no feel for a new generation of much less demanding individual customers.

  5. 5.

    An important but largely overlooked part of this story was the growing concentration of the retail sector in the US from the mid-1960s and in Europe in later decades (Hamilton et al. 2004). These chains required large volumes of low-cost supplies but had no production capabilities of their own. They then actively sought indigenously owned suppliers in developing economies such as Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore and Taiwan, which had built their capabilities during the import substitution industrialisation (ISI) protectionist periods.

  6. 6.

    Personal Communication, Richard Jolly (18/07/2017).

  7. 7.

    https://www.iriweb.org/sites/default/files/2016GlobalR%26DFundingForecast_2.pdf

  8. 8.

    Mining equipment is one of South Africa’s largest exports, constituting 8.5 per cent of total South African exports in 2005–2009. South Africa’s share of global mining equipment trade was almost 1 per cent in 2011, compared to its share of global capital equipment exports of 0.22 per cent.

  9. 9.

    This extensive trade in intermediates distorts global trade estimates. For example, the screen in a smart phone is counted twice in world trade—once as an export item from Korea to China and then again as incorporated in the mobile phone exported from China. UNCTAD estimates that this data distortion led to an overestimate of 28 per cent in the value of global Trade in 2010 (UNCTAD 2013).

  10. 10.

    As we observed above, a major reason for the failure of the European command economies was their weakness with regard to innovation. China’s experience in recent decades in which innovation has in part been pursued by state-owned enterprises is a special case and needs to be understood through a different analytic lens.

  11. 11.

    I am grateful to Martin Bell for this insight, and also for the additional observation that the R&D-centred gathering of data in the Frascati-era innovation manuals was partly responsible for the misspecification of innovation policies in Africa and elsewhere. There, to this day, R&D-centred S&T policy concerns are geared to the strengthening of research and technology organisations (RTOs) at the cost of focusing on plant- and firm-level changes in production organisation and practice.

  12. 12.

    For example, the number of the 500 largest global firms headquartered in emerging economy markets grew from 21 in 2000 to 132 in 2014 (http://fortune.com/fortune500/).

  13. 13.

    In East Africa, technologies imported from China and India are demonstrably more appropriate than those imported from northern economies. Amongst other attributes, they are cheaper to acquire, are more labour intensive and operate at smaller scales (Hanlin and Kaplinsky 2016).

References

  • Abramovitz, M. (1956). Resources and output in the US since 1870. American Economic Review, 46, 5–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58, 211–221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, R. M. (2007). Technological learning and the development of productive and innovative capacities in the industry and infrastructure sectors of the least developed countries: What’s roles for ODA? Paper prepared for UNCTAD Division for Africa, least developed countries specialised programme, Brighton, Science Policy Research Unit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bell, R. M., & Figueiredo, P. N. (2012). Building innovative capabilities in latecomer emerging market firms: Some key issues. In E. Amann & J. Cantwell (Eds.), Innovative firms in emerging market economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessant, J., Kaplinsky, R., & Lamming, R. (2003). Putting supply chain learning into practice. International Journal of Production Management, 23(2), 167–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Best, M. H. (1990). The new competition. Oxford: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J., & Desai, P. (1970). Planning for industrialization: Indian industrialization and trade policies since 1951. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhalla, A. S. (Ed.). (1975). Technology and employment in industry. Geneva: ILO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braverman, H. (1974). Labor and monopoly capital: The degradation of work in the twentieth century. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J. (2002). Kicking away the ladder: Development strategy in historical perspective. Wimbledon: Anthem Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charmes, J. (2016). The informal economy: Definition, size, contribution and main characteristics. In E. Kraemer-Mbula & W. Sachs (Eds.), The informal economy in developing nations: Hidden engine of innovation? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chataway, J., Hanlin, R., & Kaplinsky, R. (2014). Inclusive innovation: An architecture for policy development. Innovation and Development, 4(1), 33–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christenson, C. (1997). The innovator’s dilemma. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, C. (1970). The transfer of industrial technology to the under-developed countries. IDS Bulletin, 3(1), 3–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cusumano, M. A. (1985). The Japanese automobile industry: Technology and management at Nissan and Toyota. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G. (1982). Technological paradigms and technological trajectories. Research Policy, 11(3), 147–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckaus, R. S. (1955). The factor proportions problem in underdeveloped areas. American Economic Review, 45(4), 539–565.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edquist, C. (Ed.). (1997). Systems of innovation: Technologies, institutions and organizations. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emmanuel, A. (1982). Appropriate technology and underdevelopment. Chichester: J Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fellner, W. (1961). Two propositions in the theory of induced innovation. Economic Journal, 71, 305–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forstner, H., Isaksson, A., & Hee Ng, T. (2001). Growth in least developed countries: An empirical analysis of productivity change, 1970–1992. Vienna: UNIDO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C. (1995). The ‘national system of innovation’ in historical perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19(1), 5–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, C., Clark, J., & Soete, L. (1982). Unemployment and technical innovation: A study of long waves and economic development. London: Frances Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi, G. (1994). The organization of buyer-driven global commodity chains: How U. S. retailers shape overseas production networks. In G. Gereffi & M. Korzeniewicz (Eds.), Commodity chains and global capitalism. London: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, M., Limoges, C., Nowotny, H., Schwartzman, S., Scott, P., & Trow, M. (1994). The new production of knowledge: The dynamics of science and research in contemporary societies. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. J. (2000). Does the ‘new economy’ measure up to the great inventions of the past? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), 49–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamel, G., & Prahalad, C. K. (1994). Competing for the future. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, G., Feenstra, R., & Petrovic, M. (2004). Demand responsiveness and the emergence of capitalism in East Asia: A reassessment of the ‘Asian Miracle, Mimeo, Department of Sociology, Washington, DC: Washington University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanlin, R., & Kaplinsky, R. (2016). South–South trade in capital goods – The market-driven diffusion of appropriate technology. European Journal of Development Research, 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2016.18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heeks, R., Amalia, M., Kintu, R., & Shah, N. (2013, August 29–30). Inclusive innovation: Definition, conceptualisation and future research priorities. Paper presented at: annual conference of the Academy of Innovation and Entrepreneurship (AIE 2013), Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1932). The theory of wages. London: Macmillan. (Reprinted 1963).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, K., & Kaplinsky, R. (1988). Driving force: The global restructuring of technology, labor and investment in the automobile and components industries. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, J., & Schmitz, H. (2001). Governance in global value chains. In G. Gereffi & R. Kaplinsky (eds.), IDS Bulletin Special Issue on the Value of Value Chains, 32(3), 19–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Panel on Social Progress, IPSP. https://www.ipsp.org

  • Kaplinsky, R. (1978). Readings on the multinational corporation in Kenya. Nairobi: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. (1980). Inappropriate products and techniques in UDCS: The case of breakfast foods in Kenya. Review of African Political Economy, 6(14), 90–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. (1993). Export processing zones in the Dominican Republic: Transforming manufactures into commodities. World Development, 21(11), 1851–1865.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. (2005). Globalization, poverty and inequality: Between a rock and a hard place. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R. (2019). GVCs, rents and inequality. In G. Gereffi, S. Ponte, & G. Raj-Reichert (Eds.), Handbook on global value chains. Cheltenham: E. Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R., & Morris, M. (2001). A handbook for value chain research (with M. Morris). https://www.ids.ac.uk/ids/global/pdfs/VchNov01.pdf

  • Kaplinsky, R., & Morris, M. (2015). Thinning and thickening: Productive sector policies in the era of global value chains. European Journal of Development Studies, 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1057/ejdr.2015.29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinsky, R., & Morris, M. (2017). How regulations and standards can support social and environmental dynamics in value chains. Geneva: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD).

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, J. M. (1987). Introduction. In J. M. Katz (Ed.), Technology generation in Latin American manufacturing industries. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraemer-Mbula, E., & Sachs, W. (Eds.). (2016). The informal economy in developing nations: Hidden engine of innovation? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of rent seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1994, March/April). Competitiveness: A dangerous obsession. Foreign Affairs, pp. 28–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lall, S. (1990). Building industrial competitiveness in developing countries. Paris: OECD Development Centre.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lall, S. (1993). Understanding technology development. Development and Change, 24, 719–753.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K. J. (1966). Change and innovation in the technology of consumption. American Economic Review, 56(1/2), 14–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langdon, S. (1981). Multinational corporations in the political economy of Kenya. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, K. (2014). Capability failure and industrial policy to move beyond the middle-income trap: From trade-based to technology-based specialization. In J. Lin & J. Stiglitz (Eds.), Industrial policy revolution. London: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leonard-Barton, D. (1992). Core capabilities and core rigidities: A paradox in managing new product development. Strategic Management Journal, 13(1), 111–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipietz, A. (1987). Mirages and miracles: Crisis in global Fordism. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Little, I. M., Scitovsky, T., & Scott, M. (1970). Industry and trade in some developing countries: A comparative study. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B. A. (1992). National systems of innovation. London: Frances Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1876). Capital: A critique of political economy (Vol. 1). London: Lawrence and Wishart. (Reprinted 1970).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason, A. (2015). Postcapitalism: A guide to our future. London: Allen Lane.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazzucato, M. (2011). The entrepreneurial state. London: Demos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meadows, D. L., Meadows, D. H., Meadows, D. L., Randers, J., & Behrens, W. W. (1972). The limits to growth: A report for the Club of Rome’s project on the predicament of mankind. London: Earth Island Ltd..

    Google Scholar 

  • Merhav, M. (1969). Technological dependence, monopoly and growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, B. (2016). Global inequality: A new approach for the age of globalization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monden, Y. (1983). Toyota production system: Practical approach to production management. Atlanta: Industrial Engineering and Management Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perez, C. (2002). Technological revolutions and financial capital: The dynamics of bubbles and golden ages. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T., & Goldhammer, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piore, M. J., & Sabel, C. (1984). The second industrial divide: Possibilities for prosperity. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1994). The origins of endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1), 3–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1981). Inside the black box: Technology and economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruttan, V. W. (2001). Technology, growth and development: An induced innovation perspective. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schot, J., & Kanger, L. (2016). Deep transitions: Emergence, acceleration, stabilization and directionality (SPRU working paper series 2016-15). Brighton: Falmer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schot, J., & Steinmueller, W. E. (2018). Three frames for innovation policy: R&D, systems of innovation and transformative change. Research Policy, 47(9), 1554–1567.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumacher, F. (1973). Small is beautiful. London: Blond and Briggs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1968). The choice of techniques (3rd ed.). Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singer, H., Cooper, C., Desai, R. C., Freeman, C., Gish, O., Hall, S., & Oldham, G. (1970). The Sussex Manifesto: Science and technology for developing countries during the Second Development Decade (IDS reprints No. 101). Brighton: Institute of Development Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, F., & James, J. (1981). New products: A discussion of the welfare effects of the introduction of new products in developing countries. Oxford Economic Papers, 33(1), 81–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (1972). Major issues arising from the transfer of technology to developing countries, TD/B/AC 11/10.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (2013). World investment report. Geneva: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaitsos, C. V. (1974). Intercountry income distribution and transnational enterprises. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vernardakis, N. (2016). Innovation and technology: Business and economics approaches. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hippel, E. (1994). Technological innovations. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, J. (1990). The progress of policy reform in Latin America (Policy analyses in international economics 28). Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • WIPO. (2017). World intellectual property report, 2017: Intangible capital in global value chains. Geneva: WIPO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Womack, J. P., & Jones, D. T. (1996). Lean thinking: Banish waste and create wealth in your corporation. New York: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xing, Y., & Detert, N. (2010). How the iPhone widens the United States trade deficit with the People’s Republic of China (ADBI working paper 257). Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Raphael Kaplinsky .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kaplinsky, R. (2019). Technology and Innovation for Sustainable Development. In: Nissanke, M., Ocampo, J.A. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_17

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_17

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-13999-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-14000-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics