Skip to main content

The Distribution of Productive Assets and the Economics of Rural Development and Poverty Reduction

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics

Abstract

In the 1960s and 1970s, academic and policy debates on agrarian issues often spun around the distribution of land, with some arguing that neither rural development nor poverty reduction was possible without asset redistribution. While resting on defensible theoretical foundations, the argument for large-scale redistribution gave way to microfinance and other less radical interventions intended to allow low wealth households to do more with their existing, modest asset endowments. While also resting on defensible theoretical foundations, this “lend, don’t redistribute wealth” perspective coincided with a shift of development economics away from big picture theorizing towards an impact evaluation economics focused on reliable identification of microfinance and other singular interventions. Interestingly, despite the promise of microfinance to substitute for asset redistribution, impact evaluation economics found it to have at best modest effects on the class positions and living standards of poor households. In a perhaps ironic twist, a new generation of programs built around the transfer of tangible assets has shown much more promise in terms of changing household economic strategies and placing them on trajectories of sustained economic advance. While sharing some similarities with older perspectives on asset redistribution, these new approaches reflect new learning on both the psychology of poverty and the economics of asset accumulation by poor households.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In his own day, Chayanov was involved in a debate with Lenin among others on whether or not the Russian peasantry was stable or whether it was differentiating into a structure of large farm capitalists and landless workers. Using his variant of the model developed below, Chayanov argued that the peasantry was stable despite regular cycles of farm growth and contraction, which he argued were explicable solely by demographic lifecycle factors.

  2. 2.

    The assumption that the utility of consumption and the disutility of work are additively separable is both faithful to Chayanov’s discussion and rules out pesky cross-partial derivatives that add clutter but little additional insight to the model. Note also that the assumption that household well-being depends on per-capita values of consumption and works ignores the overwhelming evidence that neither consumption goods nor work hours are shared equally between members of the household (see Folbre 1984 for an early and still compelling exposition).

  3. 3.

    Access to labor markets at which they could sell their labor at a fixed \( w>\tilde{w} \) would ameliorate the poverty of these households as would the option to exploit their cheap labor by renting-in land from land-abundant households with higher price labor (Feder 1985).

  4. 4.

    In the language of Elster (1994), this peasant-like self-exploitation is an example of endowment necessitated behavior. That is, people are not born peasants, but they adopt peasant-like behavior when it is the best they can do given their endowments and the constraints they face (an observation also recorded by Lehmann 1986).

  5. 5.

    In fact, as Feder (1985) suggests, there does not need to be full contractibility in all three markets, but rather only a working capital and land market. In that case, each household would lease enough land to maintain an operational size proportionate to the size of their family and achieve the social optimum.

  6. 6.

    This point was actually made as early as John Brewster’s “The Machine Process in Agriculture and Industry” in 1950, where it described moral hazard in labor hiring as being one of the reasons for the persistence of family farming even as agriculture became more mechanized (because on the family farm, all labor has residual claimant incentives to provide optimal effort).

  7. 7.

    Bardhan (1984) pushes this even further, asserting that imperfectly aligned incentives are also linked to how institutions form. Institutional formation is not just cursory to economic outcomes or should be seen as “just being there,” but may be shaped by both information asymmetries and power asymmetries caused by these misaligned incentives. Economies with higher rates of moral hazard in labor can see sharecropping arrangements form. Or perhaps, high initial inequality in land and assets can lead to inefficiently large latifundia farms that can limit households’ outside opportunities as in Conning (2002).

  8. 8.

    As well as a few more, including that u′′ = 0; α = β = 1 and assuming a fixed cost to cultivate.

  9. 9.

    Note that for the family labor farm, the opportunity cost of labor is w, while w(1 + s′) is for the larger farm that hires in labor that must be supervised.

  10. 10.

    Models of occupational choice (e.g., Banerjee and Newman 1993; Ghatak and Jiang 2002; Buera et al. 2018) consider the sorting of a population into entrepreneurs and workers based on wealth endowments and access to capital. While this literature is not specifically agrarian in orientation, it revisits the same issue about whether and how the distribution of initial wealth shapes the structure of an economy and its performance.

  11. 11.

    Indeed, not all classes will exist at all factor price configurations.

  12. 12.

    Eswaran and Kotwal employ a Benthamite social welfare function, giving equal weight to all households in the economy, regardless of the distribution of initial endowments.

  13. 13.

    Indeed, what Eswaran and Kotwal (as well as Marxian economists like John Roemer) call class structure, neoclassical economics would call occupational choice.

  14. 14.

    In order to keep aggregate credit constant when varying θ, Eswaran and Kotwal also vary ϕ, by the equation \( \phi ={B}_T-\theta \overline{T}, \) where BT is the aggregate amount of credit in the economy.

  15. 15.

    Another limitation of both the asymmetric information-based model of Eswaran and Kotwal and the original Chayanovian model is that they treat the distribution of land endowments as fixed. While that treatment is unobjectionable in the short run, it is less defensible over the longer term if we consider time as a degree of freedom that might also allow households to lower consumption and build up stocks of money to either self-finance production or purchase land and gain access to capital that way. We return to these dynamic issues in Sect. 5.

  16. 16.

    In an important theoretical study, Conning 2005 asks whether the presumed benefits of joint liability lending (symmetric information and costless mutual monitoring) are in fact more imagined than real. Conning notes that Yunnus and the Grameen Bank itself began shifting to individual liability loans, closely monitored by bank officers. …

  17. 17.

    One of us attended graduate school in the late 1970s when a series of RCTs were implemented with US government sponsorship to study the impacts of different social welfare programs and work and labor supply incentives.

  18. 18.

    Despite its lagged publication date, the RCT for this study was implemented beginning in 2006.

  19. 19.

    The net compliance rate of an experiment is the difference between the fraction of individuals in the treatment group who took or complied with their treatment (e.g., a microfinance loan) and the fraction of individuals in the control group who also took the treatment. Note that in a classic well-controlled medical trial, the net compliance rate will be 100%, with all the treatment groups taking their medicine and the control group only taking a placebo. The ability to detect treatment impacts declines precipitously with net compliance.

  20. 20.

    As Barrett and Carter 2010 discuss, one of the unfortunate, but avoidable, side effects of the shift of development to impact evaluation is that theoretical insights have often been left aside with the economics profession following the programming decisions of government and non-governmental organizations (NGOs).

  21. 21.

    Boucher, Carter, and Guirkinger (2008) argue that risk rationed households are in a sense involuntarily rationed because they would be expected to borrow if the available contract offered higher interest rates but lower collateral requirements. A similar argument could be made for self-excluding microfinance borrowers who fear placing their few social relationships at risk as collateral for group loans.

  22. 22.

    While the Boucher et al. (2008) results are theoretical, they also show empirical evidence from four countries showing that as much as 25% of the small farmer population is risk rationed and that their failure to exploit available loan contracts leaves them poorer than they need be and in a circumstance akin to that of households that are completely excluded from credit markets.

  23. 23.

    The BRAC analysis compares “selected” with “non-selected” ultra-poor households. Non-selected households passed the means test for inclusion in the program, but failed to otherwise qualify for the program based on other characteristics. At baseline, the non-selected control group was modestly better off than the group selected for inclusion in the TUP program.

  24. 24.

    Four years after the study’s inception, control group households were brought into the program. The seven-year results reported by Bandiera et al. (2017) assume that the control group replicated the pattern of the treatment group in the first years of the study and synthetically reduce downward the position of control households at year 7 in order to obtain estimates of the long-term impacts on the treatment group.

  25. 25.

    Interestingly, Bandiera et al. (2017) show that these average impacts disguise a pattern of heterogeneity in which roughly 40% of households benefit modestly from the program, while the rest benefit substantially more than the average treatment effects indicate. In a study of small farm development program in Nicaragua, Carter et al. (2018) discuss in more detail the reasons why such heterogeneity exists in programs intended to address rural poverty with asset transfers and other interventions intended to place households on an entrepreneurial pathway.

  26. 26.

    As discussed by these authors, identification of the impact of such land reform programs has historically proven difficult because major redistribution efforts typically take place in the midst of a broader mix of political and economic changes (see, e.g., the studies in Thiesenhusen 1989).

  27. 27.

    Numerical dynamic programming solutions to this type of model are found in Ikegami et al. (2017).

  28. 28.

    Note that at the steady-state position, marginal returns to further investment are worth less than the certain cost of the foregone consumption required to finance the accumulation. Given that these costs are certain and that the gains from further accumulation are uncertain, it is suboptimal for the household to try to move beyond the low equilibrium steady-state value.

References

  • Armendariz, B., & Morduch, J. (2004). Microfinance-where do we stand? Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandiera, O., Burgess, R., Das, N., Gulesci, S., Rasul, I., & Sulaiman, M. (2017). Labor markets and poverty in village economies. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132, 811–870.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. V., & Newman, A. F. (1993). Occupational choice and the process of development. Journal of Political Economy, 101, 274–298.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A., Duflo, E., Glennerster, R., & Kinnan, C. (2015a). The miracle of microfinance? Evidence from a randomized evaluation. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7, 22–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A., Duflo, E., Goldberg, N., Karlan, D., Osei, R., Parienté, W., Shapiro, J., Thuysbaert, B., & Udry, C. (2015b). A multifaceted program causes lasting progress for the very poor: Evidence from six countries. Science, 348, 1260799.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A., Karlan, D., & Zinman, J. (2015c). Six randomized evaluations of microcredit: Introduction and further steps. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7, 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, P. K. (1984). Land, labor, and rural poverty: Essays in development economics. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, C., & Carter, M. R. (2010). The power and pitfalls of experiments in development economics: Some non-random reflections. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 32, 515–548.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, C. B., & Carter, M. R. (2013). The economics of poverty traps and persistent poverty: Empirical and policy implications. The Journal of Development Studies, 49, 976–990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Coate, S. (1995). Group lending, repayment incentives and social collateral. Journal of Development Economics, 46, 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boucher, S. R., Carter, M. R., & Guirkinger, C. (2008). Risk rationing and wealth effects in credit markets: Theory and implications for agricultural development. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 90, 409–423.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (1985). The production process in a competitive economy: Walrasian, neo-Hobbesian, and Marxian models. The American Economic Review, 75, 16–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buera, F. J. (2009). A dynamic model of entrepreneurship with borrowing constraints: Theory and evidence. Annals of Finance, 5, 443–464.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buera, F. J., Kaboski, J. P., & Shin, Y. (2018). Taking stock of the evidence on microfinancial interventions. In C. B. Barrett, et al. (Eds.), The economics of poverty traps. London: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. R. (1988). Equilibrium credit rationing of small farm agriculture. Journal of Development Economics, 28, 83–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. R. (1997). Intellectual openings and policy closures: Disequilibria in contemporary development economics. The Dynamics of the Production and Transmission of Development Ideas. University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. R., & Barrett, C. B. (2006). The economics of poverty traps and persistent poverty: An asset-based approach. Journal of Development Studies, 42, 178–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. R., & Olinto, P. (2003). Getting institutions right for whom? Credit constraints and the impact of property rights on the quantity and composition of investment. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 85, 173–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. R., & Zimmerman, F. J. (2000). The dynamic cost and persistence of asset inequality in an agrarian economy. Journal of Development Economics, 63, 265–302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. R., Cheng, L., & Alexander, S. (2016). Where and how index insurance can boost the adoption of improved agricultural technologies. Journal of Development Economics, 118, 59–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M., Toledo, P., & Tjernström, E. (2018). Heterogeneous impact dynamics of a rural business development program in Nicaragua.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chayanov, A. V., In Thorner, D., Kerblay, B., Smith, R. E. F., & American Economic Association. (1966). The theory of peasant economy. Homewood, III: Published for the American Economic Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conning, J. (2002). Latifundia Economics. Economics Working Paper Archive at Hunter College No. 02/1, Hunter College Department of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Janvry, A., & Sadoulet, E. (2015). Development economics: Theory and practice. London/New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Quidt, J., & Haushofer, J. (2017). Depression through the lens of economics: A research agenda. In C. B. Barrett, et al. (Eds.), The economics of poverty traps. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Soto, H. (2001). The mystery of capital. London: Bantam Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dean, E. B., Schilbach, F., & Schofield, H. (2017). Poverty and cognitive function. In C. B. Barrett, et al. (Eds.), The economics of poverty traps. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorner, P., & Kanel, D. (1979). The economic case for land reform: Employment, income distribution, and productivity. The political economy of development and underdevelopment (p. 210). New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dower, P., & Potamites, E. (2014). Signalling creditworthiness: Land titles, banking practices, and formal credit in Indonesia PC Dower, E Potamites. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 50, 435–459.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1994). Marxism, functionalism, and game theory: The case for methodological individualism. In J. E. Roemer (Ed.), Foundations of analytical Marxism. Aldershot: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Escobal, J., & Ponce, C. (Eds). (2016). Combinando protección social con generación de oportunidades económicas: Una evaluación de los avances del programa Haku Wiñay. Grupo de Analisis para el Desarrollo (GRADE).

    Google Scholar 

  • Eswaran, M., & Kotwal, A. (1985). A theory of two-tier labor markets in agrarian economies. The American Economic Review, 75, 162–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eswaran, M., & Kotwal, A. (1986). Access to capital and agrarian production organisation. The Economic Journal, 96, 482–498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feder, G. (1985). The relation between farm size and farm productivity: The role of family labor, supervision and credit constraints. Journal of development economics, 18, 297–313.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feder, G., Onchan, T., Chalamwong, Y., & Hongladarom, C. (1988). Land policies and productivity in Thailand. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folbre, N. (1984). Household production in the Philippines: A non-neoclassical approach. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 32, 303–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghatak, M., & Jiang, N.-H. (2002). A simple model of inequality, occupational choice and development. Journal of Development Economics, 69, 205–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gobin, V. J., Santos, P., & Toth, R., (2017). No longer trapped? Promoting entrepreneurship through cash transfers to ultra-poor women in Northern Kenya. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 99, 1362–1383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hashemi, S. M., & De Montesquiou, A. (2011). Reaching the poorest: Lessons from the graduation model. Focus Note, 69, 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helfand, S., & Taylor, M. P. (2018, Unpublished). The inverse relationship between farm size and productivity: Refocusing the debate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hulme, D., & Moore, K., (2008). Assisting the poorest in Bangladesh: Learning from BRAC’s ‘Targeting the ultra-poor’ programme. In Social protection for the poor and poorest (pp. 194–210). Basingstoke: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ikegami, M., Carter, M. R., Barrett, C. B., & Janzen, S. (2017). Poverty traps and the social protection paradox. In C.B. Barrett, et al. (Eds.), The economics of poverty traps. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keswell, M., & Carter, M. R. (2014). Poverty and land redistribution. Journal of Development Economics, 110, 250–261.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khandker, S. R. (2005). Microfinance and poverty: Evidence using panel data from Bangladesh. The World Bank Economic Review, 19, 263–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraay, A., & McKenzie, D. (2014). Do poverty traps exist? Assessing the evidence. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(3), 127–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann, D. (1986). Two paths of agrarian capitalism: A critique of Chayanovian Marxism. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 28, 601–627.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macours, K., & Vakis, R. (2014). Changing households’ investments and aspirations through social interactions: Evidence from a randomized transfer program in a low-income country. Economic Journal, 124, 607–633.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miguel, E., & Kremer, M. (2004). Worms: Identifying impacts on education and health in the presence of treatment externalities. Econometrica, 72, 159–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miranda, M., & Farrin, K. (2012). Index insurance for developing countries. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 34, 391–427.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morduch, J. (1998). Does microfinance really help the poor? Mew evidence from Bangladesh. In NEUDC Conference. Yale University

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitt, M. M., & Khandker, S. R. (1998). The impact of group-based credit programs on poor households in Bangladesh: Does the gender of participants matter? Journal of Political Economy, 106, 958–996.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabbani, M., Prakash, V., & Sulaiman, M. (2006). Impact assessment of CFPR/TUP: A descriptive analysis based on 2002–2005 panel data. CFPR Working Paper Series No. 12, BRAC-RED.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion, M. (2012). Fighting poverty one experiment at a time. Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 103–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. (1985). A general theory of exploitation and class. Critica, 17(49), 71–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. P. (2001). School subsidies for the poor: Evaluating a Mexican strategy for reducing poverty. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1966). Peasants and Dualism with or without surplus labor. Journal of Political Economy, 74, 425–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. The American Economic Review, 74, 433–444.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (1990). Peer monitoring and credit markets. The World Bank Economic Review, 4, 351–366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E., & Weiss, A. (1981). Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. The American Economic Review, 71, 393–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thiesenhusen, W. C. (1989). Searching for agrarian reform in Latin America. 333.318 S439, Boston: Unwin Hyman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimmerman, F. J., & Carter, M. R. (2003). Asset smoothing, consumption smoothing and the reproduction of inequality under risk and subsistence constraints. Journal of Development Economics, 71, 233–260.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael R. Carter .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Carter, M.R., Michuda, A. (2019). The Distribution of Productive Assets and the Economics of Rural Development and Poverty Reduction. In: Nissanke, M., Ocampo, J.A. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_11

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_11

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-13999-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-14000-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics