Skip to main content

Environmental Policy for Deep Seabed Mining

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Environmental Issues of Deep-Sea Mining

Abstract

This chapter examines the issue of developing deep-sea mining (DSM) while managing the impact upon deep seabed environmental assets. It reviews pertinent background information relating to DSM and the environment; develops a suite of potential policy instruments, including both direct and incentive-based regulation; develops additional incentive-based policy instruments, largely drawn from terrestrial conservation, for potential consideration; briefly touches upon technology and innovation to address mitigation of adverse environmental impacts from DSM; and then provides a concluding discussion.

The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the International Seabed Authority or any of its member States.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Ecosystem services are defined to be the “benefits people obtain from ecosystems.” See, for example, Dasgupta (2001), MEA (2005), and Madureira et al. (2018).

  2. 2.

    For an overview of the DSM environmental issues, see Madureira et al. (2018).

  3. 3.

    The mitigation hierarchy is comprised of four steps: avoidance of environmental damage, minimizing environmental damage after avoidance, restoration/rehabilitation of environmental damage, and addressing the residual after the first three steps have been undertaken, with no net loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services and potentially even a net gain in biodiversity and ecosystem services. See, for example, ten Kate and Crowe (2014). Below we raise a discussion of whether or not no net loss is applicable to an ecosystem that operates on almost geological time scales or at least very long time periods and consistency, whether the no net loss objective applies at all and whether an alternative objective is more appropriate (Griffiths et al. 2018; Kotchen 2009). Besides altering the level of biodiversity loss that is acceptable, the applicability of no net loss also impacts the size of the residual after the first three steps of the mitigation hierarchy have been undertaken and the applicability and role of biodiversity offsets.

  4. 4.

    Cost-effective or least-cost conservation of the mitigation hierarchy’s four steps can lead to greater overall conservation given limited funds for conservation (Squires and Garcia 2014).

  5. 5.

    The impact of the nonrenewability of deep-sea mineral resources is somewhat mitigated by the large size of the Area and expected increase in new reserves as exploration and technological progress proceed. Nonetheless, these resources should be viewed as effectively nonrenewable resources.

  6. 6.

    Sustainable development is development that “meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs,” taking into account the capacity of the natural environment to sustain, indefinitely, the quantity and quality of ecosystem services, biological diversity, and ecological integrity. Sustainable development with nonrenewable mineral resources requires transforming the nonrenewable natural capital into sustainable financial, human, and physical capital that can lead to sustainable consumption and well-being for future generations (World Commission on Environment and Development 1987). Sustainability, stemming from depleting resource revenues, is not as central for the ISA as it is for many individual mining-dependent countries with short reserve horizons, given the size of the Area and expected increase in new reserves.

  7. 7.

    This trade-off is further complicated by the potential for improved information over time about the demand for mineral resources, the environmental impacts of mining, and the availability of new technologies. Having better information can improve decision-making but may come at the cost of foregone net benefits that stretch across up to many generations (an opportunity cost). The trick is to achieve the optimum mix of waiting and not waiting. Waiting too long penalizes current and future consumption, but “hasty” decision-making without adequate scientific information can also turn out to be suboptimal.

  8. 8.

    A redistributive goal could be based on a variety of ethical premises, including Rawlsian redistributive justice or a utilitarian foundation with decreasing marginal utility of income. See, for example, Rawls (2009) and Sen and Williams (1982). Note that these principles can be applied in redistributing income either inter-temporally or across generations.

  9. 9.

    See Ramsey (1928) and Koopmans (1960) for the utilitarian approach and Rawls (1972) for justice among generations; Arrow et al. (2012) and Nordhaus (2008) provide related discussion on climate.

  10. 10.

    A similar result applies to intra-temporal allocations, where equal utility weights, but differences in income levels and the associated marginal utility of income can provide a rationale for putting more weight on consumption by low income groups, thereby justifying redistribution of income from high- to low-income households or states (Squire and van der Tak (1975).

  11. 11.

    Although this chapter does not cover the payment regime or the economics of the mining process itself, see Roth (2018).

  12. 12.

    This chapter focuses upon policy approaches that the ISA could implement, but another approach seeks to harness market pressures exerted by consumers who are willing to pay for products made in environmentally friendly ways. This approach addresses insufficient information in markets, where the amount and quality of information typically decline from producers through firms in the supply chain to consumers of final products. Different forms of certification and eco-labeling provide examples. Nonetheless, because minerals from the deep sea are typically used as inputs in the production of other goods and services, eco-labeling requires tracing the minerals’ origins throughout the entire supply chain. The effectiveness of eco-labeling depends upon the extent to which final consumers of the products produced by these minerals are aware of and willing to pay a price premium when the products are produced with DSM that are minimally harmful to the environment as much as possible and when the price premium is actually transmitted to producers to incentivize their behavior and decision-making to reduce environmental damage from their activities. See Kotchen (2013) and Segerson (2013).

  13. 13.

    In its Advisory Opinion on the Responsibilities and Obligations of States Sponsoring Persons and Entities with Respect to Activities in the Area (Advisory Opinion), Case No. 17, 1 February 2011, the Seabed Disputes Chamber of the International Tribunal for the Law of the Sea suggested that consideration could be given to a fund to provide compensation for damage to the marine environment that could not otherwise be compensated by contractors or by sponsoring states, either to fill the “liability gap” or where the contractor or sponsoring state are impecunious.

  14. 14.

    The allocation of costs and the allocation of risks are potentially two different issues. As an example, an environmental fee could impose fully expected costs on contractors but little risk, because the fee’s amount that would have to be paid would be very predictable. In contract, strict liability imposes full actual costs, but also significant risk, because the amount for which the contractor would ultimately be held responsible is unknown beforehand. See Craik (2018) for additional discussion.

  15. 15.

    With the polluter pays principle, the party inflicting biodiversity loss pays for it. This party has willingness to pay (WTP), and the affected party or society has willingness to accept (WTA) compensation. Maximum WTP for net gain and minimum WTA for no net loss in biodiversity or ecosystem services bound the size of economically rational compensation in monetary values for any voluntary payments. The beneficiary or user pays principle is just the opposite in that it holds that agents who have benefited from the processes that cause loss in biodiversity and ecosystem services should pay the costs of addressing its harms. Just the opposite of the polluter pays principle, the WTP holds for the “impacted” party and WTA for the “impacting” party.

  16. 16.

    The economic value of waiting until additional information is available with an irreversible investment is called quasi-option value (Arrow and Fisher 1984). For an economic analysis and discussion of quasi-option value with mining, see Costello and Kolstaad (2015).

  17. 17.

    Madureira et al. (2018) discuss many potential technology standards, adaptive use of technology standards as knowledge is gained, and potential process standards, notably protected areas and accompanying scientific research to evaluate the impacts of DSM.

  18. 18.

    The socially efficient level of an activity is the level that maximizes the net social benefits of that activity, which equals the benefits derived from the activity minus all social costs (including environmental costs and opportunity costs) that result from the activity. When environmental costs are not fully considered by producers, the activity level that emerges in a competitive market exceeds that level. In addition, the mix of minerals mined, areas mined, and methods of mining can be socially inefficient. All channels to mitigate environmental damage within and across steps of the mitigation hierarchy and across contractors will also be socially suboptimal. Finally, activities across steps of the mitigation hierarchy will not be socially optimal, with excessive mitigation in one step (e.g., avoidance) and insufficient mitigation in another step (e.g., minimization). See Squires and Garcia (In press).

  19. 19.

    In the language of technical economics, these factors are the degree of competition in the market and the relative price elasticities of supply and demand. (Price elasticities give the proportional change in quantity supplied or demanded to a 1% change in price.)

  20. 20.

    For extensive legal discussions, see Craik (2018).

  21. 21.

    Regulations on Prospecting and Exploration for Polymetallic Nodules in the Area (ISBA/6/A/18, 13 July 2000, as amended by ISBA/19/A/9 and ISBA/19/A/12, 25 July 2013, and ISBA/20/A/9 24 July 2014)

  22. 22.

    Craik (2018) and Madureira et al. (2018) provide additional discussion related to damages.

  23. 23.

    This outcome presumes that the penalties for violation of existing regulations are comparable to the magnitude of the potential liability contractors face if they are negligent and that both face the same likelihood of enforcement.

  24. 24.

    The bonds can take a variety of forms: cash deposit, parent company guarantee, state guarantee, financial institution letter of credit, and associated investment grade of any issuer. The terms of its release and what can be deducted against the deposit can also vary.

  25. 25.

    Adverse selection occurs in some instances when one party in a negotiation has relevant information the other party lacks, i.e., it is a form of asymmetric information that occurs before “the contract,” i.e., the agreement. In this case, the contractor has more and higher-quality information about where the sites for mining and environmental protection are to be located that the other parties lack. By then placing an environmentally protected area in a location that would not have been mined and would have been implicitly protected regardless, there is no additional conservation beyond what would have occurred without the protection (i.e., lack of additionality).

  26. 26.

    In the economics literature, offsets are voluntary contributions to a public good (here biodiversity and ecosystem services) that are motivated, in part, by a desire to compensate for (i.e., offset) the detrimental impacts of other activities such as mining (Vicary 2000; Kotchen 2009). The objective or baseline for offsets is not necessarily no net loss of biodiversity, as posed in the conservation biology literature, but rather the level of offsets that yields an optimal level of voluntary provision of the public good. Such a level balances the benefits of offsetting degradation (i.e., the benefits of the resulting increase in environmental services) and the associated costs.

  27. 27.

    See Griffiths et al. (2018) for a broader discussion of the applicability of no net loss to the mitigation hierarchy and Kotchen (2009) for additional discussion of the objective of offsets within an economics context.

  28. 28.

    In general, typically a single policy instrument is not sufficient for providing efficient incentives to address multiple-faceted problems, unless the problems are closely linked (Bennear and Stavins 2007).

  29. 29.

    In this regard, even though the supplying parties are public, the situation is closer to that of a classic public good in which the supply is the result of the collective supply of individual private providers, which in turn is subject to the classic public good issues of under-provision compared to the socially optimal level, benefits that created by each provider that they do not fully receive (external benefits), and free riding.

  30. 30.

    There are several types of technology that can provide public goods (Hirschleifer 1983; Barrett 2007). Let Q denote the total level of public good supplied, and let qi denote the quantity of public good supplied by party i, where i = 1, 2, … . , M, and there are M total parties. Then for (1) a best-shot technology, Q =  max (q1, q2, … , qM); (2) a weakest link technology, there are issues of weak supply incentives and free riding, and supply is determined by the weakest link or smallest provider of the public good, Q =  min (q1, q2, … , qM); (3) an aggregate technology Q = f(q1, q2, … , qM), where f(∙) denotes some general function that aggregates the individual supplies qi and supply depends upon the combined efforts of all parties and issues of weak supply incentives and free riding apply and each provider’s supply is an imperfect substitute for every other supplier’s contribution; (4) an additive technology, a form of aggregate technology, Q = q1 + q2 +  ∙  ∙  ∙  + qM, so that one provider’s supply is a perfect substitute for another’s supply of the public good and faces the issues of supply incentives and free riding; (5) a weighted average technology, a form of aggregate technology, Q = α1q1 + α2q2 +  ∙  ∙  ∙  + αMqM, where the αi denote weights and \( {\sum}_{i-1}^M{\alpha}_i=1 \), and some providers’ supply contributes more to the public good than others; and (6) a weaker link technology, Q = α1q1 + α2q2 +  ∙  ∙  ∙  + αMqM, where one of the αi denotes the weaker link so that greater efforts by one party i can offset the weaker effort by another party j, i ≠ j, and there are issues of weak incentives to supply the public good and free riding.

  31. 31.

    For further discussion of cooperation versus coordination in the international environmental area, see Barrett (2016).

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2002). Directed technical change. The Review of Economic Studies, 69, 781–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., Bursztyn, L., & Hemous, D. (2012). Directed technical change and the environment. American Economic Review, 102(1), 131–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L. H., Mumford, K. J., & Olesop, K. (2012). Sustainability and the measurement of wealth. Environment and Development Economics, 17(3), 317–353.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., & Fisher, A. C. (1984). Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irreversibility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 89, 312–319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. B. (2009). The nature of technology: What it is and how it evolves. New York: Free Press. 235 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2007). Why cooperate? The incentive to supply public goods. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 258 pp.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2016). Coordination vs. voluntarism and enforcement in sustaining international environmental cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 113(51), 14515–14522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennear, L. S., & Stavins, R. N. (2007). Second-best theory and the use of multiple policy instruments. Environmental and Resource Economics, 37(1), 111–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costello, C., & Kolstaad, C. D. (2015) Mining and quasi-option value. NBER Working Paper 21325, US National Bureau of Economic Research. Available at (Accessed 28 Aug 2018). http://www.nber.org/papers/w21325.

  • Craik, N. (2018). Deep seabed mining liability: Potential legal pathways. Briefing Paper 01/2018. Available at (Accessed 28 Aug 2018). https://www.isa.org.jm/sites/default/files/files/documents/bp012018-ilrp-rev.pdf

  • Dasgupta, P. (2001). Human well-being and the natural environment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fox, J., & Nino-Murcia, A. (2005). Status of species conservation banking in the United States. Conservation Biology, 19, 996–1007. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1523-1739.2005.00231.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder, L., & Parry, I. (2008). Instrument choice in environmental policy. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2, 152–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffiths, V. F., JW Bull, J. B., & Milner-Gulland, E. J. (2018. in press). No net loss for people and diversity. Conservation Biology. https://doi.org/10.1111/cobi.13184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hein, J., Mizell, K., Koschinsky, A., & Conrad, T. (2013). Deep-ocean mineral deposits as a source of critical metals for high- and green-technology applications: Comparison with land-based resources. Ore Geology Reviews, 51, 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.oregeorev.2012.12.001. Available at (accessed August 28 2018) https://pubs.er.usgs.gov/publication/70043020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1932). The theory of wages (2nd ed.). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschleifer, J. (1983). From weakest link to best-shot: The voluntary provision of public goods. Public Choice, 41(3), 371–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holland, D., & Schnier, K. (2006). Individual habitat quotas for fisheries. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 51, 72–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A., Newell, R., & Stavins, R. N. (2003). Technological change and the environment. Chapter 11. In K.-G. Mäler & J. R. Vincent (Eds.), Handbook of environmental economics (Vol. I). North Holland: Elsevier Science B.V.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, Newell, R., & Stavins, R. N. (2005). A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental policy. Ecological Economics, 54, 164–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kate, K., & Crowe, M. L. A. (2014). Biodiversity offsets: Policy options for governments. An input paper for the IUCN technical study group on biodiversity offsets. Gland: IUCN. 91pp. Available at (accessed August 28 2018): https://portals.iucn.org/library/sites/library/files/documents/2014-028.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans, T. C. (1960). Stationary ordinal utility and impatience. Econometrica, 28(2), 287–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotchen, M. (2009). Voluntary provision of public goods for Bads: A theory of environmental offsets. The Economic Journal, 119(Issue 537), 883–899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotchen, M. (2013). Voluntary- and information-based approaches to environmental management: A public economics perspective. Review of Environmental Management: A Public Economics Perspective, 7, 276–295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lallier, L. E., & Maes, F. (2016). Environmental impact assessment procedure for deep seabed Mining in the Area: Independent expert review and public participation. Marine Policy, 70, 212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. (2014). Addressing global environmental externalities: Transaction cost considerations. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(2), 424–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madureira, P., Brekke, H., Cherkashov, G (2018). Deep sea mining in the area: Scales of destruction, rehabilitation and protection of the marine environment.

    Google Scholar 

  • MEA (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment). (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being: General synthesis. Available at (Accessed 28 Aug 2018): https://www.millenniumassessment.org/documents/document.356.aspx.pdf

  • ten Kate, K., Pilgrim, J., Brooks, T., Gibbons, P., Hughes, J., Mackey, B., Manuel, J., McKenney, B., Mehra, S., Quétier, F., & Watson, J. (2014). Biodiversity offsets technical paper. Gland: IUCN. 89 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, D. P., & Thurman, W. N. (2013). Conservation easements: Tools for conserving and enhancing ecosystem services. In J. F. Shogren (Ed.), Encyclopedia of energy, natural resources, and environmental economics (Vol. 3, pp. 133–143). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ten Kate, K., & Pilgrim, J. (2014). https://www.iucn.org/ru/content/biodiversity-offsets-technical-study-paper

  • Nordhaus, W. (2008). A question of balance: Weighing the options on global warming policies. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38(4), 543–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1972). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (2009). A theory of justice, revised edition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, R. (2018) Understanding the economics of seabed mining for polymetallic nodules, presentation to the International Seabed Authority Council Meeting, Kingston, Jamaica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Segerson, K. (2013). When is reliance on voluntary approaches in agriculture likely to be effective? Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy, 35(4), 565–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A., & Williams, B. (Eds.). (1982). Utilitarianism and beyond. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Squire, L., & van der Tak, H. G. (1975). Economic analysis of projects. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Squires, D., & Garcia, S. M. (2014). Ecosystem-level impacts of fisheries bycatch on marine megafauna: Biodiversity conservation through mitigation, policy, economic instruments, and technical change. Report of an IUCN-CEM-FEG Scientific Workshop, Gland, Switzerland, 7–10 Oct 2013: 81 p. http://ebcd.org/wp-content/uploads/2014/11/353-Squires_et_Garcia-2014-_Mitigating_ecosystem_level_impacts_of_bycatch-FEG_Meeting_report.pdf or https://euagenda.eu/upload/publications/untitled-865-ea.pdf

  • Squires, D., & Garcia, S. M. (2018). Economic efficiency and the biodiversity mitigation hierarchy with a focus on marine and fishery issues. Conservation Biology, 32(5), 989–997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squires, D., Restrepo, V., & Garcia, S. M. (2018). Fisheries bycatch reduction within the least-cost biodiversity mitigation hierarchy: Conservatory offsets with an application to sea turtles. Marine Policy, 93, 55–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squires, D., & Garcia, S. M. (In press). Economic efficiency and the biodiversity mitigation hierarchy with a focus on marine and fishery issues. Conservation Biology. https://doi.org/10.1111/cobi.13155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (1971). Possible methods and criteria for the sharing by the international community of proceeds and other benefits derived from the exploitation of the resources of the area beyond the limits of national jurisdiction, United Nations General Assembly, Committee on the peaceful uses of the sea-bed and the ocean floor beyond the limits of national jurisdiction, A/AC.138/38, mimeo, 1971.

    Google Scholar 

  • USFWS (United States Fish and Wildlife Service). (2009). Conservation banking: Incentives for stewardship. Washington, DC: WSFWS. Available at (Accessed 28 Aug 2018): https://www.fws.gov/southwest/es/Documents/R2ES/conservation_banking.pdf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dover, C. L., Ardron, J. A., Escobar, E., Gianni, M., Gjerde, K. M., Jaeckel, A., Jones, D. O. B., Levin, L. A., Niner, H. J., Pendleton, L., Smith, C. R., Thiele, T., Turner, P. J., Watling, L., & Weaver, P. P. E. (2017). Biodiversity loss from deep sea mining. Nature Geoscience, 10(7), 464–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vicary, S. (2000). Donations to a public good in a large economy. European Economic Review, 44, 609–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallace, S., Turris, B., Driscoll, J., Bodtker, K., Mose, B., & Munro, G. (2015). Canada’s Pacific groundfish trawl habitat agreement: A global first in an ecosystem approach to bottom trawl impacts. Marine Policy, 60, 240–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Commission on Environment and Development, Our Common Future (“Brundtland Report”). (1987). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael W. Lodge .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Lodge, M.W., Segerson, K., Squires, D. (2019). Environmental Policy for Deep Seabed Mining. In: Sharma, R. (eds) Environmental Issues of Deep-Sea Mining. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-12696-4_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics